?tate QfoUcge of Ji^griculturp At Ol^ocneU 3IIntoersitg 3tl|aca, W. f . 3 1924 052 132 291 Cornell University Library The original of tliis book is in tine Cornell University Library. There are no known copyright restrictions in the United States on the use of the text. http://www.archive.org/details/cu31924052132291 EDITED BY G. W. PROTHERO, LiTT.D., LL.D. HONORARY FELLOW OF KING'S COLLEGE, CAMBRIDGE, LATE PROFESSOR OF HISTORY IN THE UNIVERSITY OF EDINBURGH. WESTERN CIVILISATION IN ITS ECONOMIC ASPECTS (MEDIAEVAL AND MODERN TIMES) CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS C.F. CLAY, Manager LONDON : FETTER LANE, E.C. 4 NEW YORK : THE MACMILLAN CO. BOMBAY CALCUTTA MACMILLAN AND CO., Ltd. MADRAS J TORONTO : THE MACMILLAN CO. OF CANADA, Ltd. TOKYO : MARUZEN-KABUSHIKI-KAISHA ALL RIGHTS RESERVED AN ESSAY ON WESTERN CIVILISATION IN ITS ECONOMIC ASPECTS (MEDIAEVAL AND MODERN TIMES) BY W. CUNNINGHAM, D.D. CAMBRIDGE15 , AT THE UNIVERSITY PRESS 1922 First Edition 1900, Rtprinted 1904, 1910. 1912. flUNTED IN QREAT BRITAM TO PRESIDENT ELIOT I DEDICATE THIS MEMENTO OF MY WORK AT HARVARD UNIVERSITY. a 2 PREFACE. THROUGHOUT this Essay I have tried to show how the material progress of the human race has been carried on and afFectpd by one great polity after another. Friendly critics have said that the scheme of the book brings put the organic connection between countries and between periods that seem to lie very far apart; but the selection of materials^ and the proportion of space assigned to different topics, especially in this second volume, may prove disap- pointing to readers who are keenly interested in the study of the past, for its own sake. Many historical problems might doubtless be seen in clearer light,iif they were approached from the economic staridp6irit,| but I have not attempted to deal with such diifficul ties. The definite object of my Essay has been to point out the remote and complicated causes in the past which have co-operated to mould industry and commerce into their present forms. The cornmercial and industrial in- fluence of the Anglo-Saxon race is so marked and far-reaching that it has been necessary to assign great prominence to the circumstances which have reridered England para.mount on the sea. On the other hand the vigorous tradirig life of Italian ^ So niuch uncertainty attaches to all attempts to interpret quotations of prices and to institute comparisons on this basis between the conditions current in different periods, that I haye found it impossible to make much use of evidence of this kind. Compare my article On the Value of Money in the Harvard Quarterly Journal of Economics, June 1899. viii Preface. cities in the Middle Ages was not very fruitful so far as after times were concerned ; and we cannot but feel that these magnificent communities have been less influential on the economic progress of the world as a whole, than might have been expected by the contemporaries who chronicled their greatness. The difficulty of inarshalling facts that are drawn from so many sources and of sketching the history of centuries on a few pages has been by no means slight ; it has been my good fortune that I have had throughout my task the constant assistance of Miss Lilian Tomn ; her wide reading and careful criticism have been of indispensable service to me at every stage of my work on this volume. The completion of this Essay finishes the series of three text-books' on which I have been engaged since 1893. They are intended to supplement one another as aids to the equip- ment of the student of Modern Economics ; they follow the lines of my teaching in Cambridge for many years past, and this concluding portion embodies the substance of lectures which I had the honour of delivering at Harvard University in 1899. Trinity College, Cambridgb, 8 November igoo. ' These text-books are as follows : Modern Civilisation in some of its Economic Aspects. Cr. 8vo. pp. xvi-Hi7. 1896. Outlines of English Industrial History, with E. A. M'Arthur. Cr. Svo. pp. xii + l64. 1895. Western Civilisation in its Economic Aspects (Ancient Times). Cr. Svo. pp. xii + 220. 1898. (Modem Times). Cr. Svo. pp. xii + 283. 1900. TABLE OF CONTENTS. INTRODUCTION. 71. Mediaeval Christendom as an organised society • 72. The economic debt to ancient Rome .... 73. The Christian compared with the Greek and Roman attitude towards material opportunities and resources. The recon- struction and remodelling of society .... 74. The age of discovery and the study of economic policy . 75. The age of invention, and the general application of capital 76. Divisions of the subject PAGE I 7 10 13 '5 BOOK IV. CHRISTENDOM. CHAPTER I. The Foundations of Society. 77. Security for the prosecution of labour and enterprise afforded by Moral Authority 17 78. Personal influence and official position of Bishops in dealing with Heathen Barbarians 20 7g. Restraining influence on Christianised Barbarians — ^Theodoric the Ostrogoth 23 So. The conversion of the Franks and the recognition of a common ecclesiastical authority in Western Europe .... 29 X Table of Contents. 8i. The fusion of the Franks and the Gallo-Romans ... 31 82. The economic influence of monasteries on agriculture, industry, trade 35 83. The Empire of Charles, its importance, and its character as compared with the realm of Theodoric .... 40 84. Commerce under Charles the Great 46 85. The household as the unit of society for economic purposes . 51 86. Town life — its meaning, elements and conditions ... 54 87. The Roman Obedience 6(> CHAPTER II. Natural and Money Economy. 88. Material relics of mediaeval prosperity ; civic, ecclesiastical, domestic 70 89. The transition from natural to money economy — Constitutional progress 74 90. The mediaeval theory of price ; its fundamental mistakes and its practical applications 77 91. Royal prerogative and the minting of money ... . . 82 92. Ecclesiastical and administrative system. Papal revenue; its collection and transmission 84 93. Collection of royal revenue in kind and in money ... 87 94. Civic Life. Rise of the Communes 89 95. Merchants and Fairs 94 96. Industrial organisation. Craft gilds 95 97. Household economy. Household management. Commutation 99 98. Mediaeval and ancient institutions 103 CHAPTER III. Christian Relations with Heathen and Moslems. 99. The Crusading spirit 107 100. The Vikings and the Baltic commerce 108 loi. The Haiise League .111 102. The Caliphate 114 103. The Western Mediterranean 119 104. The Crusades and the opening of the East . . . .124 105. Prince Henry the Navigator ' , ijg 106. Mediaeval and modem slavery •..>,. 132 Table of Contents. xi BOOK V. NA TIONALITIES. CHAPTER I. Secuiarisation. PAGE 107. The disruption of Christendom . . . • t . 138 108. Secular functions of the clergy and criticism of the existing system 140 109. The Black Death and social disintegration. The Renaissance 143 no. The beginnings of reconstruction. Territorial economic policy 146 111. The rise of nationalities — the influence of Roman Law . . 151 112. The French Monarchy and bourgeois interests . . . 154 113. The Nation as the unit of economic organisation . . . 157 CHAPTER II. The Intervention of Capital 114. Capital and its necessary conditions 162 115. Favourable conditions for minimising its possible evils . . 165 116. The new finance in its bearing on military and political organisation 171 117. The money-markets 175 n8. The influence of capital in recasting commercial and in- dustrial practice . . • • • • • •177 CHAPTER III. Rival Commercial Empires. 119. The Portuguese secure a footing in the East . . • .183 ijo. The Spaniards and treasure 190^ 121. The Dutch and shipping .196. \ii. The French and internal development . . . . • . 206 123. Tbe English Mercantile System . . . • « .315 xii Table of Contents. BOOK VI. THE EXPANSION OF WESTERN CIVILISATION. CHAPTER I. The Industrial Revolution. PAGE 124. The age of invention, and its effects 225 125. The loss of industrial stability .... 230 126. The capitalistic organisation of agriculture ■ 233 127. The disintegration of national economic life . • 235 128. Re-adaptation and reconstruction .... 244 129. Modifications in English finance .... • 251 CHAPTER II. General Tendencies and Particular Conditions. 130. The inevitable tendency of economic forces .... 254 131. Pessimism and anarchism 255 132. Control over the operation of economic forces in different circumstances 258 133. Nationalism and cosmopolitanism 26 [ CONCLUSION. 134. Reciprocal action of Man, and his environment . . , 268 135. Unintentional advance 270 136. Progress as real, and not fortuitous 271 137. Temporary and permanent elements in civilisation . . 272 APPENDIX. The Transplantation of Arts and Institutions . . , 27= Index jg^ MAPS. The Dominion and Conquests of Charles the Great (after Spruner and Menke) .... to face p. 40 Some important Trade Routes in the XIV. Century (based on Goetz, Die Verkehrswege im Dienste des Welthandels) ,,114 The Era of Latin Expansion ,, 183 WESTERN CIVILISATION. INTRODUCTION. 71. In the first volume of this book an attempt has been made to trace the progress of material civili- sation in the ancient world, from its beginnings christen^d >-• 18. ' A. Jameson, Sacred and Legendary Art, 11. 433. ' Levasseur, i. 143. * Imbart de la Tour, of. cil. 75, 76. ^ Keary, The Vikings in WeHern Christendom, l^^. ' Levasseur, i. 143. Also Capit. Migne, I. ool. it,";, c. if. Menctian ot Ort-enwich Dominion & Conquests of Charles the Great. CAMB. UNIV. PRESS To face p, 40 CHAP. I.] The Foundations of Society. 41 through centuries of disorder and degradation. But though his rule was so short-lived, Charles has left a very deep mark on all subsequent history : he made a magnificent effort to organise society through the influence of one civil but conse- crated authority; and he so far succeeded that his reign is a turning point in the history of Western Europe. When we compare the centuries before his time with the succeeding age we see that in his reign the various elements which had been contributed by Romans and barbarians were at last _amalga- mated under Christian influence into one great polity. The government which he created, though so personal to himself, was not a mere transitional form, like the kingdom of Theodoric; the Capitularies continued to have direct effects on the subsequent history of France and Germany; while Charles was taken as a model, consciously or unconsciously, by kings in Scandinavia' and England". All the vague reverence for the name of the Roman Empire which survived in the West attached itself to his personality. From his time onwards it is to the Empire as revived by Charles that men looked for the type of what a well-ordered polity should be ; and the administrative tradition' of classical antiquity only exercised a living influence, in so far as it had been per- petuated in the institutions which he established*. It is also true that the epoch of Charles is the beginning of the modern world, because the political problems with which we are still struggling are very similar to those which ^ Compare the story of the baptism of S. Magnus. Laing, Heimskringla of Snorro Siurleson, II. i8l. " The activities of Alfred so closely resemble those of Charlemagne as to suggest conscious imitation. ' The reintroduction from Constantinople of commercial habits and industrial arts as practised in ancient Rome, or the rediscovery of any of them from literary references, is not in question here, but only the tradi- tional survival. * Court etiquette he seems to have consciously copied from Byzantium. Gibbon, Decline and Fall, c. 58. 42 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. he tried to solve. We still aim, as he did, at bringing Christian influence to bear on political and economic life. We are still confronted by the problems presented by racial differences, and the difficulty of bringing all the subjects of a realm under one system of morality and justice '. Rulers still feel the public duty not merely of obtaining revenue but of developing the resources of the country to the best advantage. These are the recog- nised ideals of the great world-empires of the present day; and when we notice that Charles was dealing with modern problems, with which the ancient world hardly attempted to grapple, we shall feel that there is much to be said for the opinion of those who fix on the year 800 a.d. as the beginning of modern history. It is hardly necessary to call attention to the contrasts between the realm of Charles and such precursors as the empire of Alexander or that of Rome. The Hellenistic world was so imperfectly organised that few elements of common law or administration have survived; it was only in city communities that the tradition of civilised life was. maintained and handed down; but city life was the least noticeable feature of the empire of Charles. Some of the contrasts between the Roman Empire and Christendom have been already pointed out'^, and it is needless to dwell on them at greater length or to try to accentuate the differences in detail. It is, however, particularly instructive to compare the realm of Charles with that of Theodoric, and to notice that Charles, owing to the fusion of races and the wide extent of his rule, was able to aim at so much that had lain quite outside the field of practical politics at the time when the Ostrogothic kingdom ' There is, of course, o. parallelism with the Roman Empire here, but the attempt to introduce similar morality differentiates the modern from the ancient world. The abolition of Suttee in India and the objection to Polygamy in the United States would hardly have occupied the attention of the civil government in the ancient empire. " See above, p. 7, fol. CHAP. I.] The Foundations of Society. 43 was founded in Italy. The most important difference for our immediate purpose lies in this, that Theodoric seems to have been contented if he could secure civilitas, while Charles set himself consciously to promote utilitas. Charles was not merely concerned to maintain law and order, though he knew how necessary they were, and could champion them ruthlessly in his dealings with the Saxons' : it was also his conscious effort after beating back the barbarians to make the best use of the peace he had secured and to develop the resources of his empire for the benefit of the people under his charged He endeavoured, not merely to obtain a revenue, but to foster the prosperity on which sound finance must necessarily depend, and set himself to reorganise the agriculture and industry of the royal estates, and to promote commercial intercourse ^ The care that was bestowed on the sources of wealth also distinguishes the policy of Charles from that of his Frankish predecessors, who were chiefly concerned in amassing the precious metals" ; while there is also a wide difference between his scheme' for ' The war against the Saxons was forced on by the difficulty of living with such neighbours (Eginhardus, Vita, c. 7), and was followed by systematic efforts to civilise the country (Giesebrecht, Kaiserzeit, I. 118). ^ De communi omnium nostrorum utilitate. Capit. Duplex Aquisgra- nense, A.D. 8ii, title to second part. Caroli Magni Opera Omnia. Migne, I. 330. Nos considerantes utilitatem nostram at populi a Deo nobis concessi. Capit. Ticinense, A.D. 8or. lb. 212. In communem sanctae Dei ecclesiae et omnium nostrorum utilitatem. Ludovici et Lo- tharii Capit. Aquisgran. A.D. 817. lb. 396. ' The development of these resources was necessary for the main- tenance of military equipment. With this compare Oman, Art of War in Middle Ages, 78 — 83. * Levasseur, i. 151 and notes. The contrast between the aims of the Frankish kings as amassing bullion and those of Charles, is analogous to the distinction between the bullionists and mercantilists in the seventeenth century, or between the colonial systems of Spain and England. ^ In the Eastern Empire very little effort was made to organise active commerce, and a. good deal of attention was given to planting exotic rather than to developing native industries. 44 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. the material prosperity of his realm and the economic system that had been in vogue in the Eastern Empire. Some of the great difficulties with which Theodoric as an Arian Goth had to contend, were due to the fact that the Catholic clergy were always out of sympathy with his rule, while throughout Charles's dominions the Latin Church was established by his legislation. The Frankish kings had already given a great deal of encouragement to religious institutions, and much wealth had been devoted to the endowment of monasteries; but Charles' set himself to carry through the complete establishment of Christianity ; that is to say, he used the civil power to support spiritual authority, partly by insistence on the performance of certain Christian duties, and partly by strengthening the position of the clerical administration. We find in his legislation or that of his sons, canons against holding markets or courts on Sundays' ; and the observance of this day was imposed as a duty not only on the Franks but upon the Saxons'; both peoples were also required to devote a tenth of their substance to religious objects*. Attempts were begun to combat the evils of beggary by providing local maintenance for the poor" ; in the case of religious foundations* this duty was specially insisted on, and it had a prominent part in schemes of monastic reform'. An endeavour was made ' Charles endowed new monasteries at Corbie and Fulda; the Fulda charters with his signatures are still preserved at Marburg. = Capit. A.D. 813; Migne, I. 363, c. 15 (also I. 318, c. 9). ' Capit. A.D. 782; Migne, I. 146, c. 18. * Capit. A.D. 782; Migne, i. 146, c. 17. The State in imposing an ■ obligation to pay tithe enforced a Christian duty on the subjects, and did not endow religion from royal property. Charles set an example by paying a tithe on royal revenue. lb. c. 16. " Capit. A.D. 806; Migne, i. 303, c. g. ^ See Ludovic and Lothaire; Migne, i. 389, c. 49. 7 The Capitulare of Ludovic and Lothaire (a.d. 817; Migne, I. 383) is very interesting from the manner in which it goes into details, advising that the work on fast-days should be light (c. i8), and referring to the practice CHAP. I.] The Foundations of Society. 45 to bring the monasteries under better rule', and the total mass of legislation on such subjects as these shows clearly how much Charles felt it his duty to follow the example of Josiah, and on the one hand to reform ecclesiastical abuses^, and on the other to recall the kingdom committed to his charge to the worship of the true God^ It had been im- possible for Theodoric to attempt such a decided course; and, as we find a closer connection between Church and State under Charles, so too we may feel that the influence of Christian teaching on civil duty is more strongly marked in the Prankish Empire than in the Ostrogothic kingdom. The responsibility of Christian princes to God for the manner in which they exercise their powers is very explicitly stated in the Capitularies of Ludovic and Lothaire*; while there is an attempt to im- pose a higher standard of fair dealing in commercial trans- actions" than that aimed at by Theodoric, and there are signs of an increasing disposition to put limits on the traffic in slaves". of lending books from the library during Lent for private study by the brethren (c. 19). 1 Capit. A.D. 802; Migne, I. 248, c. 19. ^ There was need to guard against the malversation of ecclesiastical property (Co/iV. A.D. 806; Migne, I. 303, c. 4), extravagance in building and disregard of the duties of devotion (a.d. 811; Jb. I. 332, c. 11), and to warn against the evils which arose in connection with the develop- ment of monastic commerce. (A.D. 789 — 794; lb. i. i8s, c. 6, and 195, cc. II, 14.) 3 Cafdt. A.D. 782; Migne, I. 152. « Capit. A.D. 817; Migne, I. 393. " The principles are laid down clearly, and an attempt is made to define usurious and sordid gains (a.d. 806; Migne, I. 304, cc. i, 8); we may note the condemnation of some special forms of bargain (a.d. 809 ; lb. I. 318, c. 12). There is also famine legislation (a.d. 805; Jt^ I. 284, c. 4), and in some cases the setting of a maximum price (a.d. 794; lb. I. 193, c. 4; also A.D. 808; lb. I. 313, c. 5). ' Pigeonnean, Histoire du commerce de la Fratue, i, 'jt). See below, p. 133- 46 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. 84. When we turn from ecclesiastical to economic affairs Commerce ^6 may See that Charles took a new and very under Charles important departure ; he seems to have made the Great. ^ '^ ■ 1 ^ ^• some attempts to open up commercial relations beyond the area of the Empire, as well as to provide improved conditions for internal trade. Even though his endeavours had little immediate result, they are interesting anticipations of lines of progress that were subsequently pursued. The Mediterranean had come to be practically a Mo- hammedan lake; and though Charles was not very successful in his attempt to drive the Moslems back beyond the Ebro and free the north of Spain from their control, he was able to obtain some important concessions for Marseilles and Narbonne', which began to be staples for trade with the Levant. His friendly relations with Haroun-al-Raschid^ not only enabled Charles to establish these trading connections but also to secure privileges for pilgrims to the Holy Land. The long campaigns which he and his son Pepin waged against the Avars gave greater security along an im- portant route, but even before the practical extermination of that tribe, we find some occasional references to trading communications through the valley of the Danube". Charles attempted to construct a canal which should join the Danube* and the Main; though this seems to have been primarily intended for military transport, it would also have served to bring the commercial traffic of the Danube and the Rhine into direct connection at Mayence. This city was the starting point of a great commercial route in another direction. The conquest of the Saxons had added 1 Figeonneau, I. 73; Abel and Simson, Jahrbiicher des frdnkischen Reichs unter Karl dem Grossen, I. 257. * Eginhardus, Vita Caroli, c. 16. ^ Kurz, Oesterreichs Handel in dlteren Zeiten (1822), p. 4. ^ Eginhardus, \<4««a/f, 793. Heyd (Commerct du Levant, i. 80), shows that it had military rather than mercantile importance. CHAP. I.] The Foundations of Society. 47 an enormous area to the Frankish Empire, and had given the opportunity for extending commercial enterprise among the wilder tribes in Pomerania and the Baltic lands ; access had also been .obtained to Bohemia and Moravia. Caravans of merchants traversed these dangerous regions at no little risk', and made large profits by their importations of furs and amber. There were depots for trade with the Saxons at Erfurt and Magdeburg"; and Jumna ^ at the mouth of the Oder rose into prominence as a centre for Northern products. We also find that attention was given to maritime commerce as well. The Channel ports, Rouen and Boulogne, were of considerable importance. Nantes, at the mouth of the Loire, had doubtless prospered through the activity of Bishop Felix^, and Bordeaux had mercantile intercourse with the Iberian peninsula, and also with Ireland °. The trading relations with England were interrupted in 790 a.d.°, to the loss of the men of Boulogne; and the treaty with Oifa of Mercia in 796 a.d., by which they were re-established, gave security to English merchants and pilgrims who travelled in the Frankish Empire. Commerce must have benefited by the provision that was made for protecting the coast from pillage; Charles had a fleet on the Mediterranean which guarded the waters of Sep- timania and Italy against the Moors ; while he also kept ships in the northern rivers to provide against the attacks -of the Norsemen ^ Boulogne appears to have been the principal port on the Channel, and it was improved by the erection of a lighthouse". ' Pigeonneau, I. 61. The story of Samo, a Frankish trader, shows tliat merchants visited this region in the seventh century. 2 Capit. A.D. 805 ; Migne, i. 285. " Heyd, Commerce du Levant, i. 77. ' Fortunatus, liv. ill. c. 10. " PigeonneaUi i. 60. ' Pigeonneau, I. 74. ' Eginhard, Vita, c. i?. ^ Carlier, Commerce en France sous les rots de la premiere et de la deuxiime race (1752), in Leber, Collection, xvi. p. 113. 48 Western Civilisation. [BOOK iv, The extension of foreign commerce must of course have reacted on internal trade. The towns along the Rhine valley, — Cologne, Coblenz, Mayence, and Strassburg — entered on more prosperous times than they had enjoyed for centuries ; and a great impulse must have been given to the trade of the old established fairs of Troyes' and Paris'. The increased number of similar fairs ^ made it necessary to attempt to improve the facilities for internal communication. The Capitularies insist on the duty of keeping the roads in good repair, and Charles expended much time and money on the construction of a bridge at Mayence*. But great as were the physical obstacles with which the trader had to contend, he must have suffered even more from frequent and arbitrary exactions to which he was subject. Charles was of course careful to collect the ancient revenue from merchandise, and he organised a customs department at different points along the frontier of his enlarged realm*; but he was also at pains to put down novel and extortionate demands". Doubtless there were many local magnates who took tolls from the merchants on the flimsiest of excuses, and Charles had to legislate against those who compelled travellers to use an inconvenient route in order to force them to pay the toll at some particular bridge'. Such instances are instructive, not only as indicating the arbitrary extortion 1 Sidonius Apollinaris, Epist. lib. vi. 4. " The fair lasted for four weeks in October, commencing on S. Denys. Pigeonneau, i. 63. On other fairs see Huvelin, Droit des marchis et des foires, p. 146. ^ Inama Stemegg, Deutsche Wirthschaftigeschichte, I. 433 and refs. * Eginhardus, Vita, c. 17. ^ Pigeonneau, i. 75 ; Abel and Simson, 11. 333, and Cqpitutare, a.d. 805, c. 7; Migne, I. 285. ' Capitulare, A.D. 805, c. 13. The practice of stretching a rope across a river and demanding a fee from travellers passing it was regarded as specially reprehensible. See also A.D. 806; Migne, i. 304, c. 10. ' A.D, 809; Migne, 1. 317, c. 8: also a.d. 817; Migne, I. 408, c. 17, CHAP. I.] TJie Foundations of Society. 4g from which merchants suffered, but as showing the value of the immunities which had been conferred on so many monas- teries. It would be interesting if we had fuller information about the men who had enterprise enough to face these difficulties and to devote themselves to commerce. It is probable that a very large part of the active trade was still in the hands of aliens. At an earlier date the Syrians — a term which in- cluded all merchants from. Egypt and Asia Minor — had been the chief agents in the traffic between East and West ; they had had a considerable settlement at Paris and had been able to exercise much influence there' ; but we do not hear explicitly of them in the time of Charles, though they may of course have been commercial intermediaries in commu- nicating with Constantinople. It seems more probable, how- ever, that they had been superseded by the Jews, who had begun to come to the front during the reign of Justinian^, and who enjoyed great privileges in the Frankish Empire'. They were better able than Mohammedans to trade in Chris- tian lands, and better able than Christians to carry on business among the Mohammedans, so that the expansion of Islam gave them great opportunities. They had an ancient colony at Cologne* which may possibly have survived, and consider- able numbers were settled at Aix, Magdeburg, Paris, Orleans, Clermont, and Narbonne; they were well established at the principal centres of trade. But though they may have been the most wealthy merchants in the time of Charles, they had no exclusive possession of the field. His biographer shows that there were Christian merchants, as well as Jews, even in * Gregory of Tours, x. 26; Boichorst, Zur Geschichte def Syrer in Abeiidland in Mittheilungen fiir oesterreich. Geschichte, vi. 535. ' Vol. I. p. 203. ' Pigeonneau, I. 70; also Depping, Les Juifs an Moyen Age; Huvelin, Droit des marchls et des f aires, p. 151. * Hegel, Entstehung des deutschen Stadtewesens, 112. C. W. C. II. 4 50 Western Civilisation. [BOOK iv. the Levantine trade' : monastic commerce must have assumed considerable proportions, and important immunities were granted to the Archbishop of Strassburg^ for the advantage of the men of that city. Charles exerted himself in another economic matter, and his legislation would have been of decided advantage to trade if it could have been carried out practically. He attempted to reform the standard of weights and measures', and also to deal with the problem of currency*. There was great risk of confusion in all calculations, as Roman and barbarian methods of reckoning existed side by side, and so many distinct authorities exercised the right of coining. The monetary system had been farther complicated by such general con- ditions as a scarcity of the precious metals', and a partial return to natural economy. But the precise motives which induced Charles to take this matter in hand are not clear. He may have desired to issue a standard rate at which revenue should be assessed when it was collected in kindV or he may have been anxious to establish a scale of reasonable prices, and to put an end to the sordid gains of middlemen' who traded in the necessaries of life. Accurate definition of weights and measures and values was a necessary preliminary for either object, and it would have also been a general advantage to the trading class to give precision to the terms they used in bargaining. He had little success in imposing the uniformity he desired ; but his attempt has had a lasting influence on the metric system of a country which lay beyond the limits of his empire. The pound of silver, consisting of twenty solidi of twelve denarii each, was adopted by Charles" as his unit of currency, and this practice was introduced by the Normans into England, where it eventually displaced the • Eginhard, Vita, c. 27. 2 a.d. 775; Migne, I. 938. 8 Inama Stemegg, i. 456. * Inama Stemegg,- 1. 458. ^ Pigeonneau, i. 83. " lb., i. 469. ^ Inama Sternegg, i. 480. » Jd., i. 456. CHAP. I.] Tlie Foundations of Society. 5^ old method of reckoning by marks consisting of eight ounces of twenty pennies each. The English monetary system is a symbol of the long-abiding influence which Charles exercised, even in matters where his efforts seemed to fail utterly. 85. Even greater interest attaches to the famous capitulare de villis in which Charles dealt with the economic ^he house- activities of the household. We are fortunate '^o''* ^^ the . . , unit of society m possessmg so much mformation about his for economic efforts to foster civilisation in a territory where pi'i^po^^^- city life was so little developed; the normal economic unit, alike on royal lands, in monastic institutions, and in the possessions of lay proprietors, was fhe household. This may be a very large social group, but the mutual offices of the members are rendered as a matter of obligation, not as the result of agreements between men who are personally inde- pendent and drive their own bargains. It was already the military unit responsible for the defence of the realm', and was the territorial basis for the administration of justice and provision for the poor. In addition to this Charles aimed at so organising household life that agriculture and industry might be stimulated and improved. The capitulare de villis was not propounded as a mere fiscal measure with the view of increasing the royal revenue ; it aimed at increasing the efficiency of the economic organi- sation^ of society as a whole. Charles was of course chiefly concerned with the administration of the royal domain; the judices^ were to overhaul the administrative work of the majores*, and to see that the king's estates were properly cultivated and the local products well utilised. But the royal example would find imitators, and pressure was brought to bear on the monasteries and lay possessors of beneficial, who ■^ A.D. 807 ; Capit. Aquense in Migne, I. 307, cc. i, 1. ' Inama Stemegg, i. 349. ^ Capit. de Villis, 3, 8, 9, 14, 29. *' lb., 10, 26. ' Inama Sternegg, i. 351, 4 -3 52 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. held portions of the ancient Crown lands. The necessity of being provided with the men and military equipment they were required to furnish would tend to induce other magnates to adopt improved methods of estate management. As it appears that these large households were steadily increasing and attracting the possessors of small holdings to become members of larger organisations', the rules which were laid down for the royal villae would serve, so far as their form was concerned, for the economic regulation of the whole territory. The de villis recapitulates the matters into which the judices ought to enquire, so that the estate management might be carried on properly and efficiently both on its agricultural and industrial sides". To enable them to perform this duty it was desirable that the condition of the estates should be exhibited in writing, so that everything might be easily checked, and the general state of the property readily gauged. There were surveys, which gave a complete inventory of the villa, including a statement of the labour available and the personal obligations of each man, as well as an enume- ration of the live stock, horses, cattle, and hens, and also information about the condition of the buildings and the supply of implements'. It was part of the duty of the judices to keep regular accounts, with separate books for revenue and for outlay, and to inform the king of the state of the balanced The surveys are closely analogous to the extenta of a mediaeval manor, while the accounts, of which no specimen ^ Inama Sternegg, I. 295; Lamprecht, Deutsche Geschichte, II. 89. " On the industrial organisation of the villa compare Gareis, Bemer- kungen zu K. Karl's Capitulare de Villis in Germanistische Abhandlungen zum LXX. Geburtstag K. von Maurers, p. 246 ; Biicher, art. Gemerbe in Handwirterbueh der Staatswissenschaft, in. 926; Gu6rard, Introduction to the Polyptyque de VAbbe Irminon, I. 617; Explication du Cafit. de Villis in Bihliolhique de t&cole des Charles, ser. iii"". t. iv. (185a), pp. 324 7. 3 A.D. 812 ; Migne, I. 341. Compare Ulpian, in Digest L. tit. 15, c. 4. * Capit. de Villis, c. 55. CHAP. I.] The Foundations of Society. S3 seems to have survived, may well have set the type of the mediaeval reckonings which are commonly known as ministers' rolls. The institution which is thus depicted for us, and the system which Charles introduced with the view of regulating it, give us a Hnk with the distant past and help us to look back to the Roman villa, with its ergastula and its tillage, its vineyards, and its cattle breeding. This capitulare is also ot great interest on its own account, since it shows us an almost unique effort to organise a highly civilised life on a basis of natural economy. Military obligations, justice, and poor relief are inseparably linked with the household, within which there is no money circulation. Money and commerce were not excluded ; but the prosperity and strength of the realm were dependent primarily on the management of natural resources, and not on the accumulation of treasure. The amassing of bullion had been the Merovingian expedient' for equipping armies, and it gave the means for bribing barbarians to abstain from plundering. Necessity was doubtless the mother of invention ; and we need not suppose that Charles had consciously formulated any principles of political economy ; but it is worth while to notice that the wisdom of his methods has been endorsed in later times. It was his policy to make the most of native resources, as the secret of strength ; to promote agriculture, but without disparaging industry; and especially to encourage the manu- facture of native products. This was practically an antici- pation of the economic policy which was successfully applied«to England in the days of Burleigh, — the development of industry generally, but in conscious subordination to the needs of agri- culture, while the special advantages of particular districts for mining'' or for the manufacture of salt were not neglected either in the empire of Charles or in the realm of Elizabeth. ' Dahn, op. cit. p. 343. * Inama Sternegg, I. 426. 54 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. There is even greater interest in following out the sub- sequent history of the economic organ which Charles utilised — the household. The system which he formulated was adopted by the Normans, and was introduced into a country well prepared for receiving it, when William conquered England. The great household, as the centre of rura;l life, has had an extraordinary influence on English development ; it has shaped the ambitions of the English plutocracy from the days of William-de-la.-Pole, and has led them to set their faces from the towns where they made their money to the country, where they exercised great power: it survived to stimulate the energies of the great landowners of the last century, when money economy had become completely prevalent, and in- duced them to give their energy to the improvement of English tillage. In the ancient world, and in much of the modern world, the city has had exclusive attractions as the centre of social life J but English civilisation has proceeded on the basis that is implied in Charles's maxims of social regulation'. 86. The political history of the three centuries that followed the partition of the Carlovingian Empire itsmeaningT seems to be a mere record of social disinte- eiements, and gration and internecine warfare, and to have conditions. ° , . . been mcompatible with material progress. There ' In the expansion of English influence beyond the seas, this household type has sometimes been retained, but sometimes we have the land settled in small homesteads. The resultant civilisation in each case has varied immensely. In the tropical climates of India and Ceylon, of the West In^es and the Southern States, with the exception of some parts of Georgia and West Virginia, there are planters with labourers in practical dependence, even where slavery is extinct and cash relations exist ; and in the pasture farms of Australia there are rich squatters. In these lands we get a diffusion of wealth and culture beyond the limits of cities. In the Northern States, in Canada and in South Africa, the rural districts were occupied by little homesteads. There are great drawbacks in this latter system, since it concentrates all social advantages in urban groups and leaves the rural population to a sordid struggle for independence, or monotonous drudgery under giant capitalists. CHAP. I.] The Foundations of Society. 55 is reason to believe, however, that there was more oppor- tunity for cultivating the arts of peace than might at first sight appear; there seems to have been such an increase and diffusion of Teutonic population'' that large areas, first in the south and then in the north of Germany, were occupied by agriculturists'- But more than this, the eleventh and twelfth centuries supply ample evidence of the existence of vigorous urban life in France, Flanders and the Rhineland : while the founding of new towns in these districts and other parts of Germany went on in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries^. Such commercial and industrial centres could not have come into prominence unless there had been a real improvement in the economic conditions of Western Europe. There is no more complicated problem in mediaeval history than that which is raised by this revival of town life. An immense amount of research has been recently devoted to the legal and constitutional aspects of the enquiry ; for us this is a subordinate consideration. The full solution of the economic question can only be found by an investigation of the special history of particular communities; but it is perhaps possible to state the problem in general terms, and thus to indicate the directions in which detailed research may be pursued with profit. One of the principal difficulties to be faced lies in the uncertainty, or rather the want of agreement among historians, as to the characteristic feature of town life; we want so far as possible to be clear what we are looking for. If all that we mean by a town is an unusually populous village* or 1 On the motives for this colonisation see Lamprecht, Deutsche Ge- schichte, in. 351. ^ Lamprecht (Deutsche Geschichte, in. 299) points out that the oscilla- tion in migration began at least as early as the time of Charles. The Germans ceased to move westward, and commenced to colonise towards the east. Inama Sternegg, III. p. i. ° Hegel, Die Entstehung, p. 3^ — 47,, * Green, Short History of the English People, I. 369. 56 Western Civilisation, [BOOK IV. even a place which contained merchants among its inhabi- tants', we can hardly hope to distinguish it from other social groups. There were monasteries that had hundreds of in- mates and dependents^, and that were deeply interested in trading concerns. There is, however, some possibility of discriminating, when we look at the matter in its economic aspects. In the household there is only one proprietor, who has a power of controlling the resources of the establishment ; the town is a social group in which there are several pro- prietors', and therefore several households. If these house- holds were each self-sufficing, they could exist side by side, without entering into any relations with one another; but the group of households in a town supplement one another's industry and are mutually dependent for the necessaries of life. The town consists of an aggregate of households; each householder is free to manage the internal economy of his establishment — so long as he does no injury to the common- weal — and therefore each is economically distinct In the religious houses and other large establishments there might be much division of labour, and the community might engage in constant trade with the outside world; but however nu- merously a monastery was inhabited it would only be a household in the economic sense, and not a town, so long as there were no separate proprietors, with exclusive rights in their possessions, and consequent independence within the group. For the continued existence and growth of such a group of households, facilities of interchange are requisite; it may be impossible to say whether trade called forth a town, or 1 Pirenne in Revue historique (1895), Lvii. p. 70. " See above, p. 38. • "Proprietors" is here used in the widest possible sense, for all those who have exclusive rights to use land, or other requisites of production, whatever might be the precise terms of their tenure, or their legal status as persons. CHAP. I.] The Foundations of Society. 57 whether the presence of a town gave the opportunity of trade' ; as a question of priority it is as insoluble as the problem about the first hen or the first egg ; logically, and as observed fact, the existence of a town and the existence of internal trade are inseparable; the progress of one would stimulate the increase of the other. Something of the nature of a market, in fact if not in law, is involved in the economic idea of a town; such a market would be possible wherever the house- holds, large or small, of distinct proprietors were closely associated together, and were in any way inter-dependent so far as their economic requirements or abilities were concerned. But within the monasteries or large villas there was no similar need or opportunity for the development of habitual inter- changes and bargaining. Hence it seems to follow that though towns were found under the shadow and protection of monasteries and palaces, they consisted of the establishments of several distinct proprietors, and therefore were outside the organised life of any one household. The formation of such groups and their increase in size and importance could hardly have proceeded unless they had been reinforced by the inhabitants of surrounding districts. Herein is our difficulty. When society was organised in households, and men were bound to the soil either by proprietary rights or personal obligations, there could be little freedom of movement ; it is not easy to see from what sources the population that was aggregated in the towns could be drawn. It may be that there really was more fluidity than is commonly supposed^; but in any case it is possible to call attention to some social elements which were capable of taking a part in facilitating the growth of towns, as populous places with internal trade among the inhabitants. We must remember, moreover, that there is no difficulty about the origin of some of the most important towns of Christendom ; ' Arnold, Vtrfassungsgeschichle, II. 126. ' Inama Slernegg, II. 31, and III. 29. 58 Western Civilisation. [book IV. Cologne, Mayence, Strassburg, Paris, Bordeaux, and many others had probably survived as populous centres from Roman tijnes ; the inhabitants seem never to have lost their habits of economic independence even though their powers of municipal self-government were swept away. In many places in France the citi remained as a monument of the old days, to be the nucleus of a new growth ' ; and in all such cities there would be several proprietors, and facilities for the purchase of food and opportunities of hiring labour, or being hired as a labourer, would be perpetuated. The Roman cities of northern France and of the Rhine valley may have been reduced to the greatest poverty, but it appears that they continued to exist as towns, in the economic sense of the term. The growth of a town at a wholly new centre presents greater difficulty; but where several distinct proprietors were residing in close proximity to any point which was favourable for trade, there would be at lea,st the nucleus of a true town '. There were other social elements, however, which were ready to group themselves round this nucleus, and as they prospered they secured possessions and a footing in the towns. So far as the towns which grew up round monasteries are concerned, we see that the increased trade of religious communities during the eighth and ninth centuries involved the employ- ment of a considerable number of outside agents. Whatever the precise status of the negociatores may have been, they are definitely distinguished from the colon i a.nd serfs; if they were not so far dependent on the monastery as to be able to claim allowances from it, they would have to procure supplies by purchase and would find a market a convenience. * Flach, Let origines de I'ancienne France, II. 244. ' The possessors of land on the site where trade was springing up were the ancestors of the urban aristocracies of which we hear in the eleventh and twelfth centuries. This was the principal period of the straggle between the landed aristocracy and the trading interests, for power to control the government of the towns. CHAP. I.] The Foundations of Society. 59 Other elements would help to swell the lower grades of society in the nascent towns. Places which enjoyed the right of asylum and sanctuary' would attract fugitives from justice. Charles the Great insisted on the return of robbers and fugitive slaves", but other refugees were apparently retained; and as there was no obligation to maintain them in idleness they would probably be set to work for wages. There were other elements of roving population ; pilgrims were passing to and fro, and alien merchants were constantly on the move. They were definitely recognised in the Carolingian legislation, for the missi were to report to Charles on the advenae^ that came into their districts ; some of them might be attracted to settle permanently and contribute to the growth of a town. Some of the artisans appear to have been free ; but even those who were not their own masters might occasionally migrate; Bishop Gebhart was able to secure that a large number of his people should settle in the neighbourhood of the monastery he had founded at Petershausen*. One great reason which would induce men to draw together and reside in contiguity with their neighbours was the need of protection. This was especially felt in districts which were exposed to the ravages of the Norsemen and the Huns"; and the humbler classes would find it to their advantage to live under the shadow of a royal palace, an episcopal residence, or a great monastic household, where defence could be regularly organised. In its external aspects the tenth century town was before everything else a burg or fortified place, and many continental towns long preserved the character of military strongholds. The neighbourhood of a monastery might be less secure than that of a fort, but the trading immunities ' Imbart de la Tour, op. cit. p. 80. ' Capitular., A.D. 806; Migne, I. 303, c. 5. ^ Capitular., A.D. 806; Migne, i. 303, C..5, 306, c. 5. * Hegel, Entstehung des deutschen Stddtewesens, 117. ° W. Arnold, Verfassungsgesckichte, II. 130. 6o Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. possessed "by many of the religious houses must have been an attraction to settlers who hoped to share in these commercial privileges. The towns of the thirteenth century were not, however, a mere congeries of atoms attracted by the opportunity of protection and maintained by the facilities for trade; there were connecting ties in each town, consisting of the rights and obligations which were common to the inhabitants, or to some portions of the inhabitants, and which helped to give these groups some semblance of unity. There was, for one thing, in many of the Roman towns, common ownership of land. Besides the arable fields, which belonged to particular proprietors, there were common lands which supplied pasturage for the cattle'. The history of Nimes supplies a case in point ^; and in many other instances when an agricultural unit developed into an industrial or commercial town, the existence of the common fields must have been an important bond of union among the inhabitants', while it served as the basis for the usual food supply*. The common enjoyment of market rights was another bond of union among the townsmen. Practical facilities for the exchange of goods are, as we have seen, involved in the very idea of a town j but it seems to have been only gradually that the privileges, fiscal and legal, connected with the holding of a market were clearly defined ; the grant of such privileges by charter may in some cases have instituted a market and in others have transformed an irregularly held market into a * Lamprecht, Deutsche Geschichte, iv. •214. ° Daieste de la Chavanne, Classes Agrkoles, 117. Rietschel, Die Civitas, 61, 87. ' Maitland, Township and Burgh, 50. ■■ On the agricultural organisation at Rome in 1030 A.D., see Rodo- canachi, Corporations ouvriires H Rome, I. x. When new towns were planted in the twelfth century the agricultural conditions were carefully considered. S. Thomas Aquinas, De reg. princ. 11. 4. CHAP. I.] The Foundations of Society. 6i tnercatum legitimum^. Markets are frequently mentioned in the Capitularies, and Charles endeavoured to keep the right of making these grants entirely in his own hands. It is by no means clear in many documents whether the market referred to was an annual fair which served as the resort of strangers and a centre for foreign trade, or merely the weekly market which furnished supplies to the townsmen. In either case transactions were carried on under regal (or seignorial) authority 5 this was symbolised by the market cross, bearing the glove and sword, as tokens of the impersonal presence of the king and the duty of preserving his peace". Where a market was thus legally established it became the interest of neighbouring proprietors to obtain a house in the town', so as to share in these privileges, and bring their estates within the range of the increasing opportunities of trade. The common obligations, which drew the townsmen to- gether, were in part connected with the rights already specified ; there were fiscal burdens connected with the ownership of land, and compositions to be paid in order to free the trade of the townsmen from the usual tolls. There were also military duties to be discharged ; and the maintenance of the walls of mediaeval towns, together with the duty of manning them, must have been a very heavy burden on the property and the time of the burgesses. Much of the interest of the constitutional history of the towns lies in the story of the efforts of the inhabitants to free themselves from the discharge of these obligations, and to extort rights of self-government from the royal, noble, or ecclesiastical authority under whose patron- age and by whose favour the town had grown up. ^ 'RoM^xu, Droit des marMs, 145, 175. ' R. Sohm, Entstehung des deutschen Siddhwesens, 18. Of course suc- cessful attempts were made to encroach on this royal right, as on others, Huvelin, op. cit., 183. ^ In Domesday Book such houses were rated along with the estates, and did not form part of the town for fiscal purposes, e.g. Brightwell, D. B. l. 58 ; Mailland, Domesday Book and Beyond, 179. 62 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. Such were the chief elements which went to constitute twelfth century cities, and which were differently combined in the history of particular places. We certainly cannot account for the revival of city life in general by reference to any single element alone ' ; the increase of trade could not by itself bring about the growth of towns as distinguished from the expansion of households. In the twelfth and thirteenth centuries the constitution of a town and the importance of fostering town life were generally recognised and understood ; and conscious efforts were made by kings and nobles to plant such centres, and thus to develop the trade of their territories. Many towns' were established in Saxony in the thirteenth century in connection with the mining industry, and free towns were founded in the English possessions in France at favourable points for trade*. We may now turn from the consideration of the conditions under which towns originated and came to be organised communities, to look at their internal life before the thirteenth century. The scattered hints furnished by contemporary his- torians throw but little light on the subject; there is good reason to believe, however, that those who had proprietary rights in the land of the tovm formed a local aristocracy', and that their descendants long continued to enjoy a superior status; but they were not able to maintain their position as an exclusive caste permanently. The trading interests came more and more to be the leading factor in the prosperity of the towns; and the institutions which were organised for commercial purposes and which did not exclude either the 1 Flach, II. 3^6; also see Pirenne (Revue historique, 1895, vol. LVII. P- 65), who shows by specific instances that the origin of towns cannot be attributed either to monasteries, fortresses, or markets alone. 2 Pirenne (Revut historique, 1895, vol. LVII. p. 6S), "Les villas sont n^es spontanement sous Taction des causes economiques qu'a suscitees en Europe la renaissance du commerce et de I'industrie. " ' Inama Sternegg, in. i. 1, 11. n. * See below, p. 91. " W. Arnold, Zur Geschiehte des Eigentkums in den deulschen StadCen 10. CHAP. I.] The Foundations of Society. 63 landed or the landless man, gradually attained to considerable power. Some of these gilds and associations can be traced back to very early times, and we may also detect rudimentary forms of commercial regulation. The history of these bodies is exceedingly obscure, but it becomes less confusing if we fix our attention on the different functions they subserved. The active^ trade of the Carolingian period was carried on by caravans of merchants who travelled together for mutual protection, since solitary travelling was practically impossible. The caravan might swell to an extraordinary size as the merchants might be accompanied by a crowd of pilgrims who were glad of the convoy through perilous places; and some sort of rule and governance was necessary among this moving throng °- The organised caravan is the most primitive type of association among enterprising merchants ; and would easily lead to the institution of depots at the points which these travellers habitually visited, and where they desired to find warehouses for their goods and accommodations for man and beast. The commercial factories of foreign merchants, like the Steelyard in London, where the men of the Emperor resorted', seems to follow naturally on the localisation of organised bodies of travelling merchants^ Such depots, which furnished permanent links between a town and distant lands, seem to have arisen with the growth of mediaeval commerce, but it is at all events possible that other forms of mercantile association survived from Roman times. In any case where the food supply of a city was drawn, not from its own fields, ' Active trade is done by merchants who buy goods and adventure with them, seeking for purchasers. " Doren, Untersuchungen zur- Gesckichte der Kaufmannsgilden in SchmoUer's Stoats u. socialwissenschaftliche Forschungen, xv. ii. 162 ; Lamprecht, Deutsche Gesckichte, in. 27. * Lappenberg, Geschichte des deutschen Staklhofs tu London, ii. i. <" The hanse of which we read at S. Omer (Giry, S. Omer, 413) ap- pears to be the local depot of Flemish merchants associated for active trade to England. 64 Western Civilisation. [book iv. but by trading with outlying districts, the organisation of an active carrying trade was almost essential ; the men who con- ducted the traffic on the Seine and the Loire were well-known associated bodies in the eleventh century; and it. is at least possible that they were not a new creation, but maintained an unbroken tradition from the days of the Empire'. There is another commercial institution of which frequent mention is made, but the hints regarding its character and purpose are so meagre that it is impossible to speak of them with any confidence. The information that has come down to us is not, however, inconsistent with the hypothesis that the gild merchant was an organisation which was formed in many towns with the view of enabling the inhabitants to engage in passive trade, on the most advantageous terms'*. The gild merchant seems to have consisted of all the inhabitants of a town, rich or poor, who had occasion to buy and sell'; it would doubtless be an advantage to them all to have the means of making purchases from travelling merchants by a collective bargain, with the view of afterwards sharing the goods among themselves. There seems to have been some stage of municipal development when the gild merchant was a highly prized institution; though many important towns dispensed with it altogether, and others soon outgrew it and allowed it to fall into desuetude. There does not seem to be any analogue to this institution in the municipal life of the Roman Empire. ' Pigeonneau, i.*33, 114. ' Rodocanachi (Corporations, p. xiv.) regards the possession of com- mercial tribunals as the main element In the formation of the Mercanzia at Rome. It appears to have arisen out of the combination of earlier asso- ciations in the xiitli, and to have lost its importance as particular crafts withdrew from it in the xivth century. lb. pp. xii, xviii. ' See Gross, Gild Merchant, I. J07 ; M. Bateson, Leicester, p. xxix. ; Mayer, Zoll, Kaufmannschaft u. Markt in Germanistische Abhandlungen, p. 450: Gild Merchant of Shrewsbury in Royal Hist. Soc. Trans. N. S. IX. 99; Giry, S. Oiner, a8i; also Pirenne, Revue historique, LVil. p. jy. CHAP. I.] The Foundations of Society. 6$ The organisation of industry in craft gilds comes into clear light in the twelfth century, when we have documentary evidence of the cordwainers at Rouen, and the weavers at London and elsewhere. It seems possible that they are a branch of household organisation^, which came to have a public position when any occupation ceased to be a domestic employment and was organised on an independent basis. But the analogy between the mediaeval craft gilds and the Roman collegia is so close that it is difficult to suppose that the craft gilds or industrial organisations were never a survival which was maintained among the economically independent inhabitants of ancient cities, but always a new development transferred from the royal household to the population that gathered beside it. There seems to be no conclusive evidence of the continuous existence of the collegia even in Rome itself, and the hints which we get of their persistence at other centres are very scanty"; but they are sufficient to make the hypothesis of survival in Roman cities and diffusion from them more probable than the view which assigns to them an entirely independent origin. Of institutions which were formed for other than trading or industrial purposes it is unnecessary to speak here, though they may doubtless have had much to do with the develop- ment of municipal constitutions. There were gilds which Charles attempted to suppress*, they seem to have been analogous to the English frith gilds" which served as associa- ' On the anticipations of craft organisation in the time of Charles, see Gareis, op. cit. p. ^247. Compare the Assize of Bread under Henry II. Cunningham, Growth of English Industry, I. 568. In cases like the moneyers, when public administrative functions and worlc were com- bined, the household is a probable source of derivation. ^ Rodocanachi, Corporations ouvriires h Rome, pp. viii, xi. ' Martin Saint L^on, Corporations de Metiers, 28 ; E. Mayer, Deutsche u. franzosiche Verfassiingsgeschichte, I. 330. •• Inama Sternegg, I. 263. * Pirenne in Revue historique, LIIT. 63. C. W. C. II. J $6 Western Civilisation. [book iv. tions for the prosecution of felons. They possibly helped to train the inhabitants of a town to mutual help, and gave them practice in self-government so that they may have served as a preparation for the growth of the communes, when civic life received its great impetus at the era of the Crusades'. But from the economic standpoint such associations were not of first-rate importance ; and the city life to the growth of which they contributed was after all not a new social type, but only the reviving of a form that had already played a notable part in the history of the world'^. 87. The resuscitation of town hfe was the last stone' in the foundations of mediaeval Christendom; Obedlenc"^" many flourishing towns had revived or grown up in Flanders, Germany, France, and Italy before the thirteenth century, and if we attempt to survey society in Western Europe at that date, we cannot but feel that despite the political and racial divisions, and the area ovei which it extended, Christendom was extraordinarily homo- geneous and was bound together by very firm ties deeply imbedded in its structure. Just as in India at the present time the common institutions of Brahmanism give a unity to the social system of all Hindus, whatever may be their lan- guage or their polity, so the common religious life of Chris- tendom affected every aspect of society. We should remember, too, that there was a body politic, or at least a social organism, in the twelfth century : the peoples of Western Europe were no longer a military Empire held together by the personal ascendancy of a single ruler, Jike Charles the Great, but formed a vigorous polity which" |iad grown up everywhere under similar influences, and which was in all its parts con- nected with the centre at Rome. 1 See below, p. 89. " See vol. I. p. 93. ' It had been the first thing of which we have any knowledge in the growth of Phoenician, Greek, and Roman civilisation, ' CHAP. I.] The Foundations of Society. 6j The monasteries, as Christian colonies, had been brought to conform to the rule of S. Benedict, and thus came to have a special allegiance to the Holy See^ ; to Rome the trains of pilgrims wended their way along the commercial routes ; while it was from Rome that archbishops received the pallium which marked the dignity of their office^; and the papal theory of the relations of Pope and Emperor triumphed at last. Each of the elements in the reviving civilisation of the Dark Ages had close connections with the Eternal City, from which the known world had been ruled in imperial times. There were three great threads that ran through the whole social system of Christendom. First of all there was a common religious life, with the powerful weapons of spiritual censure and excommunication which it placed in the hands of the clergy, so that they were able to enforce the line of policy which Rome approved. Then there was the great judicial system of canon law, a common code with similar tribunals for the whole of Western Christendom, dealing not merely with strictly ecclesiastical affairs but with many matters that we should regard as economic, such as questions of com- mercial morality, and also with social welfare as affected by the law of marriage and the disposition of property by will. Lastly, there was the payment of heavy dues to Rome ; these were partly connected with the administration of canon law, and partly consisted of papal taxation of various kinds. The collection of this revenue gave rise to an enormous fiscal system : the agents who administered it were Italian bankers and their partners, and these papal merchants were settled all over Western Christendom. It was thus that a clerical organisation held the whole social system together. Each of these sides of the united life of Christendom, whether religious, legal or financial, came to be the subject of attack at the Reformation. We may say 1 WorAAsmlottt, Monks of the West, ir. 345 — 347. * Collier, Ecclesiastical History 0/ Great Britain, I. i6r. 6S Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. that in Germany there was a genuine revolt against abuses in connection with religious belief and practice; in Bohemia, on the other hand, the pressure of papal taxation had given occasion to indignant feeling for generations before the out- break came; this was also true of England, though the final breach in our country occurred in regard to the administration of canon law, and the hearing of the king's cause. But the violence of the rupture in each case helps to show how firm the ligaments had been that bound the social system together. The advantages of the new order, as compared with the ancient empire of the Caesars or with the chaos that followed on its fall, are so obvious to us, that we are apt to underrate the difficulty of accounting for the growth of the new society, as we find it in the twelfth century*. If we are content to draw on our imaginations and people the Dark Ages with men of modern type capable of cherishing our ideals and being influenced by our motives, we can then trace the course of the change in terms that are plausible throughout, and that lay stress on utilitarian aims and motives of political expediency as accounting sufficiently for the progress that occurred. But the problem is not so easily solved; we have to do not merely with the revival of ancient society in its old- form, but with its transformation. To maintain law and order when once they are established is comparatively simple ; it is a very different thing to create respect for Ufe and property anew. We can only understand the course of the recon- struction of society when we enter into the definite ideals which the men of the Dark Ages set before themselves as concrete things to be aimed at, and the motives which appealed to them personally, with their experience and their beliefs. 1 After the twelfth century there was more' direct influence from imperial institutions through the revived study of Civil Law, and also through the more frequent intercourse with Constantinople which was brought about by the Crusades. CHAP. I.] The Foundations of Society. 6g We must not only consider the enormous difficulties to be faced, but the means that were available for dealing with them. When we thus understand the complexity and con- ditions of the problem, we may see that there is only one suggestion which offers a simple, and at the same time a sufficient, solution of all the difficulties of the case. Chris- tianity furnished the new ideals, and furnished also new and powerful motives which appealed to individuals strongly, so that they set themselves to realise their aims. The Roman Empire had lingered on as the type of a decadent society, which offered no high views of life, and supplied few effective motives for individual self-discipline and energy'. Christianity brought about the resurrection of a new society, because it was not the mere sentiment of pious individuals, but a living force which permeated all the remnants of civilisation, and guided the energies of those by whom these various elements were built up into the great mediaeval polity. ^ Vol. I. p. 192. CHAPTER II, NATURAL AND MONEY ECONOMY. 88. In the preceding paragraphs we have endeavoured Material to point out the chief factors in the recon- reiics of struction of civilised society in Western Europe ; mediaeval -i i r i. prosperity; we must now descnbc the character of the ecclesiastical, economic institutions of mediaeval Christendom, domestic. and examine their working when they were at their best. Nor need we have much doubt as to the period during which Christendom reached the highest point of ma- terial well-being, according to the test we have habitually used'. The thirteenth century was one of the great eras of the world's history, an age of remarkable artistic and poetic production, of unrivalled philosophical and legal acumen^, of military expeditions and commercial enterprise. It was an age, too, that has left abundant evidence of its material pros- perity in the magnificent buildings which remain; sometimes they are in ruins, and sometimes they have been restored ; but however they may have suffered, they force us to feel what large resources were at the command of those who were able to carry out their designs on so grand a scale. The churches of Christendom — cathedral, parochial, and conventual — as they still remain, are among the most im- pressive monuments of the architectural activity of the twelfth 1 Vol. I. p. 8. * On the study of Roman Law, see below, p. iji. CHAP. II.] Natural and Money Economy, 71 and thirteenth centuries ; but many of them have perished utterly. The changed taste of a later age has done much to obliterate the evidence as to the number and grandeur of the edifices which were erected by the Normans in the lands which they conquered'. Not only was there a very general recon- struction of the older and more meagre ecclesiastical buildings, but there were also many wholly new foundations. The reform of the monastic life which emanated from Cluny and Citeaux, and gave rise to the new orders, was the sign of a fresh enthusiasm for a stricter religious life, which expressed itself most fittingly in the severely beautiful churches of the Cistercians. The witness of the ecclesiastical buildings is writ large as one of the features of the landscape through- out Western Christendom, and tells of a lavish devotion of wealth and vigour to the maintenance of Christian worship and the furtherance of pious objects. There had of course been numerous sacred temples in the old world, and a great deal of art was lavished on the service of the gods ; it is easy to trace analogies between the practices of paganism and the superstitions of the middle ages; it is not hard to shew that rites and legends from the old world had survived, and were sometimes revested in a Christian dress, when they were not so plainly unchristian'' that it was obviously necessary to stamp them out. But it is of less importance to note these superficial and occa- sional resemblances than to mark the fundamental differences. In the ancient world, religion, springing as it did from family rites and civic duties, was intensely local; the philosopher could find resemblances between the gods of different lands and give the cults a spiritualised significance ; but the religion of the individual, or of the city, was imbued with material elements, personal and local*; the one common bond ^ E. S. Prior, History of Gothic Art in England, 34. * L. Eckenstein on S. Agatha in Woman under Monasticism, p. 15. * Fustel de Coulanges, La citi aiitiqtte, (1895), pp. 37, 167. ^2 Western Civilisation. [book IV. through the ancient empire was the worship of the Emperor — of arbitrary human will. In Christendom there was one religion which was common to all; it might be localised at some particular spot, which had been the scene of a spiritual triumph— like the sepulchre at Jerusalem, or in a far less degree the cave at Subiaco — it might be hallowed by the treasured relics of some victor for the faith; but this was a spiritual faith and therefore without distinctions of person, place, or time, even when it was localised here by special associations and degraded there by admixture with pagan survivals. The internal struggles of Christendom gave rise to the scandal of conflicting appeals to one God to support the cause of rival claimants, but we no longer see the struggle of gods with gods'. There was a fundamental unity of Chris- tian faith and sentiment underlying all the differences of race and interest. Religious motives might be brought into play so as to give more vehemence to human passions; religious principles might be alleged to excuse the direst crimes ; but there was after all a common ground on which men could meet, one centre to which they could look, and a definite cause which they had at heart. The churches of Christendom are the outward and visible signs of a common religious life such as was entirely strange to the ancient world ; they are monu- ments which serve to remind us of the fact that one religious and legal organisation ran through the whole social structure. Churches and ecclesiastical edifices are among the most prominent vestiges of mediaeval culture ; but there are, besides, buildings which remain to testify to the high development of other sides of life. The crusades were the outcome of re- hgious enthusiasm, but they were also partly due to com- mercial motives, and they proved to be the means of introducing a new era of mercantile enterprise, which greatly affected the towns of Italy and Flanders, and to a certain extent of Germany, France, and England. Costly Town Halls ' Fustel de Coulanges, La citi antique, p. 175. CHAP. II.] Natural and Money Economy. 73 survive to commemorate the greatness of some of these trading centres. Such civic buildings served the same purposes as the basilicas of the ancient world; and, though there were no edifices which attained the magnificence of the range of fora which were grouped near the Capitol of Rome', there was enough grandeur to excite the admiration of those who look back from a utilitarian age. The piazza S. Marco at Venice, the Loggia at Florence, the city buildings at Bruges and Ghent, are at least striking memorials of newly developed commercial intercourse and of a municipal prosperity which had been unknown for centuries. Though the arts of peace were thus flourishing once more, the thirteenth century was an age of frequent warfare ] houses of every kind were .built in a fashion which rendered them susceptible of defence. The great castles which overshadow the towns of France and Germany have their counterpart in the fortresses which Edward I created around and throughout the principality of Wales. The art of military^ fortification had been greatly developed by contact with the East, and the means of defence far excelled the forces of offensive war- fare. The castles of great nobles were places from which defiance could be easily hurled at an emperor or king; the walls of the cities enabled the burgesses to struggle for the maintenance of liberty ; while the towers of parish churches and the buildings of mediaeval manors were capable of offering protection from hurried raids. The military and domestic, no less than the ecclesiastical and civic buildings which sur- vive, tell us something of the characteristic features of life in the halcyon days of mediaeval Christendom. The enumeration of these architectural monuments may serve to remind us of the different types of institution which we must study in turn, if we hope to understand their eco- nomic working. On the one hand these edifices bring before 1 Hodgkin, Italy, IV. 104. " As «^. at Chateau Gaillard, Oman, ^ History of the Art of War ,'^. t^'i,^. 74 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. us the far-reaching ecclesiastical system which had been con- sciously developed on similar lines throughout the whole of Christendom. Other buildings enable us to recall the city institutions, with the facilities they afforded for intercommuni- cation and trade between different points throughout Europe. There are others still which help us to form a vivid image of household administration of different sorts, as it existed in the castles of kings and barons, the palaces of bishops, and even in the monasteries or the manors. The principal groups of architectural remains correspond to the three different types of social organisation which have left their mark on Modei-n Europe. 89. The thirteenth century was, as has been pointed out, a period of great material prosperity : but it was tion from also an age of rapid transition, one might almost natural to gg^y gf economic revolution. The revival of money ■' economy— commercial intercourse and development of pro"gress!'°"^' trading centres had brought about a wide diffusion of money, which tended to the sub- stitution of money bargains for payments rendered in service and in kind. The government, ecclesiastical as well as civil, was keenly alive to the financial convenience of a money revenue, in respect to collection, transmission, and methods of account. The system of natural economy as embodied in Frankish institutions was passing away ; and the pressure of the demands of fiscal officials forced proprietors generally to reorganise their establishments with the view of obtaining a money income from their estates. The course of the transition from natural to money economy — from barter and payment in service to the use of coin — gave rise to many practical problems, and called forth a great deal of learned discussion. A mass of records and some literature survive, especially from English sources, which enable us to study some typical phases of society, as drawn by contemporary hands, and to distinguish the factors which contributed to this important CHAP. II.] Natural and Money Economy. 75 change. We can best understand the working of the social institutions of the day when we view them in connection with this economic revolution. In the preceding volume of this essay it has been necessary to call attention to other instances of the same revolution, and to note the substitution of money for natural economy, as we find it in the ancient world'. The difificulty of collecting a money revenue from the rural population was one that taxed the ingenuity of Babylonian and Ptolemaic financiers. We have also seen what dangerous power was exercised by the moneyed class in Rome, and how greedily they availed them- selves of their opportunities for becoming rich at the expense of subject peoples. Money economy had also imposed a heavy burden on the poor cultivators of Attica in the time of Solon. On the other hand we may remember that the introduction of a money economy into the Greek cities was one of the conditions which rendered the diffusion of political interest and power possible. All these phenomena may be found once more, in different forms and on a different scale, but with results that are at least so far analogous that they prove very instructive. Though there were many mitigating circumstances in mediaeval as compared with ancient times, the pressure of the change was doubtless very severe ; and there was a bitter feeling against the Jews and other bankers who had a partial monopoly of the medium of exchange. The convenience of the monetary system was, however, so great, both for fiscal purposes and as a means of opening up the possiKility of commercial and industrial development, that the revolution was inevitable : had it not occurred, all human progress would have been arrested at a primitive ' stationary state,' with society organised in household groups. The economic advantages which have accrued from the general introduction of money are clear, if we contrast Western civilisation to-day with the 1 Vol. I. 73, 100, 114. 76 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. condition of Europe in the time of Charles the Great; and we must remember that this economic step in advance rendered political and constitutional progress possible, both in the ancient and in the mediaeval world. It was not until public burdens were reckoned and collected in terms of money, that it was feasible for the subjects to aim at controlling the power of the purse. So long as revenue was obtained in different forms, it was very difficult to unite the various sections of the community in common action, and it was im- possible to criticise the financial administration intelligently and effectively. The connection between the new economic con- ditions and political progress is most noticeable in the history of the European country which first adopted representative institutions. Constitutional progress followed very closely on the administrative changes which took place in England be- tween the time of the Confessor and the time of Edward I. The system of collecting revenue in money, instead of relying on payment in kind and on service personally rendered, made for more effective government in every department, and it was a necessary step for the attainment of the prized power of the English citizen to control and to adjust taxation. When the customs on imports consisted chiefly of tuns of wine, and traditional dues were habitually levied, there could neither be the control of taxation, nor the attempts to adjust its incidence with which we are familiar. The introduction of money economy had been a necessary step without which the Greek citizen could not be his own master and have free time fot political duty ; it was also a necessary step in English political development; it brought into light what concerned all, and made it possible that the common obligations should be discussed by all. In the thirteenth century the life of cities, the ecclesiastical organisation of Christendom, and the administration of king- doms, were all becoming permeated by money economy ; but there must have been many relations of life into which it CHAP. 11.] Natural and Money Economy. 77 rarely entered, even in advanced communities. After all, the towns of Western Christendom were comparatively small ; the rural population was relatively far larger than it is to-day, and among the rural population in the thirteenth century natural economy was dominant^ and recourse to money payment was not habitual, even when it was frequent. The serfs put in their work, and were generally remunerated by rations and by the holdings which they cultivated on their own account; in other cases the produce of a holding might be divided proportionately between the cultivators and the owner of the soil. Occasional pecuniary demands pressed heavily on rural proprietors, who habitually dispensed with money and organised their establishments on a self-sufficing basis, and it is in their case that we realise most plainly the difficulties caused by the transition from natural to money economy. 90. Commercial and financial questions became so promi- nent in the thirteenth century that they attracted The me- a great deal of attention from men whose intel- of^prfcel'ltr^ lectual acuteness was very remarkable. A con- fundamental siderable body of economic literature of various its practical kinds has survived from that time. In so far applications. as it is merely descriptive it is of great interest to the historian ; but it has an even higher importance when it contains prin- ciples and enunciates maxims for the practical conduct of affairs. There were many evils in the business life of the time which it was desirable to check ; and definite principles as to what was right and wrong in monetary transactions were formu- lated by contemporary moralists with the view of establishing the grounds and limits of wise interference in matters of trade. Their economic analysis was very defective, and the theory of price which they put forward is untenable; but the ethical standpoint which they took is well worth 1 In the middle of the eighteenth century a large proportion of the rent of many estates in Scotland was paid . in kind. 11. G. Graham, Social Life of Scotland, 1. 4. 78 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. examination, and the practical measures which they recom- mended appear to have been highly beneficial in the cir- cumstances with which they had to deal. Their action was not unwise; their common-sense morality was sound; but the economic theories, by which they tried to give an intel- lectual justification for their rules and their practice, were quite erroneous. In modern times the form of economic doctrine has been affected by the fact that it has been so much discussed by men who were accustomed to deal with physical and mathematical problems, and who brought their habitual methods of reason- ing to bear on the phenomena of supply and demand. In a similar fashion the economic doctrine of the thirteenth century in Christendom was affected, as far as its form was concerned, by the engrossing studies of the time; economic problems were discussed by men who were habituated to the methods of metaphysics. In accordance with current modes of thought, they tried to determine an ideal standg-rd which should be realised in particular transactions, and sought for a definite conception of a "just price"; the practical enquiries then resolved themselves into means for discovering the just price of each particular thing. From the modern point of view this whole quest was quite chimerical : prices are always fluc- tuating, and must from their very nature fluctuate. According to the "plenty or scarcity of the time" there will be great dif- ferences in the quantities available, and therefore in the relative values, of wheat, cloth, coal and commodities of every sort. We know too, that the commodity used for money must vary in value from time to time, and that therefore there must be continual fluctuations not only in values but in prices as well. The attempt to determine an ideal price implies that there can and ought to be stability in relative values and stability in the measure of values, — ^which is absurd. The mediaeval doctrine and its application rested upon another assumption, which we have outlived. Value is not a CHAP. II.] Natural and Money Economy. 79 quality which inheres in an object, so that it shall have the same worth for everybody ; it arises from the personal prefer- ences and needs of different people, some of whom desire a given thing more and some less, some of whom want to use it in one way and some in another. Value is not objective, — intrinsic in the object, — but subjective, varying with the desires and intentions of the possessors or would-be possessors ; and because it is thus subjective, there cannot be a definite ideal value, which every article ought to possess, and still less a just price as the measure of that ideal value. This is one of the cases where the minute analysis of a conception has had practical consequences of a very far- reaching character. So long as it was held that every object had a definite value of its own, it was plausible to say that gain could never arise by a fair exchange between two indi- viduals. If I give an equivalent in exchange for what I get, there seems to be no room for me to gain ; if I have gained by an exchange, it must be because I have not really given an equivalent, but have enriched myself at the expense of the man with whom I bargained. That one country was the better for intercourse with other countries was plain enough, since God had given different gifts to each, and the exchange of superfluities was desirable ; but the calling of a merchant who got rich in the process of exchanging was always more or less under suspicion, as it was not possible to see, from the mediaeval standpoint, how his gains could be really justi- fiable. This was one reason why mediaeval writers so strongly deprecated the action of the man who bought things in order to sell them elsewhere at a profit, and raised the price against another man who wanted to buy the same article for use on the spot. This misunderstanding, with the consequent prejudice against all commercial gain, was an element of confusion in thirteenth century discussion of business morality. While mediaeval economic theory seems to us to be non- sensical, and we find it impossible to sympathise with tlie 8o Western Civilisation. [book IV. sentiment it encouraged, we may take a much more favourable view of these writers when we turn from their doctrine of what was right, to consider the practices they condemned as wrong. This is a subject to which but little attention is given in modem days : our economic analysis shows that wherever an exchange takes place, both parties gain by it, and we are apt to jump to the conclusion that if both parties gain the transaction is fair — not perhaps according to any standard of poetical justice — but as fair as can be expected in practical life. But there may be very hard bargains when one man is able to take advantage of the temporary distress of another, or where, from superior knowledge, the merchant is able to get the better of the native from whom he buys valuable pro- ducts with some paltry truck. We feel that it is unfair for the economically strong to wring all he can out of the economi- cally weak, or to trade on terms in which "common esti- mation" is notoriously set aside. We have given up as impracticable many of the old attempts to put down hard bargains with a high hand ; but modern moral feeling does not sensibly diifer from that of mediaeval times in the desire, if it were possible, to interfere with the action of any dealers who are able to enrich themselves through the necessities or the ignorance of others, and to gain at their expense. If we tried to find a test by which to discriminate hard bargains we could scarcely do better than adopt the medi- aeval phrase and say that hardship arises when a bargain is made without reference to " common estimation." " Common estimation," according to mediaeval minds, was patent and obvious in an open market, where buyers and sellers met to- gether, and bargained over local products ; but the forestalkr, who made purchases in a private way before the goods were properly exposed to sale, seemed to be a suspicious character and to be trying to enrich himself by obtaining special terms. So far as manufactured goods were concerned, "common estimation" expressed itself in the deliberate opiiuon of the CHAP, n.] Natural and Money Economy. 8i good men of any craft, who understood the conditions of production, the expense of materials and the cost in labour, and who could thus calculate a reasonable price for one group of commodities. The principle comes out in early regulations for the price of bread, and gives some justification for the statement that the reasonable price of the Middle Ages was based on a calculation as to the cost of production'. The prohibition of trading methods which ignored the reasonable price seemed well adapted for guarding against hard bargains : in some cases, however, it was possible to go farther, and to lay down definite limits to the range of prices, or even to prescribe lists which were to be authoritatively enforced. A maximum limit was set for victuals in towns; for there was reason to fear that if the licensed victualler was too extortionate and tried to take advantage of the ignorance and necessity of the travelling merchant^, he might drive away trade from that place. On the other hand the assize of bread and beer supplied a sliding scale, which would reassure the public that a rise in the price of bread was really warranted by the state of the market, and was not merely due to the cupidity of the bakers. The fixing of a minimum limit below which goods might not be sold was probably less common, but it occurs in con- nection with the English export of wool^ to the Continent. Local feeling was very strong, and each little community would insist that it should have a prior claim in regard to the enjoyment of its own products, and that they should not be purchased at wholesale rates for transport to distant markets. The whole scheme of household economy was conducted on the assumption that each estate should be, so far as possible, ^ Ashley, Economic History, i. i. p. 138. ^ On the fixing of reasonable prices in Rome, Rodocanachi, i. p. xxx. Also for wages, ib. p. 20. Compare, for similar policy, Cassiodorus, Variae, XI. 11, 12. ' Cunningham, Growth of English Industry, I. 625. c. w. c. II. 6 82 Western Civilisation. [book IV. self-sufficing, and that the bailiff should only sell the surplus that could not be used; and, as a national economic system developed, it took similar lines, and limited export trade to the sale of the surplus for which there was no demand at home. In these cases the range of prices was limited by authorita- tive regulation, but there "were also many fixed or customary prices, which arose from attempts to express payments, regularly made in kind or service, in terms of money. Charles the Great had devised a scale to show the rate at which tribute in kind' should be accepted from the conquered Saxons. Similarly the fir ma unius noctis^ appears to have had a definite monetary equivalent in the Angevin fiscal system. In many manors too the serfs paid quit-rents, or regular sums at which their services were commuted, so that, instead of doing definite works as an obligation incidental to the possession of a holding, they enjoyed their land at a fixed money rent. In such cases the customary money payment came into vogue when natural economy was beginning to give way. 91. While so much thought was bestowed on a theory of price, and its application to business practice, rogative and it was Only natural that attention should be also the Minting dcvoted to monetary theory. The best example of Money. . ,. , . .' ■" , . , . . \ of mediaeval opmion on this subject is to be found in the Tractatus de mutatione monetarum of Nicholas Oresme ; there is no reason to suppose that this author made any considerable advance on the scientific opinion which was current before his time'; though, both from its systematic character and its popular form, this treatise has a very special interest. The author, who rose to be Bishop of Lisieux, was a scholar and a lawyer, but he was also a keen observer of actual affairs; his pamphlet, which is entirely free from scho- ^ Capitulare, A.D. 797, c. 11; Migne, 1. 202. ' Viiiugradoff, Villainage in England, 303. ' Endemann, Die nationaloekonomischen Grwtdsiilze der canonislisc/ien Lehi'e, p. 75 n. Brants, V &cotwmie politique au luoyen dge, 187, CHAP. II.] Natural and Money Economy. 83 lastic ped:intry of every kind, was written with special reference to the reckless debasement of the French coinage which had taken place under John the Good of France. Much of the interest in the treatise arises from the decided view which the author expresses as to kingly responsibility, and the limits of royal prerogative. The money of the realm belonged to the community, and the king could have no right to treat it as his own, or to alter it arbitrarily at his pleasure; if he stooped to do so for the sake of gain, he was worse than an usurer, for he was not driving a hard bargain, but extorting money from those who never bargained with him at all. His political philosophy defines the standpoint from which Nicholas Oresme treated the questions of currency. He dis- cusses the importance of the stamp on the coins, and shows that the ratio of gold to silver coin depends on the relative value of gold and silver as commodities. He deals with the expedient of altering the denominations of current coins in order to raise their nominal value, and with the mischiefs that result from reducing the weight or debasing the fineness of the money issued from the mint. He recognises that it may be convenient to coin token money of some inferior metal, but insists that the purity of the standard coin should always be maintained. His exposition of economic doctrine is so thorough and clear, that centuries were to elapse before his treatment of monetary problems was superseded. The treatise of the French bishop is an admirable ex- position of the principles of a sound monetary system, but it gave little guidance on the practical difficulty which was felt in commercial circles of exchanging the money of one country for the current coin of another. This was a very complicated business, as there were real differences of size and fineness with which travellers could not be fully acquainted; but ac- count had to be taken of even more obscure phenomena; the same coin might have a different purchasing power in one country that was well supplied with the precious metals, 84 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. from that which it had in a land where bullion was very scarce, and the range of prices low. This simple fact of commercial experience was entirely at variance with the theory of a "just price," intrinsic in the thing itself; and the selling of coins and making a price for coins, as was done at fairs and other places of resort, appeared to be in itself a dis- reputable occupation, by which the exchanger succeeded in obtaining a sordid gain. The real justification for varying rates of foreign exchanges was unintelligible to the ordinary man of probity at the time; and the merchant had little means of checking the cambist's calculations. In the interests of commerce it was advantageous, when it was possible, to commit money-changing to responsible officials', who were under the direct control of the highest political authority. (1) Ecclesiastical and Royal Finance. 92. Such was the condition of opinion on prices and Ecciesias- Currency at the time when the system of money ticai and payment was being rapidly introduced in con- system? '* nection with transactions of every kind. The Papal pressure of papal taxation, the necessity of collection' and Collecting it, and the convenience of transmitting transmission. jj ^^^^ widely diffused influences which were steadily exerted in favour of the change. The popes had created an immense fiscal system all through Christendom; part of their income consisted of the rents drawn from the patrimony of the Church of Rome in Italy and Sicily^; but large annual payments were also received regularly from the lands of the numerous monasteries that had commended * The banker's business at Rome was regulated by the Holy See. Rodocanachi, op. cit. 11. 6. Exchange tables were organised at Dover by Edward I. in 1199. '' Fabre, &tudi sur It Liber Censuum in £coles /laufoises d'Athenes el de Rome, p. 8. CHAP. II.] Natural and Money Economy. 8$ themselves to the Apostolic See'. Very large sums were also levied as fees in connection with legal proceedings in the ecclesiastical courts, or as taxation insisted on under various forms. It would have been impossible to administer this revenue if it had been taken in kind, but when it was rendered in money it could be conveniently collected and transmitted to Rome by authorised agents, who had established themselves throughout the whole of Western Europe. The Papacy was not uniformly successful in obtaining a full recognition of its claims to raise revenue in all lands alike ; some sources of income were available, however, to a greater or less degree in all Christian countries. England was pre- vailed on to bear the burden of ecclesiastical taxation in its heaviest forms ^; the sums collected there were exceptionally large, when estimated in relation to the total wealth of that outlying and little developed land. Peter's pence had been raised since the ninth century, and the success of the Norman invasion, which had been in some sort a crusade, tended to strengthen the papal influence over ecclesiastical affairs in England". The re-organisation of the. ecclesiastical courts opened the way for more frequent appeals to Rome ; while the administration of canon law within the realm by papal officials appears to have been much more general than is commonly supposed^ These charges were a large item in the papal revenue; the income drawn, under various pretexts, from the endowments of different parishes, cathedrals or abbeys was also large. In addition to these habitual contributions there 1 Fabre, op. cit. pp. 37, 116. ^ Milman, Latin Christianity (31CI Ed.), vi. pp. 83, 290. For France see Glasson, Histoire du droit et des Institutions de France, v. ch. v. p. 263 ; also G^sqast, Prdcis des Institutions politiques en Pancienne Frame, II. 19, 24. ' The monastery of Battle was placed under direct papal control, and a great deal of English preferment came to be in the hands of papal nominees. ■• F. W. ^Maitland, Roman Canon Law in the Church of England, 113 fol. 8G Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. were also extraordinary dues, such as the tithe of all eccle- siastical property which was levied in connection with the second crusade. The claim to tax the people and the clergy was submitted to with a bad grace; but the ecclesiastical contention that the temporalities of the Church should be free from the payment of taxes to the Crown roused a prompt and effective resistance. The demands of the papal court became more and more exorbitant throughout Christendom generally in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries'; the increased reve- nues of the Church in Bohemia^, which had suddenly become a wealthy country, excited widespread jealousy and gave rise to premonitory symptoms of the Reformation. The camera, as the papal treasury at Rome was called, had an elaborate organisation^; and the money obtained in the different countries of Christendom was collected by Italian bankers who were generally known as the Pope's merchants; the papal fiscal requirements were thus the principal cause which led to the development of foreign banking*. The revenue from England was transmitted by bills of exchange, which were generally met by the exportation of EngUsh wool to Italian markets; there must, however, have been a considerable drain of bullion from the lands which were destitute of valuable products for export traded The chief agents in forwarding the money to Rome were known as depositaries, and they were ^ Gottlob, Aus der Camera Apostolica, p. 1 83. * Kautsky, Communism in Central Europe, p. 41. ' Compare Gottlob, Aus der Camera, p. 70 fol. * Military requirements sometimes necessitated the transference of large sums of money. Servois, Emprunts de S. Louis in Bibliothique de Vicole des Charles, 4"° serie, iv. 113. Besides the facilities for such business afforded by the Italian bankers [Bond, Loans supplied by Italian Merchants in Archaologia xxvin (1840)], an elaborate system for the transmission of the precious metals had been built up by the Templars. Delisle, Opera- tions financih-es des Templiers in Acad, des Inscrip. t. xxxill. (1889). » On the collection of the tithes in Greenland in \i%i see Heywood, Documenta selecta e tabulario secreto Vaticano quae Romanoruiii Pontificum erga Amei icae populos curam testantur. No. 8. CHAP. II.] Natural and Money Economy. 87 almost exclusively Italians ; but the actual work of obtaining the papal dues was done by collectors. Much of this income was doubtless collected in coin; but some of it, such as tithes, appears to have been paid in kind in the thirteenth century, and it would then be the duty of the collectors to realise the money worth of the corn or other products which came into their hands. They had also occasional opportunities of advancing silver to persons who were temporarily unable to meet the papal demands, and of engaging in a great deal of profitable, but not very reputable business. In so far as the Pope's merchants gained by carrying on foreign exchanges, they were condemned by the public opinion of the day ; and in so far as they took advantage of the necessitous, they gave rise to public scandal and brought religion into contempt. 93. The papal revenue system seems to have been entirely organised on a monetary basis. When coUection we turn to the administration of royal income ?f Royal . ^ Revenue in we get clearer light on the transition from kind and in natural to money economy, especially in the """^y- case of England, which is peculiarly rich in its financial records. The organisation of the English Exchequer as it existed in the twelfth century has been fully described by Bishop Richard in the Dialogus de ^Scaccario ; and so many of the Pipe Rolls have been published that there is abundant opportunity for becoming acquainted with the whole system of account'. There is an analogy between the sources of royal and papal income; in both cases there were certain landed pos- sessions which yielded a revenue; there were profits of juris- diction and an income arising from taxation ; though the items included, and the proportions of revenue obtained under each title, would not correspond very closely. The regular income of the king was assessed in one payment as the ferm- of the shire ; and the sheriff of each county had also to collect the sums that had accrued from any occasional or ^ Hubert Hall, Introduction in Publications oi Pipe Roll Society. 88 Western Civilisation. [book iv. additional source. In cases where he had expended money on the king's behalf, he was called upon to show his authority for making the payment ; and the balance due to the Crown was handed over in money. The coin was carefully scrutinised and tested before it was accepted and the sheriff could be de- clared quit of his responsibility as royal collector for that year. The English evidence is especially interesting, not only because it goes so fully into the system of account, the reckoning and testing of money and the giving of receipts, but because we find that so late as the early part of the twelfth century a portion of the royal taxation had been collected in kind', and the monetary fiscal system which is so fully described was, at least in its completeness, of comparatively recent intro- duction. In the time of Edward I special arrangements were made for the collection of the customs revenue. This is a matter of considerable interest, as we see that in one branch of the import trade payment in kind still held its own ; the ships from Gascony were expected to contribute one tun of wine from before and one from abaft the mast. During the reign of Edward III we have other instances of collecting taxation in kind, and the staple export trade of the country was seriously affected by royal demands. Parliament voted supplies to the king, to be taken up in the form of wool, and transmitted by royal agents to Flanders, where the proceeds of the sale were to be expended in military operations'. It thus appears that the fiscal system of England in the fourteenth century was not quite completely established on a monetary basis, since a temporary reversion to the primitive methods of natural economy was still possible. This revolution in fiscal practice could only be accomplished by the help of capitalists as intermediaries. It had been the deliberate design of William the Conqueror to organise his ' Diahgus de Scaccario, i. c. 7. ' Cunningham, Alien Immigrants, 78. CHAP. II.] Natural and Money Economy. 89 revenues on a monetary basis, and he induced some Jews to accompany him to England, as his scheme could not be carried through without the presence and assistance of moneyed men. The Crown desired to have command of money, and the wealth of the subjects generally consisted of land and goods. The Jews could be called upon by the Crown to make advances in money, while the taxes were being collected in kind and realised; or in other cases the capitalists might be willing to lend money to a taxpayer, so that he could meet the royal demands with current coin; the English Jews seem to have been of little service either to industry or commerce, but they undoubtedly facilitated the important fiscal changes which were carried out in the period succeeding the Norman Conquest. They attained their greatest prosperity and highest importance in the Jewish world' in the latter part of the twelfth and beginning of the thirteenth centuries. After that date, the more general diffusion of money economy may have limited the field for their operations, while their practical monopoly was broken down by the Italian bankers. It is at all events instructive to note that whereas William the Conqueror found it necessary to introduce the Jews into England, circumstances had so far changed that Edward I was able to dispense with their services and to expel them from the country. (ii) Civic Life. 94. When we turn from ecclesiastical and royal to civic economy, we find ourselves in a sphere where j,. . , ., the use of money had probably been in vogue Rise of the from time immemorial, since facilities for trade ommunes. were implied in the very idea of town life"; urban society and the institutions it evolved necessarily rested on this basis I ^ Jacobs, Jews in Angevin England, Introd. p. v. ' See above, p. 57. ' The full social effects of money-economy cannot be seen, however, in go Western CiviHsatioti. [book iv. Commerce had been an essential condition without which the towns of Western Christendom would not have come into being, and the development of trading intercourse in the eleventh and twelfth centuries afforded opportunities for the growth of civic wealth and power. We can trace how the tide of commercial prosperity flowed farther and farther north, first affecting the 'Italian Peninsula and the towns of Septimania and Provence, then showing itself in the Rhine lands and Flanders and the north of France, and penetrating at last across the Channel to England^ As the towns profited by increasing trade, they were able to secure a larger measure of political freedom. Sometimes, as in Languedoc, they fought for it; in other instances, and particularly in England, they purchased it; but by different stages and on different oc- casions, the towns of Christendom were able to secure muni- cipal liberties. Thus the growth of commercial prosperity was the chief condition which rendered possible the great movement known as the rise of the communes. As we have seen above, many towns had had their be- ginnings under ecclesiastical tutelage and protection; but in the twelfth century they had so far outgrown it as to aim at enjoying powers of self-government. They may have been inspired to make this attempt by some tradition of popular rights embodied in ancient customs I They would find en- couraging examples as they came to understand the practical independence which was enjoyed by Venice and Amalfi in their relations with the Emperor at Constantinople; the free cities of the Holy Roman Empire eventually attained to similar political independence'. The townsmen in France came to adopt one regular method of procedure in their opposition to the arbitrary exercise of seigniorial authority ; they usually those urban communities where elements of an old- order survived and police duty was done personally, and office undertaken gratuitously. ' Giry, in Histoire Generale, edited by Lavisse and Rambaud, II. 410. ' Ibid. op. cit. II. 423, 424. ° Ibid. op. cit. II. 439. CHAP. II.] Natural and Money Economy. 91 formed communes which were sworn associations for mutual support in their struggle for independence, and the wealthier merchants appear to have taken a prominent part in organising the movement. The formation of these communes could be represented as the action of "usurers'," and it led to the transference of power from the landed authority of Bishops and Counts to a moneyed aristocracy in each town. This revolution doubtless had its analogue in the history of ancient cities', and it is also an interesting anticipation of the contest between the landed and the moneyed interests over the power of directing the national policy of England in the eighteenth century. There were two points in regard to which the townsmen were particularly inclined to resent the interference of the lord — on the one hand they desired to evade his rights in connection with tolls, since these might prove very oppressive', and on the other they preferred not to have their legal business decided by tribunals which ignored law merchant. There was ample justification for the desire of the townsmen to have privileges of self-government; while the great landed pro- prietors, under whose patronage and protection the town had grown up, would feel a not unnatural resentment at the de- mand of the townsmen to set aside immemorial obligations and to withdraw themselves from long-established jurisdiction. The clergy and the seigneurs were on the whole decidedly jealous of the rising power of the communes. But it would be a mistake to suppose that the townsmen had to encounter uniform hostility. It was at least the occa- sional policy of the French kings to play off the rising towns against the great feudatories, and to show a friendly spirit ' See the Synod of Paris in 1213. Giry, op. cit. n. 428. " Fustel de Coulanges, La CitS Antique, p. 381. ^ On tolls in the Prankish Realm see E. Mayer, Zoll, Kaufmannschaft und Markt in Abhandlungen zum LXX. Geburtstage K. v. Maurers, p. 380 foil. 92 Western Civilisation. [book iv. towards communes outside their own domains. There were seigneurs too who realised that the commerce which centred in towns might be a source of wealth ; they allowed the villes- de-bourgeoisie ' to obtain limited privileges", which were granted by charter to townsmen, who yet had neither the common seal nor the belfry, which were the outward marks of the corporate life of a true commune. After the crusades had opened the eyes of the western rulers to the value of commerce, there was an additional incentive to the founding of city colonies which has been noticed above^ New towns and large suburbs were laid out on a definite plan, both by French kings and by Edward I in his French dominions. Montpazier* and Carcassonne are among the most beautiful examples of the types that were preferred, when a town had to be laid out afresh °, or when any considerable additions were required beyond its existing limits'. Among the cities of mediaeval Europe there were great varieties of political status and prestige ; their constitutions were very different, though most of the continental towns were ruled by an oligarchy, and the commons had but little voice in the management of affairs. The history of each town was distinct; but in their economic conditions and in their economic institutions they were much alike. Together they formed a system of similarly organised but distinct commu- nities, which served as depots for commerce, and provided facilities for inter-municipal trade. ' Giry, op. cit. II. 470. ^ These have no analogue in England, but seem to correspond to the Scotch Burghs of Barony as distinguished from Royal Burghs. ' See above, p. 62. * Turner and Parker, Domestic Architecture in England, 11. 154. ^ Compare the migration from Old Sarum and the founding of Salisbury ; see also below, Appendix. ° Such as Bury, Norwich, and Peterborough. Compare my paper on The Corrupt Following of Hippodamus of Miletus at Cambridge, Camb. Ant. Soc. Communications, 1899, IX. 421. CHAP. II.] Natural and Money Economy. 93 Each of these towns was an independent centre of civic life, and responsible for its own internal affairs; and each was forced to raise considerable sums of money for the ex- penses of its government and police, and the payment of the composition by which its privileges were secured. This revenue was raised by taxation, which seems sometimes to have been assessed on the various mercantile and industrial companies according to their standing, and sometimes to have been levied on the inhabitants by a house rate. The burgesses who paid their contributions and who had the freedom of a town were always careful to guard themselves against any intrusion on their privileges by outsiders ; as citizens the former had a recognised status wherever they travelled, and hence there came to be a marked distinction between them and those who were mere upland men and had no footing in the com- mercial society of Christendom. . The importance of city life, as a factor in civilised society, has been discussed in connection with the ancient world. In mediaeval times cities such as Venice and Genoa rivalled or excelled the commercial centres of classical times; they attained to immense wealth, and their industrial development gave them a measure of stability which Athens never enjoyed. Their commercial colonies, unlike those of the Greeks, continued to be a strength to the mother cities; but for our purpose it is unnecessary to dwell on the greatness of their military and naval power, since it was destined to pass away as national government became more effective. Civic organisation for commercial and industrial purposes has a more lasting interest; for towns remain as great economic centres, though their political importance as independent communities and the power which many possessed of pursuing separate economic aims have vanished. The very full information which survives in regard to the mercantile and industrial associations of medi- aeval cities, renders it clear that their gilds and companies were more highly organised and enjoyed a better political status than corresponding societies in the ancient world. 94 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. 95. The merchants engaged in active trade appear to have been the leaders in forming the communes, an'dFaire"** and they obtained a dominating influence in the government of each town'. They were the moneyed men and they naturally came to the front in an urban community, though the particular commercial calling that had a leading position in one city might not be specially prominent in another. The bankers, who acted as agents for the collection of papal revenue, were important people at many centres ; at Florence the merchants, who imported cloth', had a leading position; in London, the grocers, who dealt in bulky goods which were weighed by the large beam, seemed to monopolise all city dignities for a time, though the mercers, who dealt in silk and other valuable goods weighed in a small balance, had the older organisation there. These groups of merchants, associated in companies for the wise regulation of their own trades, had a practical control of the government of their' city. The whole mechanism of the commerce of the day becomes more intelligible when we study the regulations of the fairs, which were the principal trading resorts of Christendom. The most celebrated marts of the early middle ages were held in Champagne and Brie'; but there were similar gatherings in every land. The streams of commerce were too feeble to provide a constant market all the year round, at any one centre, for valuable goods brought from a distance ; trade was only occasional ; and each ' In England, where there were' few resident merchants engaged in active trade, the wealthy oligarchies did not show themselves until the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries. ^ The Arte di Calimala was engaged in the dressing and dyeing of imported cloth ; the Jrle di Lana, a manufacture of cloth in Florence, was a distinct trade which arose in the thirteenth century. Doren, Entwidelung und Organisation der Florentiner Ziinfte (in Stoats- und socialwissenschafi- liche Forschungen edited by Schmoller, xv. p. 7). " Bourqueloti &tudes sur ksfoires de Champagne in Mem. Acad. Inscrip. I™ Serie, v. p. 75. CHAP. II.] Natural and Money Economy. 95 fair in its turn gave the transitory merchant an opportunity of attending and disposing of his goods. The rules for the construction of the booths and the conduct of business were very elaborate, and when disputes arose, the courts of pie- powder exercised summary jurisdiction according to Law Merchant. But there were differences that could not be so easily settled, and that gave rise to long correspondence be- tween the authorities of different cities. A creditor would attempt to obtain payment by getting the mayor of his city to correspond with the mayor of the place where his debtor resided. We come to see that it was not as an Englishman or a Frenchman that a merchant claimed commercial status, but as a citizen of some one city; his position in his own community gave him his status in any place where merchants congregated, and assured him that any wrongs he suffered in his transactions would be dealt with, not by a ~-local custom of which he was ignorant, but according to the Law Merchant which prevailed in similar form throughout Christendom. 96. In addition to these associations of moneyed men engaged in active trade, there was also a great industrial deal of industrial organisation in mediaeval Organisation, towns. Manufacturing of various kinds was doubtless stimulated by commerce; it had to be carried on with a view to other than the local markets, or had at least to meet an increased demand as the town grew in size and population. It is difficult to believe that there could be much local organisation in any industry until there was need for the work of ten or twelve men engaged in the same craft; and it is consequently surprising that societies of craftsmen should be found so widely diffused in the twelfth century. There were weavers' gilds in Marlborough, Beverley and Oxford, as well as in London in the time of Henry I, and there was a similar institution' among the cordwainers of ' Mailin-Saint-L^on, Histoire des Corporations de Metiers, p. 57. Inama Stemegg II. 323 — 325. 96 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. Rouen, the tanners of Ghent and the drapers of Valenciennes. Though these are the earliest recorded instances, it is highly probable that some similar bodies were of very long standing in certain continental cities ; we have an account of the crafts of Paris in the thirteenth century, and when we see how largely manufacturing was developed in that city and at that date, and also how completely it was organised, we can hardly suppose that the industrial associations were all of very recent growth^ 6tienne Boileau ' set himself to give a complete account of the corps de mktier as existing in his time, and in his book we get a very clear picture of the habits and usages of the aristocracy of labour^ There were no fewer than a hundred such craft-gilds in Paris, and though they differed in many matters of detail, their general character was similar. The boy who desired to enter any of these crafts was apprenticed to a master, who was responsible for supplying the youth with food and shelter, and who was not only ex- pected to train his charge in the knowledge of his business but also to exercise such supervision over his apprentices that they might form the habits of good citizens. After serving his time as an apprentice, the workman became a valet or journeyman, who was hired by the master for longer or shorter ' The early rise of craft organisations in the mediaeval world, as con- trasted with their late development in Greek cities, is very remarkable. In so far as the gilds were utilised for grouping the inhabitants and assessing taxation, it is possible to find a clear motive for the formation of such bodies. But, when once formed, they supplied a recognised want in civic life and they continued to exist in many places till the industrial revolution changed all the conditions of work. The gild merchant was a passing phase, the craft gild came to stay. ' Le Livre des Mitiers. Edited by Lespinasse and Bonnardot. The royal attention to the organisation of industry in France dates back to the thirteenth century ; in England the organisation and control of craft gilds was attended to by the municipal authorities, who were inclined to resent outside interference in this matter. ' The unskilled labourer seems to have been very little considered in the labour organisation of the day. CHAP, n.] Natural and Money Economy. 97 periods to work for wages. If the journeyman saved or borrowed enough money to start on his own account he would try to qualify as master in the trade ; and for that purpose he was, at least in later days, required to produce an essay or masterpiece as proof of his qualifications. We are able to gather that industry was generally conducted by small capitalists; they were not mere employers, but worked themselves at the trade in which they instructed the apprentices; they might how- ever hire additional hands, and thus be employers on a small scale as well as workmen. The masters associated in the corps de mitier, or craft-gild, made regulations for the good conduct of the trade, — not merely for the technical training of workmen, but for the quality of the material and the con- ditions of work. Within each city, the corps de tnktier was empowered to- enforce its rules on those who were working at the craft; no unauthorised men who did not conform to its usages were allowed to work at the calling; and great pains were taken to prevent outsiders from acquiring any knowledge of technical processes, or other trade-secrets. In order to make and enforce these rules, a good deal of govern- ment was required, and it was necessary to provide for the administration of common funds, which were obtained partly by the entry money of apprentices and the gifts of members, and partly by fines imposed for infractions of the rules. The funds were occasionally used for charitable purposes among the mem- bers, such as gratuitous loans to a needy brother ; and they were sometimes increased by trading speculation. In some towns, the members of a gild had the option of sharing in an advan- tageous purchase made by one of their number ; and they were drawn more closely together by the enjoyment of common festivities and participation in the same religious rites. Such was the general type of the craft-gild', but there were ' The care of the mediaeval craft-gilds for the welfare of the skilled labourer distinguishes them from their analogues — the collegia of ancient Rome. Levasseur, Classes ouvrieres, i. 195. C. W. C. U. 7 98 Western Civilisation. [BOOK iv. minor differences in different countries'. On the Continent, generally, the artisan classes v/ere separated by a hard and fast line from the moneyed men, as far back as we can trace the history of town life; in London, the differentiation of the industrial and the moneyed classes can hardly be observed before the fourteenth century. In Germany, the valet or Geselle was encouraged to travel and acquire a more complete knowledge of his trade; in England, there seems to have been no such provision for industrial intercourse between different towns. The distinc- tions are so marked that it is important to study the craft- system of each city and to be careful about the danger of pressing analogies too closely. The mutual supervision by respectable tradesmen which was a prominent feature in the gild system operated in the interests of the public and of the workmen alike ; it remained in force till the organisation of business by large capitalists superseded the older system by securing thorough-going super- vision under a more flexible system. This latter method could be successfully carried on with workmen scattered in rural districts ; whereas gild supervision almost necessarily involved the residence of the workers within easy reach of one another. The highly skilled industry of mediaeval times was concentrated in cities, where it was regulated by gild ofiScials in the exercise of powers conferred on them by civic authority" ; but as 1 On the position of women in English and French craft-gilds re- spectively, see E. Dixon, Economic Journal, V. 225. ^ One important craft, that of the masons, necessarily had an extra- municipal character. A great deal of castle and church building was carried on on sites which lay beyond the range of any municipal powers; and we may think of this craft in the thirteenth century as forming a part of great royal or ecclesiastical establishments. We read of royal masons, and of > a. school of masons at Saintonge. Isenbert, their master, was recommended by King John to the city of London as a suitable person to undertake the rebuilding of the bridge. (3 John, Rot. Lit. Pat. memb. 2, no. 7.) We get much light from Cathedral fabric rolls on the organisation of the building trades in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries, when it still retained something of its exceptional character ; like other crafts, it was CHAP. II.] Natural and Money Economy. 99 it prospered and established distant connections there was need for the intervention of capitalists. Many trades were dependent on commercial facilities which could only be ob- tained at such resorts of wealthy merchants as Venice and Genoa, Florence, Augsburg or Bruges. The materials for the manufacture of silk and the finishing of cloth were imported ; and much of the wealth of these cities was due to their success in catering for distant markets, but their progress was incompatible with the maintenance of a purely civic policy. The necessity of procuring materials or of controlling a food supply forced some of the cities to take account of con- siderable stretches of territory. The city was the all-important unit for economic purposes in the later Middle Ages as the households had been in the Carlovingian times ; but economic necessities, no less than political ambitions, rendered a change inevitable, and brought about a reconstruction of the economic system, not on the narrow lines of a city community, but in accordance with the resources and requirements of extended territories'. (iii) Household Economy. 97. Long after money economy hkd ' been taken for granted in the industrial organisation of the Household urban population, it was hardly known ip rural Economy, districts, where natural economy still played an Management, important part. There is, in English 1 sources, 1 i t?ommutation. much literary evidence as to the adnjinistratiopii of a well- managed estate in the thirteenth century. /Eqonomically con- sidered, the best type known at that time was practically identical with the ideal of proprietors a thouskrid years earlier. ' > conducted on a money basis, but as it had'n^t grown up under municipal authority, it does not seem to have conlerred dn its members municipal status till a comparatively late date. ' See below, p. 148. 7—2 lOO Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. Land was ownad in large areas, and cultivated by dependents who rendered service or payrnents in kind. Such an institu- tion was fundamentally the same as the^ Roman villa, though there might be the greatest possible variety in the status and obligation of the dependents; and it bore the closest resemblance to the agricultural organisation in Carlovingian times'. We -have ample evidence as to its working from the countless surveys of estates", which are in existence and record the precise local condition of particular places in detail ; but the fullest description of the principles to be followed is to be found in treatises' on estate management which obtained a wide circulation in England during the thirteenth and following centuries. The best known of these is the Husbandry of Walter of Henley, which deals with practical problems of agriculture; the Seneschaucie gives an account of the various officials in a great household, "and their respective duties; the Rules of Robert Grosseteste are also instructive as showing the general scheme of household economy in a well-managed establishment. When we remember that great households — whether monastic or noble — were not only the chief centres for regulating agricultural work, but served the purpose of places of education, either in learning or in manly exercises, we see the importance of the part they played, and the interest of examining their economic side. In many parts of the Continent, and at the great English abbeys, tfiere were largd permanent establishments which could be supplied WitH fooA 'fi'oAi adjoining territory ; but the policy of the Corlqtibrbi' had been to give scattered and separate grants to his 'fdllbwer^,- and tj»e lands held by any one of the nobility were not ' contiguous, so that they found it con- ' Besides the Capitai'Iary ZJp 'Villis, we have the detailed Polyptyque of Abbot Irminon, edited by Guerard, and containing careful surveys of the Abbey Estates. ' Cunningham, Growth of English Industry, I. 576. * Walter of Henley, edited by E. Lamond. CHAP. II.] Natural and Money Economy. lOi venient to pass from one estate to another in turn. The long cavalcade of the travelling household must have been a familiar sight in mediaeval England, and its approach would often cause consternation to the Abbot or Prior to whom it ap- pealed for hospitality during its progress. The period which the noble owner could spend on each of his estates was calculated with care; the bailiff was responsible for the corn which was gathered at Michaelmas, and for keeping accurate accounts of the stock, as well as of the service of the villeins, or payments made in lieu of services, and of other receipts Each estate was meant to be self-sufficing, and to furnish food for the owner's household ; but there might be a surplus of produce which it was wise to sell, or there might be occasion to replenish the stores by purchase. With all his careful efforts, it was not possible for even the most prudent land- owner to keep entirely outside the circle of commerce and monetary transaction; and the more he was drawn into it by the demands for payments to royal or ecclesiastical officers or by other forces, the more ready he would be to reorganise the internal management of his estate on a monetary basis. The mass of manorial documents which survive will doubt- less afford some future student of economic history the means of tracing the progress of this change in great detail, as it occurred on one estate or another. At present, we can only trace the main types of economic relationship. We hear of free tenants, who may be regarded as appendages to a manorial estate rather than a constituent part of it. The payments they made to the lord seemed to consist chiefly of their contributions to the royal taxation, for the collection of which he was responsible. Within the manerium or villa, as an economic unit, the serfs were responsible for tilling the domain of the lord, and received their recompense in the form of land, which they cultivated on their own account, in their own time. The extent of the manor carefully noted for each season the precise number of days' work to which the lord 102 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. was entitled, as well as the payments in kind which he had an admitted right to exact ; the records of the annual reckon- ings, — or minister^ accounts, — show what services were ren- dered and payments received. In the thirteenth century this seems to have been the prevailing system j but there is ample evidence that it often proved convenient for the lord to accept money payment in lieu of service; grudged labour was not always worth having, and he might find it more prudent to supply seed himself than to rely on the quality which his serfs provided for him. Each part of the serfs obligations was assessed in terms of money ; and we find entries, even iri the earliest rolls, of oJ>era vendita when the lord exercised his right of choosing to receive money-compositions instead of exacting certain days or forms of work. In some instances, this came to be a matter of formal and permanent agreement ; but in such cases the payment made by the serf had no direct economic relation to the precise value of the holding he continued to enjoy, but was based on the value of his services, from which he was now quit. In the rapid changes which followed the Black Death, the substitution of payment in money for the practice of rendering service went on apace' ; but there was a more startling revolution im- pending. On the one hand, the hired labourers, on whom the landlords had come to depend for the tillage of their domains, demanded that their wages should be settled by competition, instead of being paid at the old customary rates of assessment j on the other, the landowners sought to recoup themselves for the loss of their power to exact labour by adopting the principle of competition in the management of their estates and letting the land to those who offered them most money for the use of it'. It was not till the seven- ' Trevelyan, Age of Wycliffe, 191. T. W. Page, Z)«« Umwandlung der Frohndienste in Geldrente, 37, 38. " In the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries the largest bids were made by sheep formers. CHAP. 11.] Natural and Money Economy. 103 teenth century that the new method of estate administration, on a monetary basis, came to be accepted as creditable, and that the principle of competition was unhesitatingly applied to the letting of land for arable purposes. The change, so slaw and so painful, and accompanied as it was by so much social disorganisation and misery in the rural districts, was inevitable when agricultural life was drawn into the range of monetary influence'. Permanent personal obligations were at first only expressed in terms of money, and from mutual con- venience they came to be more and more frequently discharged in terms of money. These customary payments, whether of rent or for work done in the rural districts, did not rest on any clear economic basis, like that of the reasonable prices which were calculated by the authorities of craft-gilds; the sums demanded were only the expressions of servile obli- gations, not the result of free bargaining over the terms of voluntary exchange. The stability of customary rates had many advantages; but occasional and obvious variations in the value of service or the value of land gave rise to a sense of grievance under this system ; and when once its advantage was questioned, there was no possibility that customary rates should be maintained. Competition was attractive, for it had the appearance of fairness at each particular moment; while rates fixed by custom only secured a fair average on the whole. The misery which would accrue from the loss of stability was not obvious; and despite the disadvantages in connection with competition we cannot regret this step in progress : it has given freedom to enterprising men to make the most of landed resources, as they could never have done while they relied on the household organisation of labour and were hampered by the restrictions of natural economy. 98. This cursory survey of the economic life of Christendom in the thirteenth century brings out some important contrasts ' More, Utopia (ed. Lumby), p. 32. Discourse of Commonweal, edited by E, Lamond, Introd. p. xlv. 104 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. with the ancient world, not only in aspirations but in actual „ ,. i institutions. Social progress had on the whole Mediaeval . , . , , ■ i ^ -j » ■ Rnd Ancient followed the hnes laid down m the Capitularies. Institutions. j^ ^^^^^^ ^^^^^ ^^^^ ^j^^ ^^^^^ ^f ^ ^gjj. organised empire of the West which Charles had had before him was at length realised, though in other conditions, and under the control of a spiritual head, not of a Frankish king. The civilisation of Charles's realm had fired the imagination of the northern peoples, and called forth their imitative efforts. They inherited much from the old Rome, but they inherited it in the form in which it had been recast by Charles the Great, both as regards political and civic organisation and in respect to commercial and industrial life, whether in town or country. This mediaeval society was in consequence permeated with moral conceptions which had been entirely strange to the ancient world ; the institutions of the Middle Ages had been gradually formed under the influence of religious principles which the old world would have explicitly denied. There was, first of all, a keen sense of personal responsibility in the employment of secular power of every kind; the responsibility of rulers to God for the exercise of their power over their subjects was strongly insisted upon, as well as the fact that the rich man must render account of the use he made of his wealth; it had been entrusted to him by God, and he ought to use it for God. That the forms of using wealth, which piety and beneficence dictated, were not always wise, is true enough. The problem of applying wealth to the best purpose for the good of man is not an easy one, even in the present day; but there was an extraordinary contrast between the spirit of the Roman Uke Cato, whose only sense of duty was to become richer, and that of the mediaeval proprietor who had learned that he was merely a trustee, and responsible for the manner in which he used his money. This lesson, so deeply ingrained in mediaeval Christendom, was an immense gain, as CHAP. II.] Natural and Money Economy. 105 we see when we compare the tone of opinion in the ancient world ; it is a doctrine that can never be discarded without serious danger so long as society continues on the lines of personal possession. The truth that property has duties and responsibilities must be realised with greater and greater clearness. The difference between the mediaeval and the ancient world comes out still more clearly in the new conception of labour. In the ancient world labour was drudgery ; and all possibilities of human advance were connected with the possession of leisure. This was fundamental in Greek life, and it was adopted in the old Rome ; but Christianity insisted that labour itself might be a discipline and might thus conduce to the ennobling of human character. When the beneficent influence of labour on character was once recognised, and a life of labour was voluntarily adopted by those who were in positions to escape it, it could no longer be regarded as in itself degrading. Serfdom existed so long as natural economy lasted, and the mediaeval conscience was only partially awakened to the evils of slavery^ ; but the dignity of labour began to receive adequate recognition. Here again we see a permanent gain for which society is indebted to the Middle Ages; that work is a duty to be done, and that a life spent in idleness and self-pleasing is wasted, is another belief which has entered deeply into the very structure of modem society in Western Europe and which had no corresponding influence in the ancient world. The main contribution of mediaeval society to the eco- nomic progress of mankind lay in its success in moralising industrial and commercial conceptions and institutions. Just as the Greek made an advance on the Phoenician by treating material plenty as subservient to human well-being and regarding it as means to an end, so Christianity re- constituted the economic life of the old world in accordance with a fuller appreciation of personal responsibility in the use ^ See below, p. 133. io6 Western Civilisation. [BOOK iv. of property, and a recognition of labour as a method of personal self-discipline. This moralisation was a very im- portant change ; as we look back we are apt to say that there were the strangest contrasts in the Middle Ages between high ideals and gross outrages, and that though there was so much parade of religion and so much machinery for the maintenance of a better morality, they were merely superficial. It is easy to assert that underneath the high claims of the papacy to repre- sent God's Will there was only priestly ambition, and that the great religious foundations of the Middle Ages were partly due to vanity and partly to base attempts to cajole an offended Deity with gifts. But it is an error to suppose that because the religion of the age came prominently before the eye, it was therefore merely external, with no real vitality; or to imagine that because the moral conscience of the day ex- hausted itself over casuistical distinctions between honest and oppressive bargains, it had no real hold upon the minds of men. The piety and morality of the age were very apparent, but they were not empty and lifeless ; just because they had expressed themselves in external forms and institutions, they had a chance of influencing individual character and working deeply into the moral consciousness ; at all events they were powerful enough to stay the disasters under which the Roman Empire fell to pieces and to pass on a great and improved tradition of active economic life. CHAPTER III. CHRISTIAN RELATIONS WITH HEATHEN AND MOSLEMS. 99. In describing the civic life of Christendom, and the progress of commerce, it has been impossible to avoid all reference to the non-Christian world ; in- . ''"'if 9f"sad- ing Spirit. tercourse with distant lands was one of the factors which helped to develop trade and town life during the twelfth and thirteenth centuries, and there have been occasional allusions to it in the foregoing pages ; but these scattered hints must now be gathered together, and we must try to take account of the trading activities of men who lived in regions where the papal power was not recognised as authoritative \ We may thus come to understand more clearly the causes which were at work in the movements that have been already discussed. Such a survey is also necessary if we would trace the ten- dencies which were leading up to the age of discovery and preparing for the commercial revolution of the sixteenth century. ' The trading relations with Constantinople are not treated separately ; much of their importance was due to the fact that that city was a depot for the commerce with more distant regions. In the period before the Crusades the intercourse between Rome and Constantinople was frequent (Heyd, op. cit. I. 94), while a great deal of commerce went on with Bari, Amalii, and other towns of Southern Italy which still preserved a political connection with the Eastern Empire. Heinemann, Cesehichte der Nor- mannen in Unter-Italien, p. 22. loS Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. Unity of religious belief and similar ecclesiastical institu- tions were the ties which bound Christendom into one organic whole ; the outside world consisted of the lands where these conditions did not obtain. There were heathen peoples who had never come under the influence of Christianity at all, and they had no scruple in plundering Christian shrines and in destroying consecrated buildings. There were also Mohamme- dans whose profession prepared them at any time to engage in active attacks on the Cross ; at best they treated the Christian population with contemptuous tolerance. The relations of the people of Western Europe with outsiders were necessarily affected by these religious differences, and were more often hostile than friendly ; indeed they were coloured by what we may call the crusading spirit. Devotion and commerce were closely interrelated in the Christian attempts to recover posses- sion of the Holy Land'. Mercantile enterprise combined with religious zeal in subtle proportions from the outset of the struggle, but the only lasting gain went to the trading interest, as merchants obtained a permanent footing in lands where the dominion of Christian rulers had been destroyed. The initiative in the earliest interference with the Heathen and Moslem worlds had been chiefly taken in the cause of religion, though organised commerce soon seized upon the lines which were thus opened up. It is most convenient to describe in turn the relations of the men of Latin Christendom with the non-Christian peoples on the Northern Seas, in the Western Mediterranean, and in the Levant and to take the beginning of the ninth century as our starting point in each case. 100. There is no more pathetic incident in the history of „. ,,., . Charles the Great than the account of his sorrow Tne Vikings and the Baltic at Seeing the sails of the Norsemen in the Medi- ommerce. terranean^ and his premonition of the mischief * Heyd, Commerce riu Levant, I. 131. ' Monach. SangalUiisis II. 14 in PerU, Mon. Germ. Script, li. 757. CHAP. III.] Relations with Heathen and Moslems. 109 which they would work in his dominions. Their rude and vigorous energy proved the scourge of many parts of Christen- dom for generations ; but when it was gradually absorbed and controlled, it furnished one of the most potent factors in the subsequent triumph and diffusion of the civilisation which Charles appreciated so highly. In the history of the lands over which Charles ruled, it has not been easy to distinguish the various racial elements, or to say how much of his system was due to Roman survivals, and how much to the Teutonic grafts which had been introduced in larger or smaller propor- tions by successive conquests. But at all events none of these peoples had betaken themselves to maritime enterprise; the piratical expeditions of the Norsemen were a new element, with which the nascent civilisation had to engage in a life and death struggle. It was the crucial test whether the new empire would succeed where the old empire had failed, and would be able to convert this strenuous barbarian life to be its defence and the means of extending its boundaries. The sagas, and the relics which have been discovered in the north, reveal the existence of a vigorous commercial life in the Baltic lands during the ninth, tenth, and eleventh centuries. It offers points of comparison which take us back to the Homeric poems and the early days of Phoenician trading in the Mediterranean. The picture of the Viking — halfmerchant and half pirate — reminds us of old acquaintances in the Odyssey and in Herodotus^ The seafaring man made a raid on the banks of the Seine or the Trent, and then, as a merchant, disposed of his booty and captives at one of the great seaside fairs. The description which Adam of Bremen gives of Birca^ supplies an instance of the commercial activity which was found at different points all through the Baltic lands, but which centred chiefly in the island of Gothland. So far as we can gather, however, this commercial activity 1 Vol. I. p. (A. ' Adam of Bremen, Gesta Hammabiirgensis Ecclesiae Pontificum, I, 63, 1 lO Western Civiiisalion. [BOOK IV. was different from that of the Phoenicians and their Greek imitators in two important particulars. It was much less completely organised; the Phoenicians had settled factories at special points ; and these were permanent off-shoots of the mother-city in distant lands, and had recognised rights and ob- ligations. But the Norse commerce does not appear to have arisen between towns and colonies; the Viking was rather the adventurer who went out to improve his fortunes as best he might, and who, if he found a favourable opportunity, established himself on an estate. The Norsemen may have had more aptitude for town life than some of the other Teutons ' ; but they were ready to become cultivators and colonists, and did not confine their energies to industry and trade. From their sagas, too, wer get an impression of the extraordinary individual enterprise in their voyages^ The most profitable commerce of the Norsemen was apparently conducted by the Elbe and the Oder and their tributaries, till they came within reach of areas from which they could find their way to the Black Sea and Constantinople. It was probably along the primeval amber routes that the vast quantities of Arabian coins were carried which have been found in Sweden'; but the Vikings ventured far beyond these limits and forced their way round the North Cape to Archangel; they even saUed to Iceland and colonised it after their fashion*. The story of the voyage of Eric the Red to Greenland gives a singular picture of their audacity; and though doubts have been cast on the alleged discovery of ' A Danish settlement was the nucleus of Cork, Waterford, and Dublin, and an important element in Derby, Leicester, London, and many English towns. " Toulmin Smith, Discovery of America by the Northmen, 311. » Montelius, Civilisation of Sweden, 191; Heyd, op. cit. I. 58. * The contrast between the legal and social conditions in Iceland (Dasent, Burnt Njat, I. xi., xlv.) and at Carthage (Vol. I. 145) accentuates the differences between Norse and Phoenician colonisation. CHAP. III.] Relations with Heathen and Moslems. 1 1 1 America by the Norsemen, there is no inherent improbability in the accuracy of the legend'. The whole description of their ruthless activity and grim humour in the sagas is of the keenest interest, as it describes the new strain which was introduced into Christendom, and which has perpetuated itself in the maritime enterprise and individual energy which charac- terise the modern world. 101. Such were the meii who were harrying Western Christendom from the north in the ninth, tenth, and eleventh centuries; but as they were gra- L^gu^^"** dually converted to the profession of Christianity, the danger which threatened the rising civilisation was averted. We need not pause to consider how far this process implied a complete alteration of personal religious belief; however un- intelligently and unwillingly they may have accepted the new faith, it brought them into line with the other peoples of the West. They ceased to plunder sacred places ; and, as a con- sequence, the most important centres of agriculture, industry, and commerce were respected, and opportunities for the unin- terrupted pursuit of peaceful avocations were greatly increased. There were various agencies through which this change was brought about : it was accomplished partly by the indi- vidual heroism of missionaries like S. Boniface, and partly by the militant Christianity of the soldiers of Charles the Great or the Teutonic knights; and despite its defects and weaknesses, the civilisation of Christendom could not but com- mand the respect of the peoples of the North. The tradition of the Imperial name was impressive ; the arts and culture of the great monasteries would move the barbarians' admiration. When any considerable bodies of the Norsemen came to settle on the territories they had ravaged, they were soon brought under the influence of the Christian religion, and adapted them- ^ The evidence has been discussed with great care by Dr O'Gorman in an article on the American Mediaeval Church in the Catholic University Bulletin (Washington D.C.), I. 41C. 112 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. selves to the habits and usages current in Christendom. The transformation in the case of the Dukes of Normandy was singularly rapid ; and the rule of Cnut must have done much to leaven lands which were still half heathen, with influences derived from his Christian dominions. The progress of Christianity, by limiting the field for Viking enterprise, appears to have exerted a repressive influence on the vigorous life of the north. Much of the Scandinavian commerce passed into other hands, especially into those of the Germans. There was a remarkable power of combination among the German townsmen in the thirteenth century; the cities on the Rhine' formed a political confederation for the security of merchants engaged in trading along the river ; and the towns of northern Germany worked in unison for the object of promoting active commerce. There had been plenty of personal enterprise in the Baltic trade from time immemorial, but the new movement, which emanated from Liibeck^, led to the founding of regular factories; an element of organisation was introduced, and Wisby became the centre of trade which had been previously carried on at other points. The German influence had made itself paramount by means of colonies established in Denmark and Prussia, and the associated towns' were able in 1284 to force the Norwegians to accord to the men of the Emperor commercial privileges of which they availed themselves greedily. These mercantile colonies of the Germans really had a civilising influence; among other things, they helped to extinguish the traffic in slaves which had been a regular and flourishing business in heathen times. Towns which had grown out of factories established in con- nection with trade served as centres where new churches were planted, so that there was a genuine expansion of Christendom ' Frignet, Histoire de V Association Covtmerciak, 131. •■ Laraprecht, Deutsche Geschichte, iv. 146. ' Liibeck, Riga, Wismar, Stralsund, GreifswaH, Rostock and Wisby. Beer, Allgcmeine Geschichte des IVelthanJels, i. 241^. CHAP. III.] Relations with Heathen and Moslems. 1 1 3 towards the North and East^ The work was carried still farther by the Teutonic Order, in accordance with the militant Christianity of the day, so that the whole of the southern shores of the Baltic, as well as Scandinavia, were brought wiJhin the circle of Western Christendom. Under the influence of these German towns the occasional commerce of the Norsemen was systematised and developed ; Liibeck, the leader, controlled the policy and directed the energies of the associated cities which eventually came to be known as the Hanse League. This body succeeded in putting down the bands of pirates, who maintained something of the old Viking tradition j they rendered the Baltic an inland sea from which intruders were warned off; and they secured a practical monopoly in the export of amber, of furs and tallow from Russia, and of fish, iron and copper from Sweden'', and they imported cloth and other manufactures in return. They had important factories at Bergen, the staple town of the Iceland trade, while they had access to Eastern routes through their establishment at Novgorod". They thus commanded lines of trade which lay beyond the purview of Charles the Great, and they had also important connections with the Danube valley, with Italy'', and with Bruges and London. During their most flourishing period they present a picture of intermunicipal commerce at its very bestj they formed a great mercantile federation, the members of which were independent internally, while they pursued a common policy in distant lands°. Their ^ Laraprecht, Deutsche Geschichte, III. 395. ^ Worms, La ligue hansiatique, 84, 90. ' Buck, W., Z>er deutsche Handel in Novgorod bis zur Mitte des xiv. Jahrhunderts, 37. * W. Stieda, Hansisch- Veneiianische Handels-beziehungen im i j Jahr- hunderte. * There was considerable friction between tlie different groups of towns in the League, but the union was none the less remarkable. The Con- lederation of Rhodes is an interesting analogy in ancient times. The C. W. C. II. 8 114 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. subsequent fall is often ascribed to the discoveries of the fifteenth century, and to their inability to adapt their restric- tive methods to the new fields of commercial activity that were then opened up ; but it seems to have begun before that era, through a general antagonism to the League as a monopoly, and in consequence of the rise of new nationalities which resented the presence of alien merchants enriching themselves out of native products. In the fourteenth century the English forced their way into the Baltic^ and deprived the League of its exclusive trade in cloth. This attack from the West was almost simultaneous with strenuous measures which were temporarily taken against the merchants of the Hanse League in Russia^ ; and eventually they fell before the rising spirit of English and Russian nationality; but yet it must not be forgotten that, divided as Germany has been since the sixteenth century, the Hanse towns by their combination and by the manner in which they organised the commerce of the north, initiated a national commercial policy' at a time when trading was ordinarily regulated in the exclusive interest of particular cities. 102. Charles the Great had been called upon to take an active part in rolling back the other great wave piKite. '^*''' which threatened western civilisation. The in- coming tide of Arabian victory had already been checked by Charles Martel; but Charles the Great assisted in the first stages of the conflict which was to last for so many centuries. During his reign the Crescent was driven from the Pyrenees, and Christian kingdoms were established on the north-east side of Spain. Septimania and Provence, thus set free from the fear of subjugation, formed a suitable area for the revival of Mediterranean commerce and a basis for farther encroachments on the territory of the infidel. Italian cities were much less able to lay aside their mutual jealousies and combine together for common purposes. ' Daenel, Geschichte der dmischen Hanse, 44. " im. 47. ' Ibid. 191. Some Important Trade Routes in the X1V-- Century. To /ac< UNIV. PRESS CHAP. III.] Relations with Heathen and Moslems. 1 1 5 There are, however, many striking contrasts between the struggle in the north against the Norsemen and that in the south against the Arabs. The English, and the dwellers in Germany, the Low Countries, and France, were forced in self-defence to attempt to subdue the Danish plunderers; the warfare in the south was an act of Christian aggression. In the north militant Christianity had to deal with expeditions hastily set on foot by particular leaders ; in the south it had to face well-equipped armies backed by the resources of a well- organised state. The results, too, were very different. In the north, the people of the Baltic lands were converted; there was a real expansion of Christendom, such as there had also been along the Danube valley through the conversion of the Hungarians. On the south, however, though new territory was added to Christendom, the people were not christianised ; they withdrew before the advances of Spanish chivalry, and many of those who attempted to remain on the Peninsula were even- tually expelled by Philip IV. The Moslems were not willing, like the Norsemen, to adopt the Christian faith, and to range themselves among the Christian nations. Bitter hostility between the two continued by sea and land, though their supremacy on the Mediterranean was gradually wrested from the Arabs and they were at length forced back to the African shore. The success of the Christian arms in this struggle with an organised society is all the more remarkable, if we remember that the civilisation of the peoples under Arabian rule was, when tried by almost any test, and certainly by any economic test, incomparably higher than that of Christendom. The court of the Caliphs was the resort of men who were eminent in mathematical and astronomical science, and who had made considerable progress in chemistry and in medicine. They were acute and enthusiastic students of philosophy and cul- tivated an elegant taste in literature. They had carried the arts to a very high degree of perfection, both as regards metal- 8—2 1 1 6 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. working and the textile trades ; they were adepts in irrigation, and made the most of all opportunities for horticulture and agriculture. There was no art in which they could not have given much instruction to their Christian antagonists. Even though so much hostility severed the two polities, there was sufificient intercourse between the Arabs and their northern neighbours to exert a very great influence on the thought and art of Languedoc and Provence. The admiration which Arabian society excited and the infiltration of their ideas, came in the thirteenth century to be a serious danger to the Christian faith in academic centres like the University of Paris, and the Emperor Frederick II was practically a convert to their tenets'. It is no exaggeration to say that the Arabian conquerors had accomplished much that Alexander the Great seems to have aimed at. In their hands there was a curious fusion of the East and the West; the long heritage of both was combined in the learning and material prosperity of the Caliphate. Acceptance of the teaching of the prophet — a pure Theism — was an easy condition for religious consciences that were half- prepared for it by the prevalence of Arianism ; and all forms of secular activity and learning ultimately found a home under this common conviction. The Arabian civilisation thus pre- sented a curious amalgam of elements that had little in common ; Hellenism, as it had survived in the East, furnished its quota, and the remnants of ancient philosophy and Greek science, in so far as they were kept alive in Armenia and were not destroyed at Alexandria, continued to influence men's minds; while the luxury of oriental courts was reproduced in the palaces of the West, and the industry and commerce which ministered to it were prosecuted with success. The Caliphs had the wisdom to give full scope to the talents of the conquered, when once they accepted Islamism; and thus, ^ Frederick II was much influenced by Arabian models in the adminis- tration of Sicily. Nys, Researches in the History of Economics, 36 foil. ; IIuillarrd-Br^holles, Historia Diplomaiici Fredeiici II, Preface, ccccxxii. CHAP. III.] Relations with Heathen and Moslems. 1 17 while the Arabs originated so little themselves, they raised a great civilisation that was brilliant for a time, though it was barren in its after-results. There was, however, a curious want of vitality in the Arab civilisation, when the period of conquest had come to an end ; and though it is easy to represent the Latin Church as merely obscurantist in her constant hostility to such a highly cultivated society, we cannot but recognise that subsequent events have done much to justify this attitude. As we look back, we can see that the Arabian society was lacking in the physical and spiritual qualities which would have fitted it to take a great part in contributing to the progress of the race ; it did collect and disseminate the elements of well-being that remained from the old world, but it did not carry them farther, ,or found anything that was really new. There was a strong probability for a time that the heritage of ancient civilisation would be taken up by the Moslem peoples, and diffused over the world under their guidance. The brunt of the struggle was borne by the Greeks of Constantinople ' ; and the Crusaders, all unconsciously, took action which helped to decide that this thing should not be, and that the progress of the world should be continued, not under the auspices of the Crescent, but of the Cross. When we see the decadence of society in lands where Mohammedanism has had a dominating influence, we may feel that the issue was of vital importance for the whole future of the race. The fundamental weaknesses of the Arab civilisation can be noticed as we look back even to its greatest times. On the physical side we may contrast the Western Arabs with the northern races, who were then mere ruthless barbarians and who had little in common with the cultivated gentlemen of the south; but the northerners had a special aptitude for individual enterprise which rendered them ready to go out ^ Lenormant, La grande Gike, II. 376. Ii8 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. of the beaten tracks, not merely as soldiers obeying a divinely commissioned commander, but from the very love of adventure ; of this racial characteristic, however, enough has already been said. There is a striking contrast too between the religion of the Prophet, inspiring as it was and is, and the Christianity to which Mohammedans were actively opposed. Their pure Theism, just because it is a pure Theism, could not give fruitful maxims for mundane affairs, or lay the basis for a doctrine that should ennoble secular life. The rule of the Caliphs was, in its ultimate basis, a theocracy ; it would submit to no limitations, and the objects which it set before itself, in the conquest of the world to the faith and the attainment of paradise by fighting for it, gave no scope for a doctrine of the responsibility of civil rulers, and of duty towards the governed. The popular imagination which filled the future life with dreams of sensuous enjoyment gave no check to reckless indulgence in luxury here \ and failed to lay down any clear and effective teaching on the obligations of those who were possessed of wealth; nor was there any doctrine of the value of human personality as such, to tell in favour of the gradual extinction of slavery or the improvement in the position of women. Work was encouraged not as a wise discipline, but merely because of the remuneration of the work, and the independence it afforded. From every point of view we see that there was no advance beyond the doctrine of secular life which we find in the Old Testament. Christianity is not a pure Theism, but a worship of an Incar- nate Deity, Who has established a kingdom among men ; it is, in its very essence, a religion of Humanity j it has proved itself capable of inspiring an enthusiasm for the service of man which lies outside the sphere of any mere Theism. Christianity had the power, which Islam had not, of bringing the highest motives and the loftiest principles to bear on mundane affairs, and of remodelling political, civic and industrial life. Islam, with all its enthusiasm and all its faculty for adopting alien CHAP. III.] Relations with Heathen and Moslems, iig elements, failed to supply a firm basis for social life, or to give inspiration for human progress. 103. In the relations between Arabians and Christians on the Western Mediterranean, during the early The Western Middle Ages, we have much that is analogous Mediter- with the intercourse between Phoenicians and '^*"^°°- Greeks in earher times. There is the same racial conflict of Semites and Aryans ; there is the same apparent superiority of the Semitic race at the outset, and the same steady encroachments of the Aryans, who succeeded in wresting point after point from the power of their rivals. The precise course of the struggle is very obscure in each case ; for though we have some mediaeval chronicles, and even important civic and ecclesiasti- cal documents bearing on the later contest, they only throw occasional light on particular incidents, and hardly help us to understand the course of the struggle as a whole. There were, besides, so many conflicting interests at work that the tale is hopelessly tangled, and one which it would be impossible to attempt to unravel here. The Arab empire, like Western Christendom, was split into many separate groups, which neither supported each other's interests in war, nor followed a similar policy in their peaceful relations with Christian powers. Without dwelling on minor divisions, we have only to remember that Charles the Great had been in friendly communication with the Caliph of Bagdad, while he was raising armaments against the Arabs of Spain; and that the rulers of Morocco were developing commercial relations with the cities of Italy and the South of France at the very time when the crusading wars were being carried on most assiduously in Syria.- In the East, as in Spain, there was constant hostility between the representatives of the Cross and the Crescent; but though a great struggle was waged by sea, as well as by land, it was less persistent. At the end of the eighth century the Arabian influence had been paramount in the Mediterranean; before the close of the 120 Western Civilisation. [noOK iv. reign of Charles, the maritime towns of Italy were beginning to send out their fleets and to contest the Arab supremacy; while two centuries later the Normans established themselves in parts of Southern Italy, which had been the prey of Mo- hammedan invaders, and effected the conquest of Sicily. After the loss of Sardinia and Majorca, the Arabs were thrown more and more upon the defensive, so far as their African dominions were concerned; but during this long and bitter struggle the maritime relations between Christians and Moslems were by no means uniformly hostile. It may suffice to indicate and to illustrate the different occasions of intercourse by which the Arab civilisation was brought to bear upon the relative barbarism of Western Christendom. In pursuing their career of conquest in Africa and Spain the Arabs had been glad to preserve the Christian population, and assure to them the enjoyment of rights and privileges, in- cluding the exercise of their religion, on the condition of their paying a regular tribute ; hence there was a considerable, though diminishing. Christian population in Morocco and other parts of the Arab dominions. When Cordova was recovered by the Christians in 1085 a.d., they found that the churches had not been desecrated during centuries of Arab domination ; and in similar fashion, there was a large Mohammedan population which preferred to remain in Sicily under the protection of the Norman Conquerors, rather than to seek new homes among their co-religionists. As the wave of Christian conquest rolled onwards, it swept over, rather than swept away, some elements of Arabian civilisation. The habits and tendencies of thought, which took such a firm hold in Languedoc and called forth the Crusades against the Albigenses, were partly due to a deeply rooted oriental influence in that area.. The territory which passed from one set of masters to another formed a fringe where the two civilisations met, and to some extent blended. The existence of a Christian population under Moslem rule CHAP. III.] Relations with Heathen and Moslems. 121 also brought about a certain amount of ecclesiastical inter- communication. In the tenth or eleventh century there were still forty-seven bishops in the, north of Africa; and in 1053 a.d. the Roman pontiff intervened to maintain the ancient supremacy of the Archbishopric of Carthage among the other remaining sees'. Though the settled Christian population was steadily decreasing, new elements were added; war and piracy were frequent, and many Christians were carried away to languish as captives in Moslem lands. The order of the Redemptionists was founded with the view of aiding in their release" ; it was commended by Innocent III to the good ofiSces of the Sultan Almanzar, while the Dominicans and Franciscans also took an active part in this charitable work, which continued to be a recognised duty of Christian philanthropy in the seventeenth and the early part of the eighteenth centuries. This intercourse, for religious objects, between Christendom and the Moham- medan rulers of Africa, is of interest ; it at least indicates one kind of intercommunication, and it shows that the prohibition of commerce, from which Genoa suffered in the fourteenth century, is not to be regarded as the constant and permanent policy of the Holy See at earlier times. Morocco had access by caravan routes to the products of the East, while it could also draw gold and ivory from the interior of the dark continent; but it required the oil and wine and wood, as well as furs and metals, which were produced or could be purchased in Italy, France and Spain. These mutual needs rendered commerce inevitable, even though religious differences, and inter-municipal jealousies, frequently inter- rupted it and enormously increased the risks of tradings In the twelfth and thirteenth centuries, when the crusades were being actively prosecuted in the East, there were ample and regular facilities for Christian merchants trading with Morocco. * Mas Latrie, Relations et Coniiiierce de VAjrique Septenirionale avec Us nations chritiennes, p. 29. " Ibid. p. 130. 122 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. These were secured by numerous treaties, which specified on one hand the privileges which Christian merchants were to possess, and on the other, described the conditions to which they were personally to conform'. It is curious to observe that there is little difference between the provisions laid down and those which were necessary for the prosecution of ordinary trade within Christendom, or even between the towns in any one realm at the same date. According to the most important stipulation, the persons of Christian merchants were to be secure ; it was agreed that they should not be held responsible for the debts of other men, and that they should have legal protection and remedy against wrongs done them. Each trading city had its own consul, who had the right of direct access to the Sultan ; the consul had complete jurisdiction over the merchants of his own colony when alive, and administered their goods when dead ; disputes between the merchants of two Christian cities came before their consuls, without any interference on the part of the Sultan and his officials. Each Christian city possessed its own factory in Africa, where the merchants could live, where their goods were stored and from which they might be re-exported; these were mercantile strongholds, as they were liable to attacks from many quarters and on many occasions. There was, moreover, a common understanding between Mohammedans and Christians as to the desirability of suppressing piracy, and the protection of those who had suffered shipwreck. It was also a recognised principle that Christians were not to. run unnecessary risks by attempting to trade at any points on the coast, and that they were to show reasonable respect to the religious sentiments of the Arabs; though they were free to practise Christian rites in their own chapels, within their own factories, they were not permitted to have public worship in Mohammedan cities, or ' Mas Latrie, Relations c.t Commerce de I'AJrique i>eptentrionale avec les nations chretiennes, p. 160. CHAP. III.] Relations with Heathen and Moslems. 123 even to sound a sanctus bell which might be heard outside their own establishments. The trading cities of the south of Europe were much less inclined to combine for a common cause than those of the north J each town pursued its independent policy and had its separate factories. The men of Pisa had a specially favoured position at Tunis in 1157 a.d.' The Genoese had a large es- tablishment at Ceuta in 1234 a.d.^, and helped to protect that city from the attack of a crusading fleet ; the men of Marseilles also had a factory even earlier' ; and all these towns had es- tablishments at Bougie. The factories appear moreover to have been used to some extent by the merchants of other cities. The Florentines trafficked for a time in conjunction with the Pisans*, and the factory of the men of Marseilles was used by merchants from other towns in Provence. The Venetians also had a consul at Tunis in 1281 a.d."; they had besides carried on a considerable commerce with Morocco and enjoyed special privileges for the purchase of lead". Such was the nature of the arrangements that were made" for the traffic of Christian merchants in Morocco itself; and enough information has survived to enable us to understand the plan on which their voyages were organised. Associations were formed by traders and other capitalists for the purpose of engaging in a voyage to Africa, deeds of partnership were drawn up, and on the return of the ship and sale of its cargo the profits were paid to the various partners in proportion to the sums they had contributed for the venture. This coUectivist system is probably very ancient, and survived as the business form which was adopted in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries for undertaking distant voyages. ' Mas Latrie, Relations et Commerce de VAfrique Septentrionale avec les nations chretiennes, p. 71, also pp. 90, 107. 2 Ibid. p. ISO. ' Ibid. p. 154. * They used Pisan ships though they had trade privileges of their own. ' Mas Latrie, p. 170. ' Ibid. p. 162. 124 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. 104. The intercourse with Africa which had been estab- lished on these carefully restricted lines was sades and the beneficial to particular cities, but so far as Western Opening of the Europe in general was concerned it had com- paratively little importance. The awakening of a spirit of adventure in the northern parts of Christendom was due to the preaching of the Crusades. This movement appealed to the two strongest sentiments of the age, and found a ready response among all classes of the community; it came as a call to fulfil a sacred duty, and it opened up new fields for the boldest military undertakings'. Its effects were very deep and lasting ; it did not merely afford scope for the mercantile classes to carry on commerce at new points and along fresh routes ; it also diffused new conceptions of civilised life and its possibilities among the Germans, French and English, and introduced a taste for Eastern products in places where they had been hardly obtainable hitherto. The reaction of this movement on society at large had •fat-reaching consequences ; and it is almost impossible to exaggerate the results on the mercantile class in particular. There was much business to be done in assisting in the equipment and transport of troops, as each new Crusade was organised. The commercial colonies which were soon estab- lished at Tripoli in Syria and elsewhere on the Mediterranean were far more important than their analogues — the factories in the cities of Tunis and Morocco ; for they gave access to more important lines of trade with the East^, and furnished many valuable products, such as sugar, cotton and silk, from their immediate neighbourhood'. The trading connections which were then established continued to be maintained-fthough not without interruption — till the discoveries of the fifteenth century 1 The conquest of Sicily by the Normans was in part an anticipation of the Crusades, and it gave a basis for conducting them on a larger scale. ° Heyd, op. cit. i. 163. 8 Ibid. I, 178. CHAP. III.] Relations with Heathen and Moslems. 125 revolutionised the character of commerce with the East. The prosperity of the mercantile classes also tended to improve their political status; as the towns increased in wealth, they were able as communities to purchase larger and larger privileges, and even to assume the character of territorial powers ; but at the same time the differences between the rich and poor within the cities became more noticeable. The rise of capitalist oligarchies, and the struggles against their pretensions, were really though remotely connected with the impulse which was given to commercial activity by the Crusades. The Christian commerce of the Eastern Mediterranean was never so completely extinguished as that of the West had been; in the years when the Arabs ruled Septimania, Spain and Africa, as well as Sicily, Sardinia and other neighbouring islands, Constantinople still held her own; and under her prestige the commerce of Venice and of Amalfi began to flourish. The Norman invasion of the Mediterranean was fatal to this latter city, but Venice made rapid advances ; the Greeks were content that active maritime trade should be undertaken by strangers, and the Venetians not only secured an important establishment in Constantinople, but founded depots at Caffa and other points on the coasts of the Black Sea. They had little sympathy with the Crusaders at first, for, like the Greek Emperor, they were tempted to look askance on the crowd of military adventurers who flocked into the territories where their trading interests lay. Owing to these circumstances the Venetians held aloof on the whole from the earlier expeditions', and the profitable undertakings connected with the transport of the Crusaders fell to a very large extent into the hands of their great rivals — the Genoese. When we consider on what a small scale shipping had hitherto been carried on, we see at once what an enormous impetus must have been given to business of every kind by ' W. Lenel, Entstehung der Vorherrschaft Venedigs an der Adria, P- 35- 126 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. the necessity of finding the means of conveying and of pro- visioning whole armies. The Genoese, who had taken an active part in the struggle with the Arabians in the West, threw themselves heartily into the new field of maritime employment which the Crusaders opened up. They were perhaps better prepared than their neighbours to take advan- tage of the great opportunity ; but Marseilles and MontpelUer were also engaged in catering for the demands of the Crusaders in the matter of equipment and transport. The successive expeditions, which followed one after another, served at all events to make money circulate among shipowners on the Mediterranean, as it had never done before. During the brief r'egime of the Latin kingdom of Jerusalem, the merchants of Genoa and other cities of Italy and of Pro- vence made the most of their opportunities and established considerable factories on the coast of S3nia. The Italian merchants had access for a time to the caravan routes which had formerly contributed so much to the prosperity of Tyre and to that of Antioch in Roman times j with the reassertion of Mohammedan influence, the Christian traders failed to maintain their position. Experience had aheady shown, however, that crusading had its commercial aspect, and that it could be made to pay ; and in the Fourth Crusade the religious interest fell entirely into the background. It was an expedition which was directed by the Venetians to forward their mercantile projects; they succeeded in upsetting the Greek Empire in Constantinople, and in reducing their Genoese rivals to a sub- ordinate position in that emporium; for sixty years the Venetians appear to have enjoyed a complete monopoly of the trading stations in the Black Sea, and to have commanded the Northern caravan routes to Persia and the East. But they were not sufficiently careful to maintain the valuable monopoly they had won : the Genoese were willing to assist' in restoring the ' Michael Pala«ologus succeeded in his expedition before the Genoese fleet arrived. Heyd, op. cit. i. 428. CHAP. III.] Relations with Heathen and Moslems. 127 Greek Imperial line in 1261 a.d., and in their turn attained a supremacy which, though less extensive, was similar to that which Venice had enjoyed ^ They concentrated their atten'tion on the Black Sea trade ; while the Venetians developed their Levantine trade from Cyprus^, and consolidated their position in Egypt. The trade with this latter country had suffered, but it had never been suppressed, either by the fortunes of war or by papal prohibition'. The Venetians endeavoured to mo- nopolise it, but they were unable to prevent the intrusion of other merchants from the Adriatic^, and a very large commerce was carried on by the Catalans^ and Provengals. At the be- girming of the fourteenth century there were several well- established lines of communication between Western Europe and the East through the Moslem world. The Hanse towns worked eastwards through Russia, and the Genoese from' Constantinople ; Venice, Barcelona, and Marseilles had factories in Egypt, and various Italian towns maintained prosperous establishments in Morocco. It was of course restricted inter- course, conducted at factories, but it was regularly organised and fairly constant. There was occasional agreement for common commercial objects among the Provengals and Catalans', but between the Italian towns there was little sign of any confederacy such as grew up among the traders in the Baltic; and the rise or fall of one or another of these centres was for the most part due to political causes and had but little economic significance. Intercivic quarrels were often connected with the desire of each town to maintain its monopoly, and especially to secure exclusive access to the harbours on the more important 1 Heyd, op. cit. I. 430, 441. " Heyd, op. cit. II. 7. ' After the fall of Acre in 1291. Heyd, op. cit. II. 34. ♦ Heyd, op. cit. I. 418. ' Heyd, op. cit. I. 421. * Mas Latrie, op. cit. 213. 128 Western Civilisation. [book IV. commercial routes'. Genoa succeeded in establishing her supremacy on the Western coast of Italy, and closed the harbours of Messina and Syracuse to the Pisans' and Mar- seillese^j while Venice continued to gain at the expense of Ancona and Ferrara, and attained at length to the sovereignty of the Adriatic*. Apart from these rivalries, the policy pursued by these cities was economically sound ; since their commercial prosperity and industrial activity were made to react on one another^ Each had to some extent its own character; the Venetians imitated the imperial policy in the endeavour to introduce the manufacture of articles of luxury which had hitherto been imported at great cost; they set themselves to encourage the silk industry", as well as the production of glass and mosaic, and the fine kinds of metal work. Genoa was perhaps more of a mere commercial dep6t than her great rivals, but her people were specially skilled in the manufacture of arms and munitions of war. The Florentines had devoted themselves to the textile trades and the dressing and dyeing of fine woollen cloth' ; it was only gradually that they forced their way to the sea, and superseded Pisa in a profitable trade with Morocco ; but the prosperity of their town was built on the most secure foundations, and they suffered less than their neighbours from the changes which were brought about by the age of discovery. The impulse which was given to the Italian towns was communicated with more or less rapidity to other centres in Europe". The cities in the Danube valley must have profited ' Compare Vol. I. 64, 89. " Heyd, «>. cit. i. 183. « Ibid. I. 188. * Lenel, op. cit. 47—84. » Vol. I. 67, 119. " Broglio d'Ajano, Die Venetianische Seidenindustrie, if. ' E. Dixou, Florentine Wool Trade in the Middle Ages, in the Royai Historical Societys Transactions, Xll. 158. Doren, Entwickelung und Organisation der Floreniiner Ziinfte in SchmoUer's Forschungen, XV. iii 60. * The increase of commercial intercommunication imdoubtedly affected CUAP. lli.J Relations with Heatfien and Moslems. 129 to some extent by catering for the armies which passed along that route; while Augsburg and Nuremberg, which were in direct communication with Venice, gained with the increase of her commercial activity. Nor was it only by mountain passes that communication with the North took place ; from the early part of the fourteenth century regular commercial voyages were organised from Venice to the Low Countries. The Flanders galleys began to carry a portion of the trade which had gone in previous times by the French rivers, and after the middle of the fourteenth century, when the Hundred Years' War interfered with the peaceful avocations of merchants, this stream of traffic was almost entirely diverted to the Alpine and maritime routes. In the fourteenth century we can estimate the full extent of the impulse which had been given by the Crusades. We see the organised commercial communication between all parts of Western Christendom, and with the countries which lay out- side, and we see too that a new development of industry followed in connection with the improvement of the facilities for trading intercourse. 105. It is rarely the case that the personal life of any individual embraces and illustrates the most momentous issues in the contemporary history the^Navigator! of his country ; and it would be difficult to find any single character that summed up the tendencies of his age so completely as did Prince Henry the Navigator. His work led to the discovery of the new world, and to the opening of direct maritime communication with the East; through his personal energy, and interest in founding a school of navigators, the industrial arts in the North and West of Europe. This is particularly clear in regard to the art of fortification (Oman, Art of War, 526). It is noticeable that many of the terms in use in the building trades in England are of Greek origin — laothonii, cheirotheca, schola — and that the organi- sation of masons had little in common with that of other crafts in England, while it was closely analogous to that which existed in Byzantium in the ninth century. Jules Nicole, Livre du Prifet, p. 82. C. W. C. II. 9 130 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. the preliminary difficulties were overcome and compleJ;e success was brought within sight. The change which has revolutionised European trade and has drawn the whole world within the influence of Western Civilisation was indirectly the doing of this Portuguese Prince. Yet though his action rendered modern life possible, with its cosmopolitan commerce and giant industry which far outstrip the greatest efforts of the ancient world, he was not in any sense before his time; he was emphatically a man of his time. The various threads which we have followed in the preceding paragraphs appear to meet and to be united in him. Prince Henry came of a stock which had a strain of the old Norse blood ; the kingdom of Portugal had been founded by Norman adventurers ; and his mother was a Plantagenet and therefore a descendant of Norman William. Thus the first impulse in the age of dis- covery came from a scion of the race that had made their homes on all the lands of the Northern Seas, and had swept the Mediterranean with their ships. He lived at a time, too, when his native country had come to occupy a new place in the commerce of the day ; the fleet of Flanders Galleys touched at its ports, and native enterprise was fired more and more with the ambition to obtain at least a share in the trade which the Venetians found so profitable. It is noticeable also that Prince Henry resided in the one corner of Christendom where the old crusading fervour burned most fiercely ; the continued presence of the Mohammedans at Grenada was an ofiFence to Christian sentiment and a challenge to Christian chivalry. Prince Henry had won his spurs in a briUiant attack on the infidel fortress of Tangier ; and there was in him a combination of the scientific and missionary interest in discovery with the military and religious desire of conquest, which was charac- teristic of the mediaeval world in which he lived rather than of the modern life he was helping to introduce. Islam had hemmed Christendom in on every side ; on the east as on the south, the Crescent raised a barrier against the advance of the Cl-lAr. Ill] Relations with Heathen and Moslems. 131 Cross. It was the ambition of Prince Henry to turn the flank of these ancient foes, and thus to obtain direct access to the great world, and to the Heathendom that lay beyond the wide belt of Mohammedan influence. With this object in view he organised a school of maritime exploration, where all the geographical knowledge of the day and technical skill in seamanship might be combined for one definite object. Year after year his expeditions were sent out, and pushed their way farther and farther along the African coast; but few of his emissaries were inspired by his far- reaching ambitions; they preferred to reap the immediate profits of commerce on the African coast, rather than to push on to the continents that lay beyond. They obtained gold from the Guinea coast by barter with the natives, and made a new beginning of that trade which has been the immemorial curse of Africa, by bringing negroes to work in Portugal. At the time of Prince Henry's death the Portuguese had already found their way to the Madeiras (1418 a.d.) and rounded Cape Bojador (1434 a.d.); and a few years later they pushed as far as Senegal and the Cape Verde Islands (1446 A.D.); the impulse which the prince had given was not allowed to die out, and the work of discovery became a settled part of Portuguese policy, though it was not pursued with the same assiduity in every reign. Explorers were sent by land to the East, and attempts were made to utilise the caravan routes across Northern Africa ; but the crowning success was attained in 1498 A.D. when Vasco da Gama arrived after a nine months' voyage at Calicut. Six years previously Columbus, relying on the experience accumulated by Prince Henry's school and aided by the resources of Ferdinand and Isabella, had found his way to the West Indian Islands, and fired the ambition of a crowd of other explorers; so that in the course of a few years the coasts of enormous continents were sketched in the map of the world, and a field was opened for military and 9—2 133 Western Civilisation. [BOOK IV. commercial expeditions, which was wide indeed compared with the narrow area which the Crusaders had striven to occupy. It were invidious to compare the heroism and persistence displayed by the discoverers in one great area with the virtues of other men at other times. The Portuguese and Columbus accomplished a magnificent work that has changed the face of the globe ; but it may be doubted if they showed more enter- prise in penetrating the unknown or more skill in seamanship than the Phoenicians in their voyages or the Vikings of whom we read in the sagas. The times were ripe for the fifteenth century discoveries ; facilities were at hand to take advantage of the new vista they opened up. The Norsemen had not had the means to transport armies which could conquer the lands they reached, or the skill to frame a government which could even enable them to explore the new territories systematically; but the world had advanced since their time. The business training which had been developed by merchants in the Mediterranean could be brought to bear in the Eastern hemisphere ; the Portuguese did not fare forth half as pirates and half as merchants, but as men who meant to obtain a regular establishment from which they could organise a steady trade. The preceding centuries, with their limited commerce and futile expeditions, had been a long apprenticeship and had fitted the men of the sixteenth century for the career of conquest and commerce and colonisation which had become possible for them alike in the East and the West. ig6. However highly we may rate the gain that has M diaevai accrued, On the whole, from the age of discovery and Modern we should not Overlook the mischiefs that ac- lavery. companied it. The moral results in Europe of intercommunication between Christendom and the Moslem world had not always been wholesome; and the contact between Christendom and heathendom induced a terrible relapse from the improving standard in regard to the treatment of labourers, which had been the most striking economic CUAP. III.] Relations with Heathen and Moslems. 133 feature of mediaeval society, for it led to an immediate recrudescence of slavery. When the African slave-trade had once been started, it continued to develop and increase till the horrors of the revived traffic nearly equalled or possibly even exceeded the miseries endured by slaves in the ancient world. The reintroduction of the slave-trade was a singular aberration, for which it is not at first sight easy to account; the influence of Christian sentiment and economic changes had alike tended to raise the status of the labourer in Europe ; but, for different reasons, these forces did not serve to prevent or discourage the export of slaves to the new world. The attitude of the Church towards slavery had always been perfectly clear; from the time of S. Paul onwards there had been no condemnation of slavery as an institution, or attempt to interfere with it as a condition of life in ordinary society; there was no assertion of any inherent right of man as man to be free. While, then, there was no condemnation of slavery as such, there were frequent efforts made to lighten the lot of the slave, and to protect him from arbitrary and cruel treatment by his master'. Many signs of this influence are to be found in the legislative codes of the East^ as well as in the Capitularies^ ; and the partial freedom which was afforded by limiting the master's rights gave the slave an opportunity for gradually bettering his position. Besides contributing in this way to the gradual improvement of the circumstances of the class, the Church treated freedom as an ideal, which ought to be kept in view. The liberating of slaves was encouraged as a form of charity, though it was not regarded ^ Yanoslii, De Vabolilion de Vesclavage ancien au moyeii dge, p. 37 fol. * Brownlow, Lectures on Slavery and Serfdom in Europe, p. 30 fol. Cod. Theod. lib. I.X. tit. 55. 1, s; Cod. Justinian, lib. vn. tit. 15. i. Wallon, Histoire de V Esclavage, III . 389. ' Brownlow, op. cit. 69, Cafiitula excerpta ex lege Longobardoruni, c. 14 in Baluze, Capitularia (1677), I. 351; Gueiard, Polyptyque de tAbbe Irmiiwn; prolegomenes, 331. 134 Western Civilisation, [BOOK IV. as a duty of strict obligation' ; to keep slaves was not wrong, but to free them was kindly and commendable. Hence we have the numerous wills, like that of King Alfred'', where the manumission of slaves comes in as a generous benefaction, much as the endf;wing of a college might appear in the present day. There are other examples, such as that of S. Eligius, whose methods of effecting the redemption of slaves were so strangely unlike .those of modern abolitionists'. There were, moreover, certain cases in which Christian sentiment was not content with improving their lot or making occasional efforts for setting individual slaves at liberty; a traffic which consisted in removing men from Christian homes and leaving them uncared for in pagan lands roused the strongest indignation. To be willing for the sake of mere money to sell a Christian man into a country where it was hardly possible for him to maintain Christian habits of life, and where he must die ' unhouseled, disappointed, unanealed,' was an outrage on religious sentiment. Hence, while there was little decided feeling against slavery as such, there was the deepest pity for those who were sold into captivity beyond the pale of Christendom* ; a pity which was based, not merely on sympathy with their physical lot, but on fears for their loss of the means of grace and the hope of glory. The Christian sentiment on the subject was not primarily humanitarian, but simply religious, and herein lies the secret of its limitations. When the sphere of Mohammedan influence in ^ A precisely similar distinction was drawn in regard to the use of money; to lend money without interest was a commendable sort of charity and kindliness, but it was not a duty incumbent on every man who had wealth at his disposal. * Thorpe, Diplomatarium Anglicuiii Aevi Saxonici, 492, also 513. » S. R. Maitland, The Dark Ages, 88. For the Viking slave-trade compare Torfaeus, Renim Norvegicarum Historia (1711), vol. II. p. 332. * Great pains were taken by the Genoese to prevent the inclusion of any Christian among the slaves they exported from Caffa to Egypt. Ileyd, op. cit. II. 557. CHAP. III.] Relations with Heathen and Moslems. 135 Africa had been rounded by Prince Henry's exertions, and Christendom had come into direct contact with heathendom, this strong religious feeling was not shocked by the action of those who imported heathen slaves into Christian lands; it would have been possible to regard such conduct as a pious work, since by its means the imported slaves were brought within the range of Christian instruction. It does not appear clear that any one ever advocated the trafiSc on this ground', and Cardinal Ximenes and the Spaniards generally regarded the trade with dislike, as at best a necessary evil, but a real evil ; still the point remains that the Christian sentiment which had protested vigorously against the export of slaves from Europe was not roused by the importation of slaves to Europe, or to lands dominated by Europeans and in which Christian insti- tutions existed. Apart altogether from this religious influence, economic causes had been at work in improving the condition of the rural labourer in Western Europe. They had doubtless had something to do with the diminution of slavery ; for its decline in the ancient world had been partly due to the fact that no sufficient source of supply continued to be available^. It had been necessary to introduce new methods of estate manage- ment, and to rely on the labour of serfs who were restricted to particular estates and remunerated by the assignment of holdings which they worked on their own account. The medi- aeval villein was in a very different position from the slaves of classical times, for despite the disabilities to which he was subject, he had a definite legal status, and he frequently enjoyed proprietary rights which enabled him to improve his position as opportunity arose. The gradual substitution of money for natural economy in rural life told decidedly in his favour j this gave him an increased measure of economic ' Columbus appears to have taken this view in his treatment of the natives of the Caribbean Islands. Ingram, History of Slavery, p. 142. 2 Vol. I. p. 179. 13*3 Wesiern Civilisation. [book IV. independence and much greater freedom for movement'. The change has not proceeded at a uniform rate in all European lands ; the occasions which have brought it about have been different in each country, though the general result has been similar in all alike^. For the most part this revolution occurred at a date when there was little tendency to utilise capital in the cultivation of land'; there was no considerable demand for hired labour, and no need at all to import it into Europe. A large body of peasantry, engaged in work upon their small holdings, inhabited the areas that could be most profitably cultivated'*. The circumstances in the New World were so different that the importation to it of slaves from Africa proved to be a remunerative business. There were many large capitalists in America who were eager to obtain numbers of labourers so that they might carry on mining operations and work their plantations, while a supply that was practically unlimited could be easily drawn from the dark continent. These exceptional circumstances, under which the traffic revived, bring into clearer light the reasons for its decline and practical disappearance from European lands', and help us to gauge more precisely the effect of religious ideals on the course of affairs. In the one case where Christian sentiment failed to make its protest, the horrors of slavery revived. The introduc- ^ T. W. Page, End of Villainage in England, in the Publications of the American Economic Association, 3rd series, I. p. 382. * Ingram, History of Slavery and Serfdom, 91 fol.; see also Brownlow, op. cit. p. 210, for the influence of the Crusaders. ^ The large Tuscan estates appear to have been exceptional. Pohlmann, Die Wirthschdftspolitik der Florentiner Renaissance, p. 5. In the Preis- schriften gekront von der fiirstlich-jablonowskischen Gesellschaft, 1878. * The pressure of the moneyed and industrial interests tended to depress the condition of the peasantry both in France and Germany, but not to enslave them. Lamprecht, Deutsche Geschichte, V. 87 fol. " Slavery was not extinct in Europe so early as is commonly supposed. Cibrario has collected numerous instances of sales of slaves in Italy in the xiiith, xivth and xvth centuries. Delia' Schiavitit e del Servaggio, I. pp. 227—235. CHAP. III.] Relations with Heathen and Moslems. 137 tion of money-economy gave the command of more capital to invest in slaves ; the opening up' of commercial intercourse afforded wider opportunities for engaging in the traffic; these elements in material progress were perfectly compatible with the maintenance of slavery and the oppression of the workman. It was so far, and only so far, as Christianity made itself felt as an effective force, by constant pressure exerted through many centuries, that the condition of labour was sensibly improved fiom what it had been in the ancient world. BOOK V. NATIONALITIES. CHAPTER I. SECULARISATION. 107. The resemblances between the Roman Empire of _, _. the second or third century and the Latin ruption of Christendom of the thirteenth have been already Christendom. pointed out. Both attained to a high state of civilisation, and a large part of the areas they occupied was common to both ; they were ruled from the same centre and included a similar independent city life. These points of similarity lie so much on the surface as to tempt us to overlook and ignore the deep and real differences which were inherent in the very structure of these polities ; but the marked contrast between them is forced on our attention when we compare these two great systems of society in their decline. The Roman Empire preserved its apparent grandeur, while it was tottering to its fall, and one after another of its provinces sank away into utter barbarism. In Christendom, however, there was disruption rather than decay. The central authority fell into disrepute and the cohesive influences gave way ; but the distant provinces were by no means exhausted ; they were, on the contrary, full of vigorous vitality, and were so far from CHAP. I.] Secularisation. 139 relying on the central power for defence, that they resented attempts to exercise any interference and control. The radical distinction between the breaking up of the ancient and of the mediaeval system lies in the fact that the Empire succumbed and fell to pieces as the result of a long period of economic failure and decadence; the weakness was obvious enough, even though there may be some dispute as to the precise diagnosis of the disease with which the mischief began. In Christendom however there was no similar blight. The era of the Crusades had been a time of extraordinary material prosperity ; even despite the devastation caused by the constant struggles in Italy, and the Hundred Years' War between England and France, in spite too of the destruction consequent on the Black Death and of the commercial readjustments necessitated by the fall of Constantinople, economic progress continued in many directions. Under the influence of developing trade, industry was stimulated ; the towns of Flanders and of Germany are full of fourteenth and fifteenth century monuments which testify unmistakeably to the vigour of tljeir industrial life, and the wealth of the merchant princes of the time. The outlying parts of the Empire had been the first to show the numbness which betokens a mortal malady ; .but there were no analogous symptoms in the distant parts of Christendom. A strange glamour had attached to the very name of the Roman Emperor; the mere survival of the imperial dignity had overawed the barbarian invaders; while their admiration for the imperial authority persisted, in spite of their experience of its inability to resist them. In Christendom, on the other hand, the rivalry of Pope and Emperor was too intense, and their struggle too long continued, for either to command the un- questioning obedience of the world. The subsequent triumph of the Papacy over the Emperor was spoiled of its effect by the great schism and the Babylonian captivity, when the spiritual head of Christendom became a mere puppet of France. 140 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V, When not one Pope but three demanded the obedience of mankind, and the new era of Councils opened, there was a patent confession that the Papacy had ceased to be an effective instrument for the government of Christendom. Nor had the Papacy been successful in organising effective resistance to the common foe; the greedy intrigue, which brought about the fall of the Templars, discredited its instigator, and opened up fresh opportunities for Mohammedan aggression. The Emperors had been forced to yield to the Popes, but the Papacy was unable to wield the power at which it had grasped, and failed to maintain its dignity as a spiritual head directing all the energies of a great and complex civilised society. The economic inanition, which proved fatal to the Roman Empire, had nothing to -do with the disruption of Christendom ; that was entirely due to the inability of the central power to maintain an effective authority. io8. This loss of prestige on the part of the ecclesiastical head of Christendom became a serious danger Secular . ° Functions of to the mstitutions of the mediaeval world, be- andCritSsm cause it directed attention to the principles on of the existing which the whole social system rested and rendered ys em. them the subject of much hostile criticism. The claim that Christian influence should be supreme in all the relations of life had been admitted in the foundation, and had guided the construction of the fabric of mediaeval society ; this principle seemed to imply that there was no sphere of human interest which did not come under the cognisance of spiritual authority, and with which the activity of ecclesiastics might not be rightly concerned. Practical reasons rendered it con- venient to entrust the management of civil affairs to the clergy, as educated men ; they were also regarded as especially trust- worthy, since bishops and priests were particularly bound to discharge their duties with the . fear of God before them'. Directly and indirectly an immense amount of secular business ^ Dialo^us de Scaccario, Pref, CHAP. I.] Secularisation. 141 came into the hands of clerical functionaries; ecclesiastical tribunals had control over all matters connected with wills and marriages; and much administrative work, both fiscal, judicial, and diplomatic, was carried on by ecclesiastical per- sonages, who held high civil offices in the various states of Europe. This attempt to control the life of man in all its aspects is of the very essence of the Christian religion. Homo sum, nihil humani a me alienum puto, is the Divine Word to the world. Still it is true that, those who have aimed at giving effect to this principle have often discredited it by their failure to apply it. The effort to control and direct all the various interests of mankind may distract attention from the supreme end which ought to be in view. The Benedictines had devoted them- selves to the study of letters, that they might consecrate learning, and to the pursuit of wealth that was devoted to the service of God; nevertheless they had so far lost their hold on the end and aim of the Rule under which they lived, that there was need in the twelfth century for the founding of the reformed orders at Cluny and Citeaux. In precisely the same manner the absorption of ecclesiastical officials in civil and political activity tended to distract them from the duties of devotion, and laid them open to the charge that their claim to spiritual authority and respect was a mere pretext, which was used to cloak an absorbing interest in worldly dignities and earthly gain. There was a consequent reaction of-religious feeling, which carried many earnest men into the opposite extreme and led them to disparage secular life altogether. The rise of the mendicant orders was a protest against a secularised hierarchy; in their devotion to spiritual things and to acts of mercy, they deliberately re- frained from secular duties, and alleged the example of our Lord and the Twelve Apostles as an excuse for neglecting the discipline of work, and living on the alms of th^ faithful. Mediaeval thinkers rightly insisted on the supreme value of 142 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. that which is spiritual; but they erred in giving it exclusive .importance; indeed, the hard and fast line which they drew is inadmissible. We cannot sever the merely secular from the purely spiritual and contrast them one against the other ; the problem which confronts the Christian man in all ages is that of so using earthly things as to turn them to the highest uses. He is bound to endeavour to bring the common affairs of daily life into just subordination and to limit an absorbing interest in them; but any attempt to ignore them altogether as unworthy of attention must end in disaster. That which is secular has a place in the divine order and will reassert itself if neglected. Those who, as friars, were wholly true to their vows of poverty and were personally most self-sacrificing and devout, might yet be deeply concerned about the worldly welfare of their community and vehement sticklers for its privileges or wealth. Still, the view of Christian duty which they asserted, in all its exaggeration and crudity, came to be widely popular; in the time of the Emperor Lewis of Bavaria the enthusiasm for the purely spiritual was dexterously used by William of Occam as a weapon for attacking ecclesiastics for their readiness to attend to worldly matters and to control or exercise civil functions. This teaching was formulated with such skill and acumen that it was diffused and perpetuated in academic circles; similar criticism on the existing gystem was uttered more forcibly, in the fourteenth century, by those who regarded the affairs of the times as plain men, exercising their common sense. There was a sharp contrast between the recognised duty of labour, — of accepting work as a personal discipline, — and the lives of the friars who lived in idleness as beggars. The management of the religious houses failed to show that ecclesiastics were actuated by a sense of responsibility in ful- filling the duty of administering their property carefully ; the exactions of the monasteries from their serfs or from the townsmen, who were their neighbours, gave continual cause for CHAP. I.] Secularisation. 143 complaint and were the excuse for occasional outbreaks. • A more scandalous violation of another fundamental Christian principle — that of fairness in monetary transactions — was afforded by the practices of the papal merchants, whose sharp dealings rivalled those of the detested Jew. When tried by the standards, which the Church had introduced and disseminated, the existing ecclesiastical system was emphatically condemned. It must be noted, however, that this popular criticism was saner and wiser than that of Occam and the friars; it did not discard the old conceptions as mistaken, but, in the face of existing abuses, it challenged the papal claim to unquestioning obe- dience, as the unique authority in interpreting and enforcing Christian duty. The old ideals have survived the disruption of Christendom and are retained in Christian lands as setting the standards by which right and wmng are judged ; there is still the recognition of an Absolute Will as the ground of all human authority and the guarantee against the encroachments of arbitrary human will on personal liberty ; there is frequent insistence on the responsibilities of the wealthy, and a general admission that work is a duty to be done. All this remains in the modern world, though the Latin Church is no longer accepted as the sole illustration of every Christian virtue ; the maxims of its jurisprudence have Ipeen set aside in many lands as no longer applicable, and its methods of enforcing them have lost much of their power. The mediaeval world, which owed everything to the work of the Christian Church, had gradually outgrown and ceased to rely on the forms through which that guidance had been habitually given. 109. These opinions, so hostile to the existing order, must have sooner or later had their effect in „^ „, , ,.,.,..„,. The Black undermmmg clerical authority in Christendom ; Death and but their influence was greatly accelerated by the integration, terrible pestilence which devastated Europe in The Renais- the middle of the fourteenth century. The Black Death, passing as it did from country to country and 144 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. sweeping off about half of the population in land after land", brought about many fundamental changes, both in urban and rural districts. Some of these are matters of local and special history, but one result was common to the whole of Western Europe. The Church as an organised society suffered a serious shock, which strained its most honoured institutions. The great monasteries never recovered their position and in- fluence as centres of cultivated and devout life"; the supply of clergy for the parish churches became quite inadequate. The scandals, which became more frequent and patent, were subsequently dealt with in some lands by the Council of Trent, while they were made the occasion for religious revo- lution in other countries. The Church not only suffered from an insufficient supply of men, but came to be more exposed to another attack, after the Black Death. Since a large pro- portion of the population had died, and the conditions of life and labour had changed for the worse, the amount of wealth devoted to religious objects appeared to be excessive and to be quite disproportionate to the requirements of each state. The jealousy of needy potentates was roused and their avarice was quickened; they were eager to take advantage of any chance that offered for diverting the grants that had been made by pious benefactors. Much of the contemporary testimony as to the corruption of the Church comes from tainted sources and is untrustworthy, and it is a thankless task to try to sift the evidence in detail; we can see that apart altogether from any religious or moral causes which contributed to the downfall of the ecclesiastical system, the Latin Church must have lost its predominance, so soon as society was able to dispense with the support it had formerly afforded. The Truce of God had ceased to be a useful guarantee for the opportunity of pursuing peaceful avocations, since the royal authority was better able to enforce the law, 1 Cunningham, Growth of English Tfidustry and Commerce, I. 331. ^ Gasquet, The Great Pestilence, pp. 205, 214. CHAP. I.] Secularisation. 14S and to secure that the intermission of war and pillage should not be exceptional and occasional, but general and permanent. There were trained civilians who could administer the affairs of the realm, so that rulers were able to dispense with the services of the clergy in many capacities which ecclesiastics had at one time filled to advantage. In earlier times the monks had improved the art of agriculture, and aided in the development of commerce; but in the fifteenth century the abbey estates were no longer models of good management, and trade was cared for by the merchant oligarchies of the towns. The Church had ceased to be a leader in the arts of practical life, while her inability to utilise privileges and possessions to the best advantage under changed conditions, was fatal to her position as the dominating influence over secular life in all its aspects. The general disorganisation of European society and de- creased respect for the spiritual head of Christendom reacted on the finances of the Roman Court, and rendered it neces- sary for the Popes to devise new methods for obtaining revenue'. The temper of the times was such that a systematic attempt to increase papal taxation would have been a dan- gerous expedient in any case; but murmured criticism gave place to active resentment as the full effects of the Renais- sance" movement began to be felt. The conscious imitation of ancient models at the court of Rome was a cause of scandal ; and the scheme for the erection of a magnificent ecclesiastical edifice which should be a centre for the world's worship brought matters to a crisis ; an attempt was made to ' GoUlob, All! der Camera, t88. 2 The Humanists were repelled by mediaeval ideals and did not a little to undermine mediaeval institutions. They valued art and letters; and regarded them as objects well worth living for on their own account. The Humanists refused to look on life in this world as a mere discipline and preparation for another sphere; and thus they contributed to the process of secularisation, but they bad little direct influence on economic progress, for they merely reverted to ancient ideals which were already discredited by the logic of events. C. W. C. U. 1-3 146 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. meet the expense of the building of S. Peter's by the sale of indulgences in Germany ; this roused the indignation of Luther, whose protest served as a wedge, that was driven farther and farther home, till Christendom was severed to pieces. no. The malign effects of the Black Death and the social disintegration it induced were more ob- nin**s^*^'"' vious and long continued than might have been Recon- the case if the ecclesiastical institutions had Territorial retained "their pristine vigour; but they were no Economic longer able to cope with the fresh difficulties Policy. " "^ . . that arose. From this time onwards some im- portant matters which had hitherto been attended to as pious duties were disregarded ; churchmen lacked either the will or the power to bestir themselves ; and when men tried to remedy this neglect in the sixteenth century, the work was taken up by the civil and not by the ecclesiastical authorities. Internal trade could only be carried on with difficulty in countries where it had previously flourished, for all the facilities for intercommunication had suffered severely. This had been specially the case in France, where the devastation caused by the Hundred Years' War had aggravated the mischief due to mere neglect'. Even in England many of the bridges had broken down', and there was no one with sufficient public spirit to attend to them properly. Throughout the Middle Ages it seems as if the repair of roads was rather a piece of Christian philanthropy than any- thing else. The rendering of assistance to travellers was a form of active benevolence, and the story of the building of Barnstaple bridge' shows how much this work was required for the public safety. We find that such repairs were a frequent subject of pious benefaction; the great ecclesiastics and monastic cor- porations are said to have devoted a considerable amount of ' Levasseur, op. cit. 421 — 9. ^ Jusserand, English Wayfaring Life, 64. ' Leland, Itinerar}' (T744), II. 75, f. 66. CHAP. I.J Secularisation. 147 wealth to this purpose' ; at all events as their vigour declined they were less ready to take an active part in the matter. The statute of 1555 a.d., which provides for the appointment of road surveyors', embodies the modern view of the nature of the obligation ; it was a public improvement to which great atten- tion was given by Henry IV of France'. There was also a process of secularisation in the arrange- ments which were made for the relief of the indigent. The distresses of the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries appear to have given new prominence to the question of pauperism, and the need of making provision for the poor was very im- perfectly met by the monasteries at that time. This may have been partly due to the diminution of their wealth, and partly to increased carelessness of the wants of the poor ; but it should also be remembered that the mediaeval methods of charity were thoroughly unsatisfactory. Doles of food, if occasional, can do little towards aiding the poor effectively; if regularly perpetuated, they tend to create an idle and pauperised class. Many ex- periments were tried by the founding of hospitals and other charitable institutions for the local maintenance of the poor; in many towns efforts were made to promote discriminating almsgiving and the organisation of charitable help ; and the task came to be fulfilled as a matter of civic or municipal expediency*. There was some doubt as to how far this way of viewing it was in accord with the Christian maxims of neighbourliness; and the point was discussed at some length by the doctors of the Sorbonne^. They gave the sanction of 1 Thorold Rogers, Agriculture and Prices, I. 139. Jusserand, op. cit. 45. A. Law, English Tcnuns and Roads in xill Centttry in Economic Review, VII. 300. 2 1 and 3 Philip and Mary, u. 8. ' Fagniez, Veconomie sociale de la France sous Henri IV, 180. * A. S. Green, English Town Life, i. 41, n. 2. E. Leonard, Poor Relief, 7. ' Ashley, Introduction to English EconoTnic History, I. ii. 348. 148 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V, their authority to methods of undertaking the duty' which had httle in common with the traditional Christian practice of indiscriminate almsgiving. But distressful as the period of transition must necessarily have been, it was an enormous boon that civil authority was so far developed as to be able to take in hand the various forms of social activity for which the ecclesiastical system was no longer able to provide. There were in the fifteenth century two distinct types of secular authority, the monarchies and the cities; both were capable of organising departments of governmental action which had hitherto been relegated to the Church, and both were making their importance felt as growing territorial powers. The kings and the towns of Western Europe had some- times found a common interest in opposing the great feuda- tories and curbing their pretensions; in the fifteenth century a fair measure of success had been attained, and the noble families were relatively less independent of the kings and less important than the wealthy centjiBS of trade. Feudal society passed away throughout Western Europe ; but in some countries, as in Italy and Flanders, the towns had become so strong that they were able to maintain an economic and political indepen- dence. In others, and especially in France and in England, the authority of the sovereign was brought to bear effectively on the whole territory and controlled the affairs of towns and of mral districts alike. In this way it was possible in all the regulation of industry and trade, to keep one supreme object in view and to attempt to utilise all. resources so as to strengthen the realm as a whole. This might necessitate the repression of particularist aims and even the suppression of local privi- leges, but it helped to bring out an underlying community of interest among all the citizens, and to give solidarity to the ' Oo the tentative experiments of Tudor times and the growth of the English systems see £. M. Leouard, The Early History of English Poor Relief, 31. CHAP. I.] Seatlarisation. 145 whole social system. When a wise economic policy was adoptea for any nation there was abundant opportunity for the healthy interaction of rural, urban and commercial life upon each other. In Italy and Flanders, and to some extent in Germany, many of the towns acquired additional territory ; and each was inclined to organise a definite economic system whicii should suit its own circumstances ; monarchic and civic policy have this feature in common'. In fifteenth century municipal regulation there is less exclusive attention to the prosperity of the powerful merchants, and there are signs of a readiness to take account of both landed and civic interests in the develop- ment of territorial resources. There would be immense interest in tracing the history of particular towns ; in seeing how physical circumstances affected the beginnings of their trade ; and in noticing the precise fashion in which the commerce of any one reacted on its internal life, and favoured the local development of special branches of industry. Few things could be more instructive to the economist than to examine the precise mercantile policy which was pursued by different city-states in the Middle Ages", and to consider how far it tended to their success or brought about their failure. But it may be doubted if any one continental city directly con- tributed by its experience to the formulating of the schemes for national prosperity that were tentatively devised in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries and that were systematically pursued in the sixteenth and seventeenth. The course of industrial progress had been directed by the great cities of Italy and Germany; but after the age of discovery it was forced into new channels, and even those towns like Florence', which were most ready to ■ Compare Schmoller, Mercantile System, on the whole subject. " Naude, Die Getreidehandelspolitik der Europdischen Staaten, p. 17. In Brandenburg and other parts of Germany the expansion of town regula- tions to include considerable territories is specially noticeable. Schmoller, op. cit. 33. " For Florence see Pohlmann, Die Wirthschaflspolitik der florentiner Renaissance, p. 140. 150 Western Civilisation. [I300K V. adapt their institutions, were being left on one side. Me- diaeval civic life is of less interest in its bearing on ' the future than in its relation to the past; in the story of the great towns of the Middle Ages we may see how closely history sometimes repeats itself; for many purposes, their glory and their decay serve to illustrate the description that has been already given of the city-states of ancient Greece; and there was little in mediaeval town life that was a really new contribution ^ to the economic progress of the world. The rivalries of different cities and the ineffectiveness of experi- ments in confederation were causes of weakness in Germany and Italy as they had been in the Greek lands. In the fifteenth century the two former countries were far ahead of the rest of Western Europe industrially and commercially, and both had declined relatively, and perhaps absolutely, at the opening of the nineteenth. They had retained the old political form of the city-state, and this was not well adapted to guide and control new experiments in trade ; all their economic institu- tions were devised with the object of giving each merchant a fair share of the opportunities afforded by a well-known and limited market, and not with the view of obtaining access to new regions and ousting rivals by successful competition. Industrial progress had been restricted to suit the traditional policy of exclusive communities, and had not such free scope as it enjoyed in territories where the course of development was determined by the larger ambitions and the systematic policy of kings and their advisers. As we look back we may see that its ability to attain to national unity was the question of 1 Since history never repeats itself exactly, there is no law of uniformity in history as there is in physical nature, and generalisations can never be stated in a rigid form. Where there is a strong similarity, however, between the institutions in two distinct periods or places, the comparison of the minor differences throws much light on the special character of each. ^ The high development of the gild system in mediaeval towns as compared with those of ancient Greece in their best days, is an important difference. CHAP. l.J Secularisation. 151 supreme importance in the fifteenth century', so far as the immediate economic future of each country was concerned. By a curious irony those very countries, where the most notice- able mercantile success had been secured on the old lines were least ready to adapt themselves to the new conditions; and the very greatness and independence of the cities of Germany and Italy were obstacles to further progress. III. The welding of different areas of Christendom into large countries, each of which was a single eco- _. „. , nomic whole, was a consummation of the highest Nationalities- importance ; it would be most interesting in this of Roman"*^^ connection to try to trace out the various in- '^^'"■ fiuences which led to the consolidation of peoples and the rise of nationalities". Military necessities were often an important factor. In some cases, as in Spain, the growth of national unity seems to have been principally due to the pressure of a common enemy; the conquest of Granada added to the prestige of Ferdinand and Isabella, and strengthened the ties by which Castile and Aragon were held together. The seven provinces of Holland were forced into union under similar pressure, and common dangers have sufficed to fuse the varied population of Switzerland into a republican nation. In France the Crown proved to be the centre round which the patriotic sentiment, which resented the English domination, was able to rally. But besides these conscious antagonisms there were other factors which served to strengthen the monarchs who were beginning to exercise a large measure of independent power in their several territories and to mould the separate ^ Ehrenberg, Hamburg utid England, pp. 12, 35. * The insular position and physical conditions of England, and the administrative ability of her kings, had enabled her to attain to national unity at a very early time. Though her industry was far behind that of the other countries of Europe in the fifteenth century, she had developed national political institutions which enabled her to take full advantage of the opportunities that eventually came within her reach. Cunningham and MacArthur, Outlines of English Industrial History, -p. 23. 152 Western Civilisatjon. [BOOK V. portions of Christendom into well-administered polities. . No constructive influence was more important than that which was due to the revived study of Roman Law, for this helped to determine the character of the new civil authority that was absorbing those duties of government which ecclesiastical institutions could no longer successfully discharge. Roman jurisprudence was the characteristic product of the Roman mind ; its influence on the economic life of the modern world is the debt we owe to Rome herself, as distinguished from other civilisations of the past. The revival of the study of R.oman Law in the thirteenth century had an extraordinary influence on the political and consequently on the economic growth of modern Europe. Civil law proved an important destructive agent, sb far as the organisation of mediaeval Christendom was concerned, for its introduction aided in the process of secularisation by calling forth a class of civilians and temporal lawyers who could supersede the canonists'. The canonists had practically ac- knowledged the supremacy of the corpus juris civilis from which so much of their doctrine was borrowed"; and justice could be better administered in the civil than in the ecclesiasti- cal courts in those cases in which there were competing claims to jurisdiction. Throughout the greater part of Europe its triumph over badly codified customs was complete ; and Civil Law exercised an extraordinary influence in the moulding of thoughts and habits during the period of transition when the mediaeval was giving place to the modern. The re-introduction of Civil Law not only cleared the ground but distinctly told in favour of economic progress. The Church had established respect for property in barbarous times, and had thus laid the foundation on which all civilised society ' The increase of the towns in wealth supplied social conditions in which the pursuit of this study became possible and advantageous. Savigny, Geschichte des rSmischeti Rechts im Mittelalter (1834), III. 84. ^ Adams, Civilisation in Middle Ages, 36. CHAP. I.] Secularisation. 153 rests ; and the Roman Law with its distinctions facih"tated the discussion and decision of titles to property, and provided the means of defining and enforcing contracts. In some cases where the principles of the two systems were in conflict, there was a distinct advantage in the eventual triumph of the older code; for its conceptions' were in accordance with the money economy which was coming into vogue, and gave the means of thinking clearly about the new problems which the introduction of capitalism into industry and commerce was bringing to the front. The Law Merchant of the Middle Ages had been almost entirely derived from Roman sources ; and as the sphere of ecclesiastical jurisdiction became more restricted, the tone of commercial morality embodied in the Civil Code came to be more generally adopted. Canon Law had con- demned usury in a fashion that found little support in the legislation of Justinian ; the influence of the Christian system had doubtless been most beneficial during the transition from natural to money economy', but the restrictions which ec- clesiastical jurisprudence imposed on the conduct of business between wealthy merchants appeared to have no real justifi- cation, and a little ingenuity served to set them aside ^ The ordinary conscience of the plain man was clear that the lending of money at moderate interest was often fair and convenient to all parties in the mercantile community, and that only excessive gains were to be condemned as extor- tionate. This was the attitude of the CivU Code upon the subject, and the fact that merchants and financiers could appeal to such an authority in defence of their conduct must have done much to remove the ancient prejudice against ' Lamprecht, Zum Verstdndniss der wirlhschaftlichen und socialen Wandlungen in Deutschland vom 14. sum 16. yahrhundert, in Z.f. Social- und Wirthschaftsgeschichte, I. 247. * See below, p. 167. ' Ashley on the Contractus Trinus, Introduction to Economic History, I. ii. 440. 154 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. traders as a class, and to enable them to maintain their status and dignity as men who were engaged in an honourable calling. Even more important with regard to subsequent progress than these direct effects on economic life was the influence of Roman Law on the growth of njonarchies. Stich a maxim as Quod principi placuit legis habet vigorem tended to render the rising civil powers the " centre and source of the whole insti- tutional life of the state'," as the Emperor had been in ancient Rome. It implied an absolutist ideal ; and the ad- ministrators who were steeped in its influence, consciously or unconsciously, brought their ideas to bear in curtaiUng old privileges and in shaping new institutions. There is no country in Western Europe where the legal system was un- affected by the Civil Law; but its influence on the political life of a nation is most clearly seen in France, where it helped to build up a typical example of magnificent kingly power and state. The effects of Roman jurisprudence may be traced in the characteristic weakness as well as in the unique greatness of the ancien regime. 112. When the Hundred Years' War had come to an end, and France had rest for a time from the Monarchy and troubles that distracted her, strong and wise Bourgeois government was greatly needed for the sake of restoring social order and encouraging the agri- cultural, industrial and commercial activities which seemed to be almost extinct. France was fortunate in coming under the rule of kings who threw themselves energetically into the task. Charles VII and Louis XI were able to bring back com- parative prosperity to France as a whole. They called her into being as a nation with an economic life directed and in- spired by the monarch and his advisers; the congeries of separate cities and provinces was, for many commercial pur- poses, welded together into one country. On the other hand, the success of these monarchs in creating material prosperity ' Adams, Civilisation, 320. CHAP. I.] Secularisation. 155 anew, reacted on the position of the Crown ; the institution of a permanent taille'' supplied a regular revenue which enabled the kings to maintain a well-disciplined standing army and freed France from frequent pillage by unpaid mercenaries. This greatly augmented the royal power ; and it also brought home to the kings the direct gain which accrued to them personally from fostering the material prosperity of the trading classes in the community and thus providing an ample fund from which taxation could be drawn. In reorganising finance Charles VII was fortunate to be able to rely on the service of Jacques Coeur, a man who had a remarkable genius for making the most of the oppor- tunities that were left to his unhappy country. The district round Bourges, of which he was a native, had suffered less than the rest of France from the wars; and he was able to give new life to its struggling woollen manufactures. At the same time he succeeded in taking up the threads of the old trading connections on the Mediterranean; Montpellier^ became the principal centre of his operations, and attained to great importance till it was superseded by Marseilles. Jacques Coeur had visited the principal marts of the East; he obtained papal permission to trade with Mohammedans, and he was able to settle his factors in the towns of Syria and Egypt^. His achievements were astonishing, even though his success was short lived; as the concessions he enjoyed were personal to himself the trade he had established seems to have declined at his death. He forms, however, an in- teresting link between the earliei' prosperity of Septimania and the later commercial ambitions of the French monarchy. When viewed, not as a trader but as a financier, Jacques Coeur may be regarded as typical of a class of native mer- chants who assisted European monarchs in fiscal organisation; ' De Nervo, Les Finances franfaises, I. 93. * Germain, Histoire du commerce de MoiitpelKer, II. is,, ' rigeonneau, op. cit., i. p. 373. 156 Western Civilisation. [book v. the advances he made enabled Charles VII to recover Nor- mandy', Gascony, and Guienne. The transition to money economy in affairs of state had become complete; and the merchants had silver in their chests with which they could trade, but which they might be prevailed on to lend; they were the men whose knowledge of business enabled them to suggest expedients for raising money, to superintend the pro- cess of collecting it, and to make temporary loans to their royal masters. The practical alliance of the crowned heads of Europe and their wealthy subjects was profitable to both ; the kings were furnished with the resources they needed without being forced to accumulate treasure and keep money lying idle ; while the capitalists obtained trading privileges or mining concessions. Jacques Coeur was the most eminent of the merchant princes of his day ; the rapidity of his rise and the extraordinary wealth which he accumulated seem to have aroused the jealousy of less faithful servants of the Crown, and he was treated with base ingratitude by his master*. He was the most prominent figure in the finance of the times ; and since his day the political power of the banking interest, has been constantly felt. The city of Lyons seems to have been for a time the principal scene of their ope- rations' ; and the great capitalists of Augsburg and the Hanse towns were able to exercise an important influence on the political action of the princes from the fact that they could come to the royal support at critical moments*. The revival of French prosperity began in the time of Charles VII, when a great deal was done to improve internal ^ CMTaent, Jacques Coeur et Charles VII, 131. 2 It is interesting to compare and to contrast the career of the great English merchant-prince of the century — William Canynges of Bristol. Pryce, The Canynges Family. ' Endemann, Studien in der Rotnanisch-Kanonistischen Wirthschafis- und Rechtslehre, l. 158, and Ehrenberg, Das Zeitalter der Fugger, 11. 72. * Compare the Fuggers and Charles V, Ehrenburg, op. cit. r. 142, 152. The Hansards and Edward IV, R. Pauli in Haiisische Geschichtshldtter (187s). 75fol. CHAP. I.] Secularisation. 157 communications; he freed the country from brigandage and abolished the exorbitant tolls which had been exacted on the rivers. The work thus begun was carried on by his son Louis XI, who selected his counsellors largely from the com- mercial classes, and incurred much unpopularity with the noblesse by the attention which he gave to bourgeois interests '. Not that he was altogether popular with those whom he be- friended; local privileges —like those of the companies of merchants of Paris and Rouen on the Seine — might have to be set aside in the interest of the monarchy as a whole. In the industrial corporations the king claimed the right of nominating members on special conditions"; and thus these bodies, which had assumed a new importance with the revival of trade, were brought into direct subjection to royal authority. The organisation of a customs' department was necessary as a fiscal measure; but it caused considerable annoyance to traders. In spite of these difficulties, Louis XI succeeded in developing industrial activities and in consolidating the realm, so that it enjoyed a rapid increase in material prosperity during the peaceful days of Anne of France and Charles VIII. Thus the foundations of the French monarchy — as a centralised economic whole — were laid in the fifteenth century, though there was to be bitter humiliation and disastrous internal strife before Henry IV obtained the reins of power, and Sully and Colbert were able to continue the systematic development of the country. 113. The disruption of Christendom had proceeded some way before the Reformation and the struggle which Luther inaugurated by his defiance of ^^ t^g unU°of the Pope. The practical proof of the breaking Economic . , , , .... r Organisation. up of the old system lies m the appearance of new polities in its place. As early as the fourteenth and ^ Pigeonneau, op. cit. I. 397. ^ Levasseur, I. 438. On the corresponding movement for nationalising the municipal gilds in England, compare Growth of Industry, I. 436. 158 Westei'ii Civilisation. [BOOK V. fifteenth centuries we see traces of the rise of nationalities, and this change is of unique importance ; we now find something that is characteristic of the modern as distinguished from the ancient world, something that is economically new. The social forms of the household and the city have been found in all ages, since the days of Greek colonisation. Though there had been great states such as the military empires of Alexander and Augustus these were merely held together by force of arms, and the civilisation of these territories was concentrated in the various cities which had been preserved within their limits and survived their fall. The era of industrial prosperity that opened with the Crusades still took the old forms, and Christendom was planted with new and flourishing cities; but modern times were to witness the relative decay of city institutions. Material welfare was henceforward to be sought for and organised with reference to wider territories, and account was to be taken of the development of the resources and the industry of each country as a whole ; we have come upon a new unit of economic organisation. A country has been defined for economic purposes as a territory through which there is a free flow of labour and capital; and this will at least serve to point the contrast be- tween the city life of the Middle Ages, with its effort to maintain the exclusive privileges of each locality, and the broader life of modern times in which industry and commerce are organised, not for the profit of a particular place, but with a view to developing the resources of the whole country and promoting national progress. The definition helps us to note the material conditions which were necessary for carrying out a national economic policy ; unless a considerable amount of capital was available, it was impossible to develop the industrial capabilities of large areas; and so long as natural economy held good in rural districts there could not be a free flow of labour. The mediaeval and ancient worlds have been compared and Chap, i.] Secularisation. 159 contrasted above '; there were similar types of industrial and commercial organisation in each, but there was a difference of spirit and a difference of moral character between the two. The contrast of the ancient or the mediaeval with the modern, world is somewhat different, since the latter is characterised by the prevalence of a new basis of economic regulation and as a corisequence by a broader commercial policy directed to national and not merely to civic purposes. The nation was not, of course, an entirely new creation in the later Middle Ages, but it was a most important variant of an old political form ; the terms ' state ' and ' polity ' may be applied to cities as well as to nations, but the requirements and opportunities of the larger communities are very different, and the process of taking over and applying to the wider areas the best that had been developed in the experience of city life was no small undertaking. The fourteenth and fifteenth centuries were a period of increasing secular activity, and during this time old institutions and administrative machinery were being utilised for national objects. The nationalising of civic regulation is the new economic departure of the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries. The Roman Empire had preserved for a time the great municipalities as integral elements ; in its declining days they were ruthlessly exploited in the interests of the imperial govern- ment; the wealth of the richest citizens was the object of deliberate attacks. Modern governments have not shown the same jealousy of the well-to-do ; since rulers began to realise that their own power could be increased through the wealth of the people. The Crown was consciously dependent for occasional supplies on the great merchants ; it was not un- natural for princes to consult the opinion of financiers as to national welfare, and to give effect to their views as to the best economic policy for the country as a whole. Money was essential for the glory of the monarch, and he gradually ^ See nbove, p. 7. iCo Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. learned that he could not obtain it regularly and permanently unless it flowed steadily into the coffers Of the people'. Commerce thus came to be a recognised object, not only of local but of national importance; and attention to public resources was also nationalised. The food supply had been a mere matter of civic'' and municipal interest in ancient times, while in the modern world the development of agriculture has been taken up in a broader spirit as a national interest. The regulation of industry both in France and in England underwent a similar revolution ; what had been special to privileged towns and locally established in particular districts, was organised as a general policy ; gild regulations became embodied in Acts of Parliament which applied to all places alike ; the resources and requirements of the whole realm were carefully considered with the view of introducing new industries. In the ancient world we have seen the planting of towns, and subsequently the despoiling of towns in military a:nd imperial interests; but the development of the modern world has not been so much confined to urban communities on the one hand, nor has it taken place at the expense of towns on the other ; it has been guided by the larger conception of national wealth. In the succeeding chapters we shall be chiefly concerned with the growth and working of national economic policy', and national economic rivalries. This new economic type came into being partly at least as a result of the religious and political changes which brought about the disruption of Chris- tendom and gave rise to national polities. As we look back on the destruction of the old system and the consolidation of modern realms, it is not easy to analyse all the elements that have contributed to the new social form. Community of race is usually the foundation of nationality, and the structure 1 Discourse of Commonweal, edited by E. Lamond, p. 35. " The difficulty that was felt was that of catering for Athens or Rome, there was no question of tlie food supply of Greece or Italy as a whole. CHAP. I.] Secularisation. l6i may be compacted by the use of a common language, and experience of a common history, though men of diverse blood have been knit together by the influence of one government enforcing the same fiscal system and administering one code of laws. Another unifying element which was of primary importance in the sixteenth century was that of similar religionj the princes, as sovereigns, sought to enforce a uniformity of religious belief and practice within the realms over which they ruled. So far as the economic side of national life is con- cerned, nothing has been so important as the existence of a natural boundary to mark out a common country, with the consequent interaction of the different material interests which may cooperate so as to develop the resources and power of the whole polity. Each of these separate factors had played its part in the growth of national life and institutions; and at the beginning of the sixteenth century the geographical discoveries opened up vast fields for national rivalry and political ambition. The rising nationalities were brought face to face as conscious antagonists ; the East Indies and America disclosed to the monarchs of Europe a vision of new worlds to conquer. The social system of Christendom was falling to pieces, but European civilisation was not decaying, it was only being transformed. Fresh ideals were taking the place of old ones and were proving attractive, at a time when there were new facilities and opportunities for realising them ; the vigorous life which was thus springing up was able to supersede merely local interests, and gave rise to powerful and far-reaching commercial insti- tutions. C. w. c. II. I r l62 CHAPTER II. THE INTERVENTION OF CAPITAL. 114. The breaking up of a complex civilisation like that of mediaeval Christendom and the transition its necessary to the modern world involved so many and Conditions. ^^^j^ great changes, that we can only appreciate their character and importance when we look in turn at dif- ferent aspects of this revolution. From the religious stand- point, we have seen an increasing secularisation ; from the political point of view, we have noted the beginnings of the rise of nationalities ; and the economic factors which were at work in connection with both of these movements have been indicated. It is important, however, to look more closely at the special economic feature of this period of transition, and to note the gradual and increasing intervention of capital. In dealing with the Christendom of earlier ages we have found it unnecessary to take account of capital, for — as we under- stand the term in modern times, — it hardly existed at all. In the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries we may notice it emerging from obscurity, and beginning to occupy one point of vantage after another, until it came to be a great political power in the State. It served too, as an instrument for facilitating the development of commerce, of industry and of agriculture in the territories of European nations, and also for effecting the colonisation of the newly discovered lands. When we come CHAP. II.] The Intervention of Capital. 163 to trace the later developments of modern industry, we shall see the enormous power which it has eventually secured. We cannot attempt to give accurate dates or even assign definite limits to such changes as the progress of seculari- sation, and the rise of nationalities j it has only been possible to explain in part why corresponding political movements occurred at different time."- in different countries. It would be still more hopeless to try to treat the intervention of capital as an event which happened at a particular epoch, or a stride which was taken within a given period. It is a tendency which has been spreading with more or less rapidity for centuiries, first in one trade and then in another, in pro- gressive countries. We cannot date such a transformation even in one land ; for though we find traces of capitalism so soon as natural economy was ceasing to be dominant in any depart- ment of English life', its influence in reorganising the staple industry of this country was still being strenuously opposed at the beginning of the present century". The revolution — for this has been a real revolution — which came about so gradually in our own island, has run a different course in other lands ; there has been no regular series of steps in the march of capitalistic progress. We may, however, hope to get some clear ideas of the nature of the fundamental changes which have been brought about by the intervention of capital, if we are content to note some of the most striking mani- festations of this force, as it affected national policy and aided in the development of national economic life. ' The collection of the revenue was being organised on a money basis in the Norman and Angevin reigns, and there was scope for the operation of capitalists in farming the revenue and lending money to those who were not ready to meet the calls made upon them. ' The agitation of the Yorkshire weavers against the abolition of compulsory apprenticeship was due to conscious hostility to the capitalist organisation of the weaving industry. Growth of English Industry, 11. 455- II — 3 164 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. We have already noticed the partial persistence of natural economy in the later Middle Ages; with the era of the Crusades, however, there was a rapid extension of money economy, and therefore a general introduction of those" con- ditions under which the formation of capital and the em- ployment of credit became possible. Under natural economy they cannot exist; there may, of course, be accumulations of wealth, stores of many kinds and stock for carrying on industry ; but capital, properly so-called, implies the existence of a fund of money ^ which can be utilised in any direction and transported with comparative ease from place to place. In modern business parlance, 'capital' is regarded as es- sentially fluid"; and but for the existence of money, wealth could not have this character. Similarly, commercial credit only comes into being when men have wealth that can be readily realised in money, so that they can be trusted to have the means of meeting their liabilities at a definite date', 'Capital' and 'credit' have their analogues under a natural economy in stock in trade, and the reputation of being rich ; but these terms are essentially, as we know them in modern times, ' historical categories,' since they only become applicable in so fat as money economy has asserted itself as the order of the day. So far as town life is concerned, we cannot go back to any period when money economy was not dominant, and we find signs of capitalism and its influence in the cities from very early times. Merchants who carried on active trade appear to have been provided with ready money for their transactions. Though a great part of the industrial population coasisted of independent workmen organised in craft gilds, the principal companies ftf many towns in the fourteenth century were ^ Modem Civilisation, 125. " Capital may of course be ' sunk ' in land or ' fixed ' in other forms ;, the statement in the text refers to its nature rather than its applications. * Modem Civilisation, 44. CHAP. II.] The Intervention of Capital. 165 composed of capitalists ; both in Strassburg^ and in Florence' the manufacture of cloth was organised on capitalist lines by great captains of industry in the fourteenth century. Even in the most advanced towns, however, there were considerable hindrances which interfered with the free play of capitalist enterprise ; each merchant was restricted to one special trade, and was prevented from encroaching on the callings of his fellow-townsmen; there was little opportunity for the trans- ference of capital from one employment to another. Most of the industrial arts, too, were organised with regard to the require- ments of the city market by small independent masters, who each hoped to get a fair share of existing trade rather than to extend it; the regulations of their craft gilds were not favourable to the formation or application of capital. Similar obstacles existed in the rural districts, though they were gradually breaking down on all sides, so that there were steadily increasing opportunities for the investment of capital during the fourteentb and fifteenth centuries. 115. Capital was not, of course, a wholly new thing, since it had been familiar enough in the ancient world ; but many of its applications were being cond^^^s for introduced afresh into Christendom. The Medi- Minimising its ' . . possible Evils. terranean lands had undergone the transition from natural- to money economy and had come under the dominance of capital in ancient times. We have seen some- thing of the oppression which was exercised by moneyed men under the Roman Republic, and of the grievances to ^ Sclimoller, Die Strassburger Tiicher u. WeberzUnfte, p. 500. ^ The Arte di Calimala was engaged in importing and dressing and dyeing foreign cloth — a business which obviously required capital. The Arte delta Lana arose later ; its prosperity dates from the settlement of the religious order — the Urailiati — who had acquired the art in Flanders and prosecuted it with great success. In 1 338 there were 200 shops in Florence, employing 30,000 workmen : so that this industry was apparently also organised on capitalist lines. E. Dixon, Florentine Wool Trade in Transactions of Royal Hist. Soc. Xli. l6g. i66 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. which they were subjected under the Empire. We should never shut our eyes to the dangers which are inherent in money economy and the capitalistic organisation of society; but it is important to notice that at the time when this system was beginning to reappear in Western Europe there were tendencies at work which served to set limits to its influence and to minimise the evils it involved. Powerful as capital is, and great as are the advantages which it has to offer, the conditions of life in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries were so unfavourable to it as to delay its introduction and to check its operations. The whole social system stood in its way; for the organisation of much of the labour in the towns was so rigid as to admit of little modification, while in the rural districts the survival of villeinage presented still greater obstacles to the enterprise of moneyed men. Astriction to one place is perfectly congruent with natural economy ; the mediaeval landowner was satisfied to employ, as best he could, the labour which he found available, and was able to retain it under his control. With the capitalist, the case is different ; he possesses wealth which he can direct to any profitable undertaking that opens up, and he has the means of compelling or attracting labour to follow in the direction where his enterprise sees the probability of reward. So long as slavery was in vogue, the transference of labour could be effected in the most ruthless fashion by the purchase and export of slaves; but this was no longer possible at the epoch when capital began to take part in the industrial development of mediaeval Europe ; slavery had ceased to exist"; labour tended to follow capital because it was attracted, not because it was forced. In the fourteenth century the labourer had obtained such freedom that he was able to bargain for higher wages, and to insist on obtaining them. The craft gilds conferred a recognised status on skilled artisans'" ' I'"or some exceptions see above, p. 136. ' L.inipiecht, Deutsche Geschichte, IV. 189, CHAP. II.] The Intervention of Capital. 167 and defined a standard of comfort which helped to determine the workman's demands; they also set an example for the occasional or permanent organisations by which the labourers of lower grades tried to give effect to their ideas\ That capital, when unfettered, could be quite as oppressive as in the old days, was shown by the reappearance of slave industry in the New World, and at a later date by the degradation of labour under the stress of the Industrial Revolution. But on the whole it is true that the labourer had attained to such a status in Christendom that the organisation of agriculture and industry on a capitalistic basis could proceed on sound lines, and did not prove unfavourable to the material and social well- being of the working class. Capital has been a disintegrating force and has broken down the astriction of the serf to the soil, and the restriction of the artisan to the narrow limits imposed by the gild, but its action was restrained until they were capable of facing the new conditions. Capital has not crushed the individual workman as a man, or forced him into the degraded and helpless position of the labourer in the old world. Whilst the organisation of labour both in town and country limited the field for the application of capital to industry, the current sentiment on usury laid down practical restrictions which favoured the development of a healthy system of borrow- ing. In all ages of the world's history, there has been a temptation for the moneyed man to take advantage of the occasional necessities of his poorer neighbours and to lend money on exorbitant terms j in every period of transition from natural to money economy there is especial danger that this evil may arise, as it has commonly done^ in connection with the collection of a money revenue. Christian sentiment had set itself against the extortion of usurers, for this had been ^ On journeymen's gilds on the Continent see Schanz, Zur Geschichte der deutschen Geselkn- Verbdnde, 26 ; in England, Webb, Hislory of Trades Uuionhtitf 1 — II. " Vol. I. 47, 128, 187. i6S Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. one of the most blatant evils of the later Empire, but it had recognised as legitimate two distinct methods — apart from partnerships in commercial business' — in which capital might be temporarily transferred to a borrower. No objection was taken to the conduct of those who tried to buy a rent-charge, and thus to secure an income in perpetuity by sinking money in a definite estate. The return of the principal thus invested could only be obtained by reselling the rent-charge ; the man who entered into this agreement parted with his capital and obtained the right to enjoy a regular income. It was also regarded as permissible to lend capital for a definite time on a pledge, such as the Crown jewels, or the anticipated receipts from a tax; this secured the repayment of the principal at the date assigned, but was only supposed to ensure the return of the exact sum lent. Doubtless there was much evasion of the prohibitions against usury in actual life, but the fact remains that borrowing was chiefly done by wealthy bodies like towns, or by princes, for public purposes, and not by the cultivators of the soil. The peasantry continued to pay their quotas of taxation in kind or in service ; while the princes had recourse to moneyed men to advance current coin which should enable them to anticipate or to realise their wealth. It was not the poor taxpayers so much as the authority who levied the ta.K, that had recourse to the money-lenders. The sale of rents or pledging of property gave a town'' or a prince the temporary command of a large sum of money ; and the system which was developed for public convenience came, as capital grew more abundant, to be gradually introduced into private affairs as well. At all events the chief economic contrast between the later Empire and the later Middle Ages may almost be 1 It was always permissible to enter into partnership in risks and profits, but the opportunities of doing so were rare. Ashley, Introduction to English Economic History and Theory, i. i. 155. 2 Sclionberg, Finanzverhallnisse iter Stadt Basel im xiv. und xv. Jahr- huiidert, 90. CHAP. II.] The Intervention of Capital. 169 summed up in the fact, that the Byzantine statesmen devised expedients for despoiling the wealthy, while modern potentates were reduced to borrowing from them. The fact that capitalistic intervention in finance took this less oppressive form, was not only important so far as the peasantry' were concerned, but it also had a most favourable bearing on other monetary conditions. The gold paid by the industrial and mercantile classes to the Roman emperors was sunk in buildings or expended in wars on distant frontiers ; it was usually withdrawn from circulation in the district where it had been collected. On the other hand the money bor- rowed by princes from mediaeval bankers had to be repaid; it was not wholly sunk, and it was not merely dissipated; it was returned after a time into circulation and might be used as capital in industry or commerce. Hence the princely ex- penditure of the later Middle Ages did not prove as exhausting as that of the later Empire had been. In the fourth century the State was the oppressor of the men of enterprise and re- source; in the fourteenth it was becoming apparent that the interests of the monarchy and the moneyed men were the same in the long run ; government had on the whole to be conducted on principles that had the approval of financiers, and kings were learning that honesty in the repayment of loans was the best policy. Beneficial changes of many kinds resulted from this practical alliance between the princes and the capitalists and from the pressure which moneyed men could bring to bear on government. Their influence was felt most advantageously in connection with the circulating medium. The kings of Europe, like the emperors of Rome, had yielded to the temptation to snatch a temporary gain by debasing the coinage; and it was not always possible to demonstrate the dishonesty and inexpe- diency of the step in a convincing fashion. But the real ' That the incidence of taxation in France was such as to burden the peasantiy specially, is another matter. 170 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. inconvenience became apparent when it was necessary to repay large loans, especially if these loans had been negotiated by foreign capitalists who had stipulated as to the coin they would receive. The difficulty of contracting new loans, had a similarly educative effect ; it convinced the monarchs of the fifteenth century that it was wise to pay their debts and thus to maintain their credit. The evils of the transition were thus minimised, owing to the restricted and gradual manner in which the power of capital, with its influence on social organisation, was brought into play; and it must be borne in mind that the introduction of the new system under proper limitations was advantageous to society and to individuals of every class. In Athens, the ex- istence of money economy had rendered true political life possible, by conferring on the individual, freedom in the management of his time. In the modern world the preva- lence of money and capital has encouraged and facilitated freedom of movement from place to place ; it has thereby had a disintegrating effect on many institutions, but it has tended to promote a form of personal liberty which is highly prized in the present day. The feudal system implied the existence of local restrictions and responsibilities, and the feudal armies were based on local obligations, till capitalists were able to relieve the pressure of military obligations by pro- viding better armies of soldiers habituated to constant fighting and drawn from distant regions. Industry had been con- trolled by local organisations, with exclusive privileges and special powers of supervision; but at length capitalists were able to introduce new methods and processes under more effective supervision; and the localised gilds became an ana- chronism. The thoroughgoing introduction of money economy once again rendered personal freedom possible; and the change in later mediaeval times was not confined to the privileged citizens of great towns but also affected the peasantry and inhabitants of rural districts. CHAP. II.] The Intervention of Capital. 171 116. The intervention of capital eventually brought about an entire reconstruction of the social system of . ^ The new \Vestern Europe. The conditions under which finance in its this occurred have been described in the pre- MilitafyTnd ceding paragraphs and the character of the new Political order has been indicated in general terms. It ""e^^'^a '°"- is worth while, however, to consider some aspects of the matter in greater detail, and to examine the new administrative and financial machinery which these fresh activities shaped for themselves as they gradually entered into political life. The military system of the early Middle Ages was organ- ised on the lines that have been already described' in con- nection w^ith the Empire of Charles. Each political magnate maintained his own troops, and was responsible for bringing them into the field properly equipped and provisioned. The commissariat was irregular or non-existent, and it ■ might be hardly possible to retain an army in the field, or to continue siege operations at the critical moment in a campaign. The slightness of the political ties between the feudatories and the Crown rendered it difficult to get soldiers together, and they were likely to disband so soon as the specified time for which they were bound to serve had elapsed. Military operations carried on under such conditions were not only very ineffective but also extraordinarily expensive. The withdrawal of the industrial population and the yeomen from their work must have been a serious interruption to the ordinary processes of production, while the undisciplined hosts were only too likely to provide for their necessities by plundering the country in which they were quartered or through which they passed I The intervention of capitalists, who provided the means of hiring mercenary troops, and later of forming disciplined armies, rendered a better military organisation 1 See above, p. 51. " Cunningham, Growth of English Industry and Cominerce, I. 455, n. 8; Levasseur, Histoire des classes ouvriires, l. 421. 172 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. possible and reduced the indirect evils caused by war so as to make it far less costly. In so far as any king became possessed of money, so that he could hire mercenary troops, he had a more efficient fighting instrument at command, and one on which he could rely so long as his money lasted. The Flemish^ and later the Swiss mercenaries', were finer troops than the feudal levies, for they were habituated to constant fighting; not only were they better soldiers, but they were also more completely under control, so that the strategy of a campaign had a greater chance of being carried out as planned. These were militaiy advantages, and the economic benefits to a country were quite as great; the mercenaries could be paid in money at a definite and known date ; the raising of a feudal army had involved the disorganisation of ordinary industrial life, and an indefinite charge on the resources of the realm. The benefits which accrued from the intervention of capital were apparent, not only during the conduct of a campaign, but in all the preparations that might be necessary for a war; capitalists rendered the collection of revenue, in so far as it was taken in money, more 'convenient' and less 'ex- pensive^' The sale of offices, ecclesiastical and civil, is a cumbrous mode of obtaining supplies ; the payment of the large sums which were occasionally demanded as feudal aids must have been very oppressive. The voting of parliamentary supphes introduced comparative 'certainty ' into the system of taxation, as it enabled the landowners and merchants to know beforehand what they would have to pay. The action of the ^ Cunningham, Alien Immigrants, 25; Oman, A History of the Art of War [Middle Ages) {\ii)'S),y]t,. * The French frequently relied on Swiss help, and Lyons was found a convenient monetary centre for making the necessary payments to them. Ehrenberg, Das Zeitalter der Fugger, II. 72. * Compare Adam Smith's maxims of taxation, Wealth of Nations, v. Chap. II. pt. 2. CHAP. II.] The Intervention of Capital. 173 great bankers rendered this practice convenient, not only to the taxpayers, but to the Crown. Financiers were ready to advance money on the security of supplies that were actually voted, and thus to provide the Crown with the use of large sums at short notice, and long before it would have been possible to collect the money. When the advantages of the new method of military administration were once understood, no prince could afford to disregard them; all monarchs were compelled to rely on money as the sinews of war', and had frequent occasion to borrow in order to meet the exigencies of a campaign. The importance of a hoard of bullion had been recognised from time immemorial^; and the possession of the royal treasure, at any time of disputed succession, meant nine-tenths of the title to the Crown'. These hoards, like other forms of wealth, were subject to vicissitudes, however, and the accumulations of years might be rapidly dissipated or lost ; the princes were* compelled in such emergencies to turn to the Jews, Lombards, or others who afforded the means of replenishing the royal treasury at times when money was urgently needed. Great monarchs had not been particularly Scrupulous in keeping faith with these creditors*; but in the fifteenth century they were forced to be more careful in regard to their engagements. An inter-civic money-market had been developed. The great city communities of the Middle Ages were frequent borrowers', ' Macchiavelli argued on the other side, that war could be rendered profitable, and should be pursued as the best means of obtaining treasure. There have been many cases where it has been successfully conducted on this principle; but it is none the less true that the accumulation of treasure is a necessary preparation for successful war. Ehreriberg, 0^. cit. I. 6— g. 2 The Goths and other Teutonic peoples accumulated large treasures, but they seem to have employed it to gratify a taste for barbaric display, rather than as the basis of military power. ^ The case of Henry I of England furnishes an illustration. * Peruzzi, Storia del Commercio e del Banchieri di Firenze, 46r. * Ehrenberg, op. cit. I. 19. 174 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. since they had need of money both for civic improvements, such as the repair of their walls', and also for military opera- tions. As the security they offered was excellent, the terms on which they could obtain money were comparatively moderate^ The monarchs of the day were forced to offer good security, too'', in order to borrow at allj and they were compelled to repay the loans, if they wished to maintain their credit and be able to borrow again. The monarchies of Europe outstripped the civic communities as political powers, but the civic com- munities had forced the monarchs to accept mercantile methods and standards in the management of their finance. As the rulers of Europe ceased to be primarily dependent on landed estates for their revenue, some interesting con- stitutional changes followed. In Spain, the government monopolies of commercial or mining rights tended to increase the wealth of the Crown without enriching the subjects, and afforded the firmest basis for an absolutism*. The establish- ment of a permanent taille in France gave the Crown an in- dependent income, and rendered absolutism possible in that country as well. As the income of the Crown was derived from the taxation of the agricultural and industrial classes, it was essential that the people as well as the prince should be prosperous i hence the tendency of the French monarchy to the paternal regulation of industry with the view of rendering the country rich. In England the Crown's necessities contijaued to be the people's opportunities, and all attempts to exercise rule in disregard of the popular will were destined to failure. Not merely did the people as taxpayers succeed in enforcing their demands but there is reason to believe that the in- termediaries who negociated loans were also able to exercise ' Lamprecht, Deutsche Geschichte, iv. 212. " Towns occasionally made themselves jointly responsible with the kings for royal debts. Ehrenberg, op. cit. i. 25. * For this principle of state-craft compare Knies on Macchiavelli ah volkswirthschaftlicher Schriftsteller in the Zeiischrift f. d. gesammte Stoats- wissenschaft (1852), a^i. CHAP. II.] The Intervention of Capital. 175 considerable influence from time to time. The Fuggers, who supplied resources to Charles V, were in general sympathy with his aims ; they were forced by their own embarrassments to refuse him further advances at a critical moment and to ruin his hopes, but they seem to have made no attempt to control his policy. In England, on the other hand, the great London financiers and other royal creditors appear to have aimed at directing the economic policy of the realm and to have been fairly successful in forcing their views upon the Crown. Large sums of money were -borrowed from towns in their corporate capacity, and their representatives could make their wishes known in Parliament j from the time of Richard II onwards we can trace the existence in Parliament of a moneyed interest which gradually increased in influence till it at last succeeded in overbalancing the power of the landed gentry. 117. The financial magnates of the fifteenth and six- teenth centuries carried on business in a double capacity, as they not only engaged in lending markeu.""^^' money to the Crown, but were merchants as well. Their practice in this respect was of great importance, for it rendered their money-lending legitimate from the stand- point of the canonists. Christian moralists considered it fair that any man should be reimbursed for actual sacrifices in- curred in making a loan; to take so much as this in return was not to extort money from another, but to guard oneself against a definite loss. Men like Jacques Coeur or William Canynges or the Fuggers and Welsers' would not let their money lie idle ; and it was perfectly true that in lending it to the king they were depriving themselves of the opportunity of making commercial gain. It therefore came to be recog- nised that a lender might legitimately charge for lucrum 1 These Augsburg capitalists speculated in all sorts of undertakings; silver mining in the Tyrol, copper in Hungary, quicksilver in Spain, colonisation in Venezuela, estate management in Spain, and commercial ventures. Habler, Geschichte dei" Fuggerschen Handlungin Spanien. 176 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. cessans or damnum emergens; and no serious effort could be made to prevent such capitalists from entering on transactions which were practically advancing money on interest. In older days it had been possible for canon lawyers to distinguish oppressive from fair bargains by the mere form of the contract, and to limit the transference of capital, from one business to another, to those cases where a temporary partnership was formed, and risks and losses were shared alike. When it came to be generally assumed that a man would usually get some gain by investing his money, and was therefore entitled to be compensated for merely refraining from using it himself, the old prohibitions ceased to apply and the negociation of loans came to be an everyday feature of commercial life. In popular opinion, however, those merchants who devoted themselves to foreign banking and financial business, as con- trasted with the commercial export and import of goods, were generally regarded as somewhat unscrupulous. It is difficult to tell how far the common accusations were justified, either in the case of the Italians, who were the foreign bankers of the fourteenth century, or of the magnates of Antwerp and Amsterdam in the sixteenth and seventeenth. Possibly these capitalists were strong enough to manipulate the exchanges in their own interests, but there was at any rate a semblance of competition which seems inconsistent with the existence of monopoly rates; even in the fourteenth century there were occasional concourses of merchants when the rates for foreign payments were settled by bargaining in a market. Organised money-markets were held at the great fairs of Champagne \ Geneva^, and Lyons'; and bills from many distant towns were drawn for a definite date on bankers at these fairs. The coin ' F. Bourquelot, &iudes sur les foires de Champagne in Memoires prhentes h VAcadimie des Inscriptions, 2°" S^rie, V. (1865), Vol. 11. p. 102. * Borel, Les foires de Genive, p. 131 — 142. ' Huvelin, Droit des AlarchSs et des Foires, p. 564. CHAP. II.] The Intervention of Capital, 177 of each country was rated in terms of a standard unit (scudi de marche^), and money was bought or sold at this price. In so far as this represented the difference in the fineness of the coins respectively, the work of exchangers was of course recognised as necessary and useful business, which had to be attended to in the interests of the currency^. There must have been times, however, when the rates were affected by the supply and demand for bills on a particular country, and by the purchasing power of money in that country. From the standpoint of the mediaeval moralists there was much suspicion, to put it no more strongly, attaching to all such transactions ; they held that silver was silver, and that for anyone to get ad- vantage by exchanging silver for silver must somehow be unfair. Still these occasional money-markets existed ; and though much unfair gain may have been made by unscrupulous men, the gradual development of regular markets and constant com- petition circumscribed the opportunities for exacting exorbitant rates in performing a real service. As a result of these changes in opinion, the most powerful restrictions which had checked the fluidity of capital were broken down; in the fifteenth century it had at last become possible to obtain the means of developing any promising undertaking. 118. During the latter part of the fifteenth century many favourable openings at home and abroad were The influence beginning to offer themselves to enterprising of capital in men ; the exclusive privileges of aliens had been mercia"! nl™ curtailed, and the active trade of France and of industrial -m 1 J 4 practice. Holland ^ of Scandinavia and England , was 1 Endemann, op. cit. I. 214. " Cunningham, Growth of English Industry and Commerce, I. 362. 3 Van Bruyssell, Histoire du Commerce en Belgique, u. 63. * The importance of the English moneyed men is seen in the number of capitalist companies which were found towards the close of the fourteenth century ; as well as in the assessments of merchants and the large loans advanced by the towns. Cunningham, op. cit. I. 381. C. VIT. C. II. i3 178 Western Civilisation. [booK V. attracting native energy. The profits on successful ventures were large^ and every new prospect of profit constituted a demand for capital. And the supply was forthcoming ; hitlier- to prudent persons had been content to hoard their wealth"; so soon as they were persuaded to invest it in economical under- takings for the sake of gain, they were treating it as capital. The best opportunities, of course, lay with those who had the good fortune to live on any of the lines of the world's trade. The Venetians enjoyed a supremacy in the Adriatic", and a leading position in the trade with the East by the Red Sea route ; the German merchants, who crossed the passes and distributed the spices and otlier products of the East in the land beyond the Alps, found the connection most advantageous. The Genoese were able to carry on their trade with Con- stantinople and the Black Sea with little interruption, and the Florentines did a large business with the north coast of Africa. But all this commerce was dwarfed by the ocean voyages which became possible after the discovery of the Cape of Good Hope and of America ; Lisbon superseded Venice, and the Netherland merchants, who had found the fishing trade a remunerative industry^ and a good apprenticeship for seamen, took up the carrying trade between the Spanish Peninsula and Antwerp. This city, as a northern depot for Eastern produce, as well as the centre of a large trade in fish and in cereals, entered on a career of extraordinary prosperity in the sixteenth century. The rate of mercantile profit was doubtless very large, but expenses were heavy too ; many of the fairs, where traders of all nations had had unusual facilities for free in- tercourse, had declined before the close of the fourteenth ' The profits of Spanish merchants in the American trade are said to have been 300 or 400 per cent. Beer, Geschkhie des Welthandels, II, 147. ' E. Dudley, Tree of the Commomveal, 52. " Lenel, Die EiUstehimg der Vorherrschaft Venedigs, p. 82. * Van Briiysscll, II. uy. CHAP, li.] The Intervention of Capital. 179 century', and business was gravitating more and more to towns which served as permanent, and not occasional, centres of trade. But to trade regularly in any town it was necessary to pay the requisite dues arid obtain a definite status ; the cost of obtaining such a standing was only lightened in the case of companies of merchants, like the merchants of the Hanse League, who had establishments of their own in London'', Bruges', Bergen*, Novgorod', Venice^, and elsewhere, and who made rules which enabled them to share the advantages and the expense of maintaining their factories. The discipline was very strict, and their regulations were framed so as to ensure that no one man should monopolise the commerce, or encroach unduly on the trades of other people'^. This system, depending, as it did, on the maintenance of exclusive privileges, was inconsistent with that freedom for enterprise in pushing trade which is the life of modern com- merce. Antwerp proved attractive to capitalists, not only because of its situation and connections, but because it per- mitted almost as much liberty to the men of all nations as they could have enjoyed in any fair. There were practically no special concessions, and hence it was possible for any merchant to trade there; but besides this, no objection was made at Antwerp to the practice of dealing on com- mission", The freemen and privileged merchants of any ^ Cunningham, Alien Immigrants, 91. Huvelin, op. cit. 278. " Lappenberg, Geschichte des Hanslschen Stahlhofes zu London, p. 6. ^ Stein, Die Genossenschaft der deutschen Kaujleute zu Briigge, p. 14. * Worms, La ligue hanseatique, 163. ^ Daenell, Geschichte der deutschen Hanse, 45. " Stieda, Hansisch- Venetianische Handelsbeziehungen im \tijah.rhiindert; see also Simonsfeld, Der Fondaco dei Tedeschi in Venedig und die deutsch- venetianischen Handelsbeziehungen, II. 69, 71. This establishment was chiefly frequented by South German merchants. ' An excellent illustration of the policy is given by the Stint of the English Merchant Adventurers. Cunningham, Growth of English In- ' dustry and Commerce, I. 416. * Ehrenberg, op. cit. II. 6. . 12 — 3 l8o Western Civilisation. [JiOOK V. mediaeval city had been peculiarly careful to retain their exclusive advantages, and to prevent any broker from acting on behalf of an unfree trader; each merchant dealt personally or through his own factors. But at Antwerp there was no leason for maintaining such limitations, and forms of business agency, which have become universal in the modern world, were first introduced in the city on the Scheldt. The great South German bankers fixed their principal establishments at this centre ; they were attracted by the openings it offered and they helped to promote its prosperity. Merchants en- joyed far greater facilities for obtaining loans at low rates of interest, and for any period that might be desired, in the Antwerp money-market, than had been at all usual even in the fairs of Champagne and Lyons. Bruges' with its long- established reputation was unable to shake off the old com- mercial traditions, and was rapidly superseded by Antwerp, where business was conducted on the lines that were most convenient to enterprising capitalists. As commercial intercourse revived and increased during the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries, it tended more and more to bring about a revolution in industrial life. .Groups of small masters, each of whom was working on his own account though they were associated together for mutual supervision, were neither able nor willing to adapt themselves to new condition^; ajid they were gradually superseded in the more important callings by capitalists who employed large numbers of journeymen. One craft after another was affected by the opportunities which the expansion of trade afforded, and artisans began, under the direction of merchants, to manufacture, ' Van Bruyssell, li. 232. ^ Holland appears to offer an interesting exception, as the small in- dependent masters held their own in all the old industries during the seventeenth century though newly-planted trades were organised on capitalist lines. Pringsheini, Beitrdge zur wirthschajtlichen Entwirkdiing der vereiniglen Nicdirlande, iu Sclimoller's Forschun^en, X. iii, p. 30. CHAP, ir.] The Intervention of Capital. i8i not merely with reference to the requirements of their neigh- bours and the demand in the city market, but with a view to the possibilities of sale in distant places. There were some trades — such as the silk trade in Italy in the fifteenth century — which were forced to rely on commercial intercourse for a supply of the materials they employed; but whenever, and from whatever reason any industry was drawn into the circle of distant trading interests, there was a tendency in. favour of the introduction of capitalistic organisation. Capit- alist merchfnts were required as intermediaries to purchase materials or to sell goods, and they easily sUpped into the position of capitalist employers who directed their workmen and controlled the conditions and terms of labour. The views of a capitalist employer of labour and those of small independent masters would often differ as to the rules which were beneficial in any trade. The capitalist would wish to be free to employ as many journeymen as he liked, with such division of labour as was convenient, while the small masters would object to an establishment which was so organised as to engross a great part of the trade. There might also be differences about the training of apprentices and the numbers in which they should be employed; the capitalist policy diverged from tliat which was traditional in the craft gilds. In sonie cases, where the difficulty arose, the wealthy members appear to have been strong enough to take the control of the gild affairs into their own hands, and to modify the institution till it became an oligarchical association of capitalist employers ; many of the corps de metiers in France appear to have been thus transformed' ; and bodies which had been originally associations of small masters came to be prac- tically identical in character with such a capitalist company ' H. Hauser, Ouvriers dn. temps passS, p. 119 fol. Com]Daie also for Germany, Lamprecht, Deutsche GescliiclUe, v. 64. A similar change of character can be traced in the tailors of Bristol. Fox, Merchant Tailors of Jirislol, 32, 86. 1 82 Wesfa^n Civilisation. [BOOK V as the Arte di Calimala at Florence'. In other cases the small masters were able to maintain the traditional policy, and the capitalist employers preferred to migrate beyond the range of gild authority. The restrictive regulations which the crafts imposed on journeymen forced them to withdraw from such old centres of trade as Worcester' and York to districts where moneyed men were free to offer them better terms; particular towns were impoverished but the national industries were fully maintained, and capitalists and wage-earners alike benefited by the changes. In this way it appears that capital afforded facilities for inducing labourers to migrate, and thus helped to transplant the arts of life and to open up undeveloped regions. In the earlier times labour had been practically restricted to one city or to one estate, and there had been great difficulty in transferring it to places where it could be more advantage- ously employed. But capital solved this difficulty ; it gave the means of introducing bodies of labourers and setting them on work, so as to plant a new industry or to open up mines and develop unused resources. Capital supplied the material means of fostering the national wealth of any qountry, and of thus giving effect to a progressive economic policy. ' See above, p. 94. ' Cunningliam, Growth of Industry, i. 512, 518. CAMB. UNIV. PRESij The era of LATIN EXPANSION. To face /. 1S3 183 CHAPTER III. RIVAL COMMERCIAL EMPIRES. The Portu- guese secure a footing in the East. 119. The peoples of Western Europe at last secured direct access to the East through the persistent enterprise of the Portuguese; but this is only a small part of the debt we owe them. Their undaunted energy and heroic sacrifices over- came extraordinary difficulties and rendered it possible fqr European traders to establish a footing in the Indies, and to open up regular commercial communications with lands that had hitherto been inaccessible. The object, of the Portuguese Crown in promoting the voyages of discovery had been clear enough ; it was desirable to obtain a share in the Eastern commerce which enriched the Venetians through their trading allies, who monopolised the Red Sea route and the Persian Giilf. The active commerce of these seas was entirely in the hands of Arabs ; they had settlements in many towns, and there was a considerable Mo- hammedan population at some of the ports '. The Arab mer- chants, whom Vasco de Gama and the other Portuguese captains encountered in Indian waters, were not inclined to brook any interference with their profitable monopoly. This mercantile and seafaring race were little more than aliens on the coasts of the Indian peninsula ; but as they were long-established aliens they were able to rouse the Zamorin of Calicut into hostility ' Rowlandson, Tohfut-til-MtiJahideen (Oriental Translation Fund), 70. 184 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. towards the Frankish intruders. The Portuguese had not at- tempted to found a factory there on their first visit (1498 A.D.), and when the experiment was made on their second voyage (1500 A.D.), it proved a disastrous failure; for their representa- tive and his associates were murdered as soon as the ships had left. This was an offence which the Portuguese could not overlook, and it led to their first rupture with a native prince. They thus learned that it was impossible for them to share in the trade of the Arabs, or to have factories side by side with Mohammedan merchants in the same port; they could also count on a cordial reception in places where they were not thwarted by these commercial rivals. The Nestorian Christians' were a considerable body, whose influence was favourable to men of their own faith ; and the Hindu princes were glad to find any power that could stay the progress of the Mohammedan races, which were encroaching by conquest on the north and carried on an exclusive commerce on the south. Favoured by these circumstances, and by the divisions in the Mohammedan world' which prevented any united at- tack upon them till they were well established', the Portuguese were able to found commercial factories at Cochin (1501 a.d.) and Cannanore (1502 a.d.) on the Malabar coast. They quickly attained such maritime superiority as to monopolise the trade of these towns, and vessels which were not protected by Portuguese permits* were destroyed. Portugal thus began to enforce an effective sovereignty in the Indian Ocean. In order, however, to control the spice trade with Europe, and to transfer this business from the Arabs and Venetians ' Beazely, Portuguese Colonial Empire in Royal Hist. Trans. (1894), viiT. 115, 116. ' H. Morse Stephens, Albuquerque, 77. ' Suliman organised such an attack soon after his accession in 1520. See Morse Stephens, of. fit. 177. * Rowlandson, Tohfut-td-Mujahideen, 90. , CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 185 into Portuguese hands, it was necessary to obtain the command of the gates through which trade passed at Aden and the Persian Gulf. This had been a favourite scheme with King Emmanuel; and more than once the establishment and con- solidation of the settlements , in the East were sacrificed to fruitless efforts at closing the Red Sea route from Suez to the East'. The Portuguese first established themselves on Socotra (1507 A.D.), and eventually secured possession of Aden for a time (1517 — 1538 A.D.); but Albuquerque, with all his genius, had never been able to give full effect to his master's purpose. Still he was so far successful in hampering the Arabs in their Red Sea trade as to cause a serious diminution of the customs which passed into the hands of the Sultan of Egypt. The Portuguese were more fortunate in their attempts to control the navigation of the Persian Gulf, through which access could be obtained to the Euphrates valley and the caravan routes to the Levant. They obtained permission to establish a fortress at Ormuz and subsequently got possession of the entire city ; they were in consequence able to claim a maritime authority over the whole of the trade of that region ; coasting voyages were the usual method of communication, except during the Monsoon, and those who possessed this harbour could command the route''. The most simple, and at the same time the most efficacious method of obtaining the desired monopoly was to exercise a control over the spice trade at its source. All the commerce of the Spice Islands, as well as of the Far East, was con- centrated at Malacca ; and after establishing a factory at this point the Portuguese soon found a pretext for taking possession of the town. They were consequently able to regulate the supply of pepper and nutmeg in their own interests ; while this commercial dep6t gai^e them a basis from which they could ' H. Morse Stephens, op. cit. 94. 2 Compare Vol. I. p. 6^ on the spheres of Greek and Phoenician influence. 1 86 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. push their trading connections in China (1517 a.d.) and Japan (1542 A.D.)\ They thus laid the basis for the establishment of direct and regular commercial intercourse between Europe and the principal countries of Asia, and for nearly a century they succeeded in retaining as their own a monopoly of the trade they had wrested from the Arabs. Almeida and many of the Portuguese would have been content to aim at making their sovereignty of the sea effective by maintaining a strong navy; they believed that this would give adequate security to the commercial factories which were planted at different points of the coast. But Albuquerque, the greatest of the Portuguese governors, was convinced that this policy was impracticable; he set himself to obtain so much land as would enable him to maintain self-sufficing stations which might serve as a basis for the operations of his ships. Without adequate territory it seemed to him impossible to keep up the efficiency of the fleet, so that it should be able to protect the factories from attack by land, and to over- power the naval expeditions that might be expected from Egypt. With this object he forced the hands of the home government, and established, not mere commercial factories, but garrisoned fortresses; he also obtained such concessions of tribute as might render the administration of the new empire self-supporting. The final conquest of Goa, and the organisation of a Portuguese Civil Service to take over the government of the territory, were the fruits of Albuquerque's unwearied efforts to develop the commercial empire of his master on a basis that he believed to be really sound, and to offer a prospect of permanence. The Portuguese were engaged in a new undertaking ; ' but the commercial intercourse which they established on the new route, very closely resembled that of the Venetians and Arabs whose profitable monopoly was now a thing of the past^ It * Saalfeld, Geschichte des portug. Kolonialwesens, 104. ' Heyd, op. cit. n. 517. CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 1 87 was the practice of the Portuguese to send out a fleet to the Indies once a year ; the management of the undertaking was in the hands of officials, though the merchants who sailed in the ships were independent traders. They had to pay customs to the government, and certain articles were reserved as a State monopoly'; though the organisation of the fleet had a political and military character, the actual trading was a matter of private enterprise'. In this we have a very close repro- duction of the system that regulated the fleets of Venetian galleys which traded in the Mediterranean'. It was also the deliberate purpose of Albuquerque to substitute a Christian for the Arab trading population which had carried on active commerce in the Indian Ocean. He took their capital Goa, and used the lands which had belonged to mosques for the endowment of Christian Churches and monasteries ; and by deliberately encouraging the marriage of Portuguese soldiers with native women, and the growth of a Eurasian population, he set himself,, like Alexander, to bring about the fusion of the East and West. It was a bold line of policy, and one which later rulers of India have scarcely dared to follow; it certainly had its dangers; for the corruption of the adminis- trative class, and weakening of the moral fibre of the Portuguese is commonly associated witl;i their adoption of ^ Iliibler, Geschichte der Fuggerschen Handlung in Spanien, 24. ° The merchants who travelled by the fleet were not necessarily Portuguese, and Germans were allowed to fit out ships for the voyage. F. Kunstmann, Die Fahrt der ersten Deutschen nach dem porittgiesischeii Indieii, p. 5. Many interesting details will also be found in the Tagebuch des Lucas Rem, edited by Grcilf in the Sechsundzwanzigster Jahres-Bericht des kistorischen Kreis- Vercins im Regierungsbezirke von Sclnaaben und Neuburg (Augsburg, 18C1), and in J. P. Cassell, Primlegia und Hand- lungsfreiheiten luelche die Konige von Portugal ehedem den di:utschsn Kaiijleuten zu Lissabon ertheilet haben. " On the organisation of the Venetian fleets see Lenel, op. cit. 68. On the similar organisation of the Flanders galleys compare R. Brown, State Papers, Venetian, I. pref. p. Ixii. For the Portuguese fleets see Saalfeld, op. ci:. 138. 1 88 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. Eastern habits. The attempts which were made by the In- quisition to prevent the deterioration of Christian principle by contact with heathen and Mohammedan peoples were mischievous in other ways. The action of the Holy OfHce was disastrous to the ancient Church of India, which was suspected of heresy, while it was powerless to check the wrongs which were wrought by greedy and irresponsible officials. Even in the days of its greatest prosperity the commercial empire of the Portuguese proved disappointing j it failed to supply the streams of wealth which had been expected. The reasons for this are obvious ; such efforts had to be exerted to maintain the political conditions, under which this trade had become possible, that the energies of Portugal were exhausted, and the profits of commerce did not repay the outlay. It is marvellous that a nation of 3,000,000, and an army of 40,000, should have sufficed to obtain a supremacy over the whole of the Indian Ocean, and to secure a footing in Africa and in Brazil as well ; but when we read of the frightful loss of life in each expedition, we cannot be surprised that the effective force of the country was sapped in the course of such a gigantic struggle. It is to be noticed, too, that the enterprise of individual citizens was diverted /rom fruitful industrial employments and even from shipping; the Indian commerce, which centred at Lisbon, did not react favourably on home industry or internal trade, and the active work of distributing the Indian products in Europe was done by alien merchants'. All those who ' " Nowe lett us goe to the good simple Portingall who full hongerly for spices almost sales yeerely in compasse about 3 quarters of the world, and when they have brought their spices home are not the riche purses of Antwerp, the subjects of King Phillip ready to ingrose it into their handes and oftentimes give money for it aforehand." Epistle to the most noble and illustrious Lordes Edzart and John, Earles of Estfrizland, Lordes of Emden (1564), f. 7. Sloane MS. S18, British Museum. The Hollanders and Zeelanders did most of the shipping, especially after the fall of CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 189 wished to better their fortune sought for administrative posts, and many of the ofifioials were tempted to try to advance their personal interests more quickly by a resort, to unfair means. Eventually the administration became exceedingly corrupt and therefore very expensive; but even in its best days, the political outlay which was necessary for developing the trade absorbed all the profit to which the Portuguese rulers had so confidently looked forward. It is also true that the economic policy of the Portuguese was not commercially sound; it depended to a large extent on their power to oust the Arabs and to secure a monopoly ; they had few products or manufactures to export in exchange for Indian spices, and they were reluctant to send silver abroad. They might have succeeded by means of military power in extorting a tribute, but political changes at home upset their whole commercial system. After 1580 a.d. the fortunes of Portugal were linked to those of Spain, and the enemies of Spain attacked the trading factories of the Portuguese ; these had no means of effective resistance, since their commerce had not been based on physical advantages but on political superiority. When the Dutch were strong enough to defy the united forces of the Iberian peninsula they were easily able to direct the trade with the Indies into new channels, and thus they entered into the enjoyment of the possessions which the Portuguese had so hardly won. Though the fruits of Portuguese enterprise were wrested from them so soon, we cannot but give a tribute of admiration to the men who had the heroism and enthusiasm to win their way against such odds as Albuquerque faced. They were in a way heirs of the old crusading spirit, at least on its commer- cial side; they broke the Arab monopoly in the Indian Ocean and rendered it possible for that great peninsula to be brought into contact with Christendom. They were less successful Antwerp; though Danzic and the Baltic Hanse towns were keen com- petitors. Hiibler, op. cit., 174. igo Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. in Africa, and the Arab trader remains as one of the curses of that benighted land ; but India and the Far East have been rescued from his exclusive domination. Though the principal motive was merely commercial, and as such one with which he would have had but little enthusiasm, the hopes of Prince Henry were at last accomplished; the flank of the advancing Crescent was turned, and the Moslem power was threatened at its very heart. Portugal was exhausted for the time* lay the effort, but the world is a gainer in that she was ready to take the lead. 120. There is a contrast in every particular between the yj^^ history of the rise of the Spanish Colonial Empire Spaniards and that of its neighbour in the Iberian reasure. Peninsula. The Portuguese obtained access to a highly civilised country, and sought to bring a profitable trade under their own control ; the Spaniards secured a footing among barbarian and half-civilised peoples, who had made but little progress in the arts of life and had no organised trade. The Spaniards encountered no opposition in attempting to colonise southern and central America; they were perfectly free to deal with the country they had conquered as they pleased, and were able to give effect to their views as to the wisest use to make of their power and the best methods for utilising the resources of their new possessions. The decline and fall of their influence in these countries has demonstrated that the economic policy which the Spanish king and his advisers pursued was completely mistaken. The mineral wealth of the new world seemed to open up ' The revival of the Portuguese power under the House of Braganza in the seventeenth century was undertaken on other lines. The colonising of Brazil had been deliberately neglected in the period of Portugal's grJ^atest prosperity, and the efforts of the Marquis of Pombal to develop native industry in the eighteenth century may be regarded as an imitation of Henry IV and Colbert, or as an attempt to shake off the influence of England by copying English methods. CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 191 the prospect of accumulating such a vast treasure, that it would enable the Spanish monarch to determine the destinies of Europe. The realm which had been consolidated by the marriage of Ferdinand and Isabella and the conquest of Granada had ample resources of its own ; in some parts the soil was admirably cultivated, while there were also large areas devoted to pasturage, and the native wool supplied ample materials for an extensive manufacture of cloth. The long wa:rs against the Saracens seem, however, to have had dis- astrous effects both on the country and on the population ; the land had been rendered less fit for tillage', and the military ardour of the people^ distracted them from the drudgery and comparative indignity of agricultural or industrial pursuits. The conquest of the new world with its mineral treasures was congenial to the national temperament. It was a task calling for military prowess; and the rapid success of the Spaniards raised the expectation that they would be able to accumulate such masses of treasure that they would be irre- sistible. Severe prohibitions were enacted to prevent the ex- port of gold or silver from Spain, in the hope that other nations, which were possible political rivals, might be precluded from having a share in the mineral wealth that was annually imported to Seville. This was the staple port where the India House was established and all the trade was concentrated': the galleons were loaded at Seville in August and Septembei, and then dropped down to Cadiz, where they waited for a favourable wind ; one armada accompanied the fleet, and another cruised the seas, as far as the Azores, on the look- out for pirates. On the return voyage the fleets bringing the silver plate from Mexico and Peru were combined at Havana, ^ Naude, Die Getreidehandelspolitik der europiiischen Slaaten, 181. » lb. 182. ' J. de Veilia Linage, Spanish Rule of Trade, translated by Stevens, p. S+. In later times goods intended for consuraplion in Spain might be landed at any port where the vessel touched. 192 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. and sailed together for Spain about the month of June'. Masses of bullion were brought to Spain, especially in the eleven years from 1545 a.d. onwards, during which the mines of Potosi yielded annually, at the lowest computation, 2,215,000 pesos'. The government obtained a large revenue from customs, and was at pains not only to protect the plate-fleet by sea, but to prevent the export of the bullion that was safely landed at Seville. But the policy thus pursued proved a disastrous failure : the Crown never enjoyed a period of repose when saving was possible ; the wars of Charles V were too costly to permit the formation of a hoard; the India House was crippled by the loss of the Armada, and Philip II died deeply in debt'. The bpaniards had sacrificed everything else to the attempt to build up political power by the mere accumulation of bullion ; their want of success in the main object of their policy left them so impoverished as to demonstrate that the means by which they pursued it had been grossly mistaken. Spanish colonial policy was at fault, as little attention was given to the cultivation of the soil, or to the planting of any industry. The colonists exported such natural products* as could be obtained with little labour, and devoted all their energies to mining operations ; the working of the mines was not a government monopoly, but was carried on by private enterprise. Large as were the total returns, it does not seem to have been a profitable speculation in all cases*; and at ' J. de Veitia linage, Spanish Rule of Trade, 193. " Soetbeer, Edelnietall-Produktion (1879), fi. The opening of the mines of Potosi ahnost synchronised with the discovery of improved processes of reducing the ore with quicksilver. '^ Beer, AUgemeine Geschichte des Welthandels, II. 147. Ehrenberg, op. cit. II. 259. * See the list in J. de Veitia Linage, op. cit. Preface. ' The determination of the Fuggers in 1531 a.d. to drop their scheme of colonising in S. America after they had succeeded in procuring all the necessary concessions may be taken as indicating their view of the value of colonial investments. Habler, Die Geschichte der Fuggerschen Handlung, 67. CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 193 all events it diverted both capital and labour from attempts to develop the other resources of the colonies. Mining on a large scale was pursued in a manner that was detrimental to the native population ', and rendered it necessary for the under- takers to procure more stalwart labourers by arranging for the importation of negroes. The regular business of supplying 4000 to 5000 negroes per annum was contracted for in turn by the Portugue'se and the Genoese; the Spaniards, with all their faults, had a rooted dislike to taking part personally in the traffic'', and in the eighteenth century it came to be absorbed by the English merchants, who outbid the French. There was little labour available for other occupations than mining, and as a consequence the colonists were dependent on the mother country for supplies of all kinds, not merely for textiles and manufactured articles, but for cereals as well'. They had of course the means of purchasing these goods easily with the silver of the mines, but the Spanish colonies would have been far stronger if more vigorous attempts had been made to develop their general resources. The colonial market for Spanish foodstuffs was large, and it might have afforded a great stimulus to tillage in the Peninsula, where there were doubtless regions which were able to respond to the increased demand'. But in many parts of Spain natural economy still held good, while other districts had not recovered from the devastation and depopu- lation caused by the war. The colonial requirements were so considerable that they caused a rapid rise of rates in the home ^ Leroy Beaulieu contends that the oppression of the Indians in con- nection with mining has been much exaggerated. De la Colonisation chez lespeuples modernes, p. 14. ^ J. de Veitia Linage, op. cit. 159. " Martin Hume, Spain, 1479 — 1788, 84. * Charles V made considerable improvements in Aragon which ren- dered large tracts of territory available for tillage. Martin Hume, op. cit. 85. c. w. c. 11. 13 194 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. markets; considerable purchases of growing crops' were made by merchants who wished to export them, and the government endeavoured by legislation to prevent the rise of prices. Again and again the Cortes were compelled to raise the maximum tariff of permissible rates", but these imperfectly successful efforts to keep prices low rendered agriculture less profitable. There were other difficulties to which tillage was exposed ; the mesta, a great organisation of sheep farthers with ancient privileges, not only objected to the increase of tillage at the expense of pasture', but exercised their rights in the driving of their flocks so as to injure the arable farms through which they passed on their great migrations*. Altogether the legislation of the Cortes was so unfavourable to agriculture that the Spanish corn-growers derived little advantage from the great colonial demand. The depressed condition of tillage, arid the fact that food continued to be scarce and dear, was one of the main reasons for the failure of the Spaniards to reap the benefit of the large colonial market for textiles and other manufactured goods. For a time indeed there was a rapid expansion; German capitalists settled in the country^, and manufacturing was conducted on a considerable scale; Cuenza and Seville were the centres of the cl6th trade, Valladolid of the silk industry, Cordova of leather manufacture, and Toledo of the production of arms". Foreign labour followed in the wake of ' Bernays, Zur inneren Entwkkelung CasHliens in Quidde, Deutsche Z. f. Ceschichtswissenschaft (iSSci), I. 404. ^ Naud4 Getreidehandehpolilik, 184. ' In 1552, Church and corporation lands which had been broken up for tillage were thrown back into pasture. Martin Hume, op. cit. p. 85. * Naud^, op. cit. 201. ^ They hoped for liberal concessions from Charles V. Lamprecht, Deutsche G^schichte, v. 479. " Beer, II. 144. Habler, Die ■mirthschaftliche Bliite Spaniens. The subject has given rise to much controversy, but it appears that there has been a tendency to exaggerate the duration of the prosperity of Spain. CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 195 foreign capital, but the new development of industry was not heartily welcomed; the increased population it had attracted seemed to be to blame for the scarcity and dearness of food ; while the gilds of small masters were opposed to the capitalist organisation of industry that had sprung up so rapidly'. The traditional policy of the country was that of legislating on behalf of consumers, and the newly-developed industries had to contend with unfavourable conditions. The Spanish markets were flooded with goods produced in countries where the range of prices was lower ^; while a prohibition of export', along with sumptuary laws^ seriously limited the demand for native manufactures. There are indications that the short-lived industrial prosperity of Spain was waning as early as the time of Charles V. The Spanish policy of maintaining privileges and favouring the consumer was as disadvantageous to the capitalist manufacturers as it had been to agriculture. The wealthy foreigners were blamed by the hidalgos for all the difficulties that arose in connection with the rise of prices ; native pride and prejudice formed an alliance with native poverty ; the expulsion of the Moriscos was only one instance of a continual attack upon alien elements", till the disabilities to which they were exposed — either as capitalists or labourers — forced them to withdraw. The Spaniards had been unable, in spite of the stimulus of the colonial demand, to develop great manufactures, and they would not allow the Germans or Italians to do it in their stead. In these circumstances there is little difficulty in ac- counting for the complete failure of the bullionist policy of Spain : even if the ruling dynasty had enjoyed a perpetual peace, it would have been impossible under the existing ' Martin Hume, op. cit. p. 84. = lb. p. 87. " Beer, op. cit. 11. 145. * Martin Hume, Year after the Armada, p. 220. ' Martin Hume, Spain, 1479 — 1788, p. 213. 13—2 196 Western Civilisation. [BOOK v. economic conditions to retain the silver in the Peninsula and to prevent it from passing out in the course of commerce. The prohibition of the export of bullion had never been abso- lutely enforced, as some of the German and Italian capitalists had enjoyed permits' which allowed a limited export; and the balance of trade was so heavily against Spain, that the tempta- tion to smuggle silver out of the country must have been great. The mass of the treasure of the new world did not find its way to the Spanish mint, but came into the hands of men who desired to use it as capital, and who succeeded in trans- ferring it to Antwerp, Genoa and other centres where they could invest it at a profit. The Spaniards, by their harsh legislation in the interest of consumers at home, interfered to prevent the colonial demand from stimulating the development of agri- cultural and industrial resources in the Peninsula. There were ever-increasing difficulties about maintaining their shipping and equipping their armies; as their commerce declined, it became obvious that they had missed the opportunity of attaining to great material prosperity. The bullionist policy had proved impracticable, it entirely failed to buttress the military power of Spain, and the colonial empire which Spain had created became the prey of peoples with a keener com- mercial spirit. 121. In the earlier part of the seventeenth century there seemed to be every prospect that Holland would andswp"prng. ^0°" attain an undisputed position as the predo- minant power, not only in European waters, but in the East and West Indies as well. She had great wealth ; her ports formed the chief European emporium both for fish and corn ; and the trade in these necessaries of life gave employ- ment to an enormous mercantile marine, which far exceeded the fleets of the Mediterranean cities in their most prosperous days. The United Provinces had means at their disposal not ^ Bonn, Spaniens Niedergang, 182. Ehrenberg, op. cit. w. 223. CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 197 only to secure their own independence, but also to break the power of Spain in the East Indies and in America. The foundations of their commercial prosperity were deeply laid, since the Netherlanders had been carefully endeavouring for centuries to make the most of their resources and of their opportunities for trade. From the earliest times of its known history Flanders had been famed for its industry and particularly its woollen manufacture, which centred round Bruges and Ghent. In the fourteenth century the towns of Brabant, especially Louvain, also excelled in this art; and though Dordrecht and Amsterdam were chiefly given to maritime employments and engaged in the import of wool from England, they gradually took to manufacturing and attained considerable success in the making of cloth. It was in the fifteenth century, however, that the Netherlands made most rapid progress; and owing to its varied maritime and industrial advantages, this territory enjoyed under the Bur- gundian family a period of extraordinary material prosperity. Most of the wealth of the northern provinces was due to the herring fishery. The art of curing fish had been much im- proved at Biervliet' in the earlier half of the fifteenth century; and the Dutch threw a great deal of energy into the prosecution of the fishing trade, so that their fleets reaped the richest harvest of the sea, not only near their own coasts, but off the shores of England and Denmark and in the Baltic. Thus they obtained a large supply of an article of common consumption throughout Christendom, and were able to do a profitable trade with Germany by the Rhine, and with France, Spain and Portugal by sea. Though the greater part of their country was little adapted for corn growing, it had admirable facilities for pasture, and not only enabled them to provide wool, but large quantities of dairy products for export. Their commerce was thus firmly based on the excellence of their manufactures, 1 J. de Witt, Political Maxims 0/ Ihe Slate of Holland (I'm), p. ^^. 198 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. and the abundance of the products of land and sea. The men of Amsterdam were able to take advantage of the position of their city to make it the centre of the maritime trade between the Baltic lands and the rest of Europe. The Nether- landers were forced to import corn from Prussia, Poland and Russia for their own requirements, and they succeeded in organising a great carrying trade for supplying the deficiencies of countries on the Mediterranean. This transport of corn between the districts which were then the granary of Europe and the southern lands which raised other products, came to be of far greater importance than all the rest of the Dutch trade put together ; the Hollanders competed successfully with the Hanse towns in the sixteenth century, and after the fall of Antwerp they had only occasional cause to fear the interrup- tion of this traffic". It continued throughout the seventeenth and the greater part of the eighteenth century to be the back- bone of the Dutch commercial system : so long as this trade with neighbouring lands was left to them, they could afford to regard the distant commerce of the world and the maintenance of colonies and factories in America and the East Indies with comparative indifference". The Dutch monopoly of the Spice Islands, which moved the jealousy of other nations in the seventeenth century, was not the foundation of the prosperity of the United Provinces, but was a mere excrescence, which was added incidentally and ' Considerable alarm was felt in 161 1, when Christian IV of Denmark increased the toll on vessels passing through the Sound. The Dutch trade was also threatened in 1622, when the Spaniards endeavoured to revive their connection with the Hanse towns on the Baltic; but the Dutch suffered no lasting injury. The most serious difficulties were caused by Gustavus Adolphus, when he established Swedish power on the Baltic in 1630, and diverted the corn from Poland for the commissariat of his armies. Naud6, op. cit. 348, 354, 360. " It is interesting to compare Adam Smith's chapter on the different employments of capital with the Dutch practice. WealtJi, of Nations, II. v. CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 195 under the pressure of their great struggle with Spain. The severities of the Spanish rule in the sixteenth century and the cruelties inflicted during the War of Independence had seriously interfered with the commerce, and with much of the industry of Flanders and Brabant. Refugees from these districts mi- grated northwards, and Amsterdam gained immensely by the fall of Antwerp. That city had been the chief emporium for the distribution of the spices and other valuable products which were imported into Spain and Portugal; and despite all efforts to force this trade into other channels, it continued to enrich the merchants of the United Provinces. They were able to avail themselves of opportunities which the Spaniards had failed to appreciate ; and the linen manufacture of Holland received a considerable impetus from the market that was opened up in the Spanish colonies. Just as Napoleon's armies were supplied with English manufactures, so was Spain forced to purchase goods from' the nation of traders' which she was endeavouring to coerce. Still, this illicit trade though highly profitable was extremely uncertain; and Philip, by seizing fifty Dutch ships in Lisbon harbour", forced the merchants of Amsterdam to adopt a bolder line, if they were not to lose this branch of business altogether. They determined to at- tempt to penetrate to the sources of the spice trade for them- selves, and to organise expeditions to the- East, instead of confining their energies to European trade. For some little time they prosecuted the attempt to open up an independent line of communication by the Arctic Seas^ though the first voyage (1594 a.d) had showed that the diffi- culties were very great; but in 1595 a.d. they adopted the southern route and sent out a fleet by the Cape, so that they ' Rogers, Holland, 162. * Saalfeld, Geschichte des holldnd. Kolonialwezens, I. 10. " Rogers, op. cit. 173. This had been already attempted by the English; it gave access to the silk trade with Persia, but not directly to a spice trade. 56o Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. entered into direct competition in waters where the Portuguese had established their supremacy. The four Dutch vessels which formed their first East Indian fleet (1595 a.d.) sailed by way of Madagascar to Java ; and though one ship had to be abandoned and many lives were lost, the adventure was so far successful that a larger fleet started in 1598 a.d.', and a permanent factory was established at Bantam in 1602 a.d. Several partnerships were formed and fleets were sent to the East, with the result that the market for spices was glutted, and some of these associations were ruined by the fall of prices"; but in 1602 A.D. the various partnerships were united into one company which was privileged to carry on the trade as a monopoly. In the first half of the seventeenth century it had a very large measure of success ; the factories which the Portuguese had established were incapable of defending them- selves against the Dutch ^ and the latter were able to put serious hindrances in the way of the development of the East Indian trade of England, which promised to become a formid- able rival. The Dutch came to be heirs of the monopoly in the Spice Islands, and of the .Portuguese trading connections with China and Japan; while the linen manufacture of Holland^ enabled her traders to export cargoes for which there was a ready sale in the East'. The Dutch were less willing than either the Portuguese or English to assume the cares of an Eastern Empire; but not even they were able to avoid it altogether. Political responsibility had been forced on the Portuguese by the need of a firm basis from which to resist the Arabs ; and though ' Bonnassieux, Grandes Conipagnies de Commerce, 44. " Beer, 11. 180. " Amboyna fell in 1605. Saalfeld, op. cit. i. 38. ■" Negapatam was the staple for this after 1606. Beer, II. 181. ' Neither the Portuguese nor the English manufactured commodities which commanded a good sale when offered in exchange for the goods they procured from the Indies. CHAP. m.J Rival Commercial Empires. 201 the Dutch were content on the whole to avoid continental possessions, and to try to secure commercial privileges by treaty with native rulers, they were impelled to exercise a strict territorial supervision over the, particular islands where the spices were produced. They paid pensions of about ;£'33oo' to native rulers to exterminate the clove and nutmeg in other islands, and concentrated the cultivation in Amboyna, where they were able to control it themselves. So far as their East Indian trade was concerned, they were not eager to de- velop it, but preferred to keep it within such limits that they might secure a high rate of profit ^ While we are inclined to blame this restrictive policy, we ought not to shut our eyes to the fact that it proved, in some ways at least, a wise one. Holland was never exhausted as Portugal had been by the attractions of eastern traffic and command. On the contrary, the great gains accruing from this exclusive trade were capitalised and advantageously employed other mercantile and industrial undertakings, both in their own and in neighbouring lands. The Baltic trade in corn and furs showed a steady improvement; the Hanse towns were completely superseded, and the Dutch enjoyed a very large share of the active commerce of Sweden and Russia. They also entered the Mediterranean and took up much of the business formerly done by Italians. The Venetian shipping continued to decline, and the Dutch commenced to carry on a considerable trade with Smyrna and the Levant. In all these directions they out-distanced the English merchants, and, as it appeared, chiefly because there was an abundance of money in Holland which could always be obtained for new enterprises that offered the prospect of a moderate return on the capital invested. While her trading relations were thus extending on all ^ Raynal, Voyages, i. iS6. > ' Saalfeld, op. cit. I. 274. On the policy pursued in limiting llie production of coffee, sugar, etc., see lb. I. 236. Also on the restrictive policy at the Cape, Leroy Bcaulieu, Colonisation, 89. 203 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. sides, the original sources of the wealth of Holland were not neglected. Fishery was actively carried on, and attention was given to sealing and whaling, which were pursued at first with the aid of Biscayan harpooners'. The industries which migrated from Flanders, from Germany, and later from France, were prosecuted with success in Holland, where they were organised on capitalised lines*, so that the country became more noted for the excellence and variety of its manufactures. Besides this, unremitting attention was given to farming ; root crops and artificial grasses were introduced so as to afford winter fodder, and though Dutch horticulture was in some ways an extravagant hobby, it none the less gave a stimulus to a remunerative business. The reaction of Dutch commerce on the industry of Holland led to a remarkable development of native resources of every kind. There had been a strange fatality about the conduct of Spanish affairs, especially in the way in which the action of the government played into the hands of the provinces that were defying them. The low import duties on goods entering Spain had been highly advantageous to the Dutch; they had also gained by the immigration of protestants expelled from Spanish dominions ; and there was another way in which the policy of Spain worked for the ultimate benefit of Holland. In No- vember 1596 A.D.°, Philip repudiated his debts and resumed possession of the lands which he had mortgaged; he thus destroyed his own credit, while he also ruined the Italian and German financiers from whom he had borrowed, and left the Dutch without rivals in this lucrative business. The monetary world of Florence had received a blow from which ^ Beer, II. 203. ^ Pringsheim, Beilrage zur wirtschaftlichen Etitwickelung der vereinig- ten Niederlande im 17. unci 1%. Jahrhundert in Schmaller's Forschungen, X. iii. (1890),. p. 33. Xhe old-established industries of Holland continued to be carried on as domestic crafts, and the gild regulations were strictly enforced. lb. 40. " Rogers, op. cit. 187. CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 203 it did not easily recover when Edward III and Robert of Sicily failed to keep faith with the Peruzzi; and Philip's bankruptcy destroyed the financial supremacy of the Fuggers of Antwerp and Augsburg. Amsterdam became the new monetary centre of Europe ; the business of foreign banking was increasingly concentrated there. This succession of great opportunities, which occurred during the first half of the seventeenth century, enabled the Dutch to attain the highest pitch of prosperity in every depart- ment of economic life. They reached the zenith of their prosperity about 1649 a.d. ; from that time onwards, though the Baltic trade which was the main source of their wealth continued to flourish, they began to lose the lead in the race ; and rivals, who imitated their methods, became successful competitors. The French under Colbert developed industries of their own, so that a valuable neighbouring market was closed to Dutch manufactures; the Scandinavians, like the English, were jealous of the intrusion of Dutch fishermen in their waters, and the practical monopoly of the Dutch was at length completely broken down by the opening of the Sound. The English Navigation Act of 1651 a.d. had been partly dictated by political considerations and by a desire to sever the West Indian colonies from intercourse with royalist sympathisers, but it also struck a severe blow at the carrying trade of the Dutch and weakened their hold upon North America. They even failed -to maintain their interest in the Peninsula ; for in the middle of the seventeenth century, when the Portuguese power was revived under the house of Braganza (1640 a.d.), considerable advantage accrued to England and but little to Holland. The struggle of the Dutch West India Company for the possession of Brazil' was useless so far as Holland was concerned, while the alliance of Charles II with the royal house of Portugal restored an ancient friendship and gave sub- stantial advantages to the growing maritime power of England. 1 Boniiassieux, op. cit. 74. 204 Western Civilisation, [BOOK V. The revival of Portugal and of the Portuguese colonies was profitable to English capitalists ', and was controlled to a cer- tain extent in the interests of English industry ; the Methuen treaty marked the success of English merchants in their con- test with the Dutch for the carrying trade of Portugal and her dependencies. The inability of the^ Dutch to secure and to maintain a predominant position and to exercise a world-wide influence, was not due to any economic weakness, but rather to their political temperament and character. The Dutch had not attained to a true national life ; it is hardly an exaggeration to say that "the Netherlander before 1795 a.d. recognised no fatherland, but only a father-town"." The strength of their civic as compared with their national patriotism prevented them from making the most of their opportunities in the seventeenth century; they did not fail from lack of means, so much as from want of will ; they had no ambition to develop a colonial empire. In no other country did the strictly economic motives count for so much in the determi- nation of policy. Even their struggle for independence had been greatly influenced by a desire to escape the centralised government and the taxation which the House of Austria had imposed on their commerce". John de Wit, the leader of the merchant princes, explicitly advocated " Peace at any price V as the aim at which their diplomacy should be directed, since any war was likely to injure their shipping' and its in- terests. They had no positive ideal towards which their pursuit of material wealth was subordinated ; with the Dutch, as with ' Beer, 11. 119, 133. At the earthquake at Lisbon the loss of ca:pital to English merchants is said to have been very large. Ibid. 121 note. ^ J. Blok, Eene hoUandsche stad in de middeleeuwen. 1883. Preface. ' Pringsheim, op. cit. p. i. On the struggle over the Congiegeld which was revived by Charles V in 1540, to the serious disadvantage of the corn trade, see Naud^, op. cit. 319. * Naud6, op. cit. 436. CHAl'. 111. J Rival Commercial Empires. 205 the Phoenicians in the old world; commerce was not so much a means to an end as an end in itself. Had Holland been ambitious of retaining her position as a world power she had ample resources at her command, and she might have made an effective bid for the leadership among the representatives of Western Civilisation. But she did not rise to the responsibility; while other nations advanced and expanded, she concentrated her energies more and more on the trade that lay easily within her reach. The wealth and prosperity of Holland continued till the latter half of the eighteenth century, when improvements in the cultivation of England', together with the opening up of Odessa'' as a new port and of fresh sources of supply in America, revolutionised the corn trade. But long before statistics showed any signs of the decline of her wealth or her maritime importance, she had lost all pretensions to rule the destinies of any large area of territory. Indeed her system of government rendered it impossible for her to undertake such a task with success; the seven United Provinces had been drawn together by the requirements of common defence, but they did not succeed in organising a workable administrative system. Though the Dutch were willing to make vast sacrifices at some moment of dife necessity, they were unable to make steady and regular preparation for possible exigencies', and had not the means of repairing their losses and retrieving their disasters. The par- ticularist interest of different towns and districts was strong enough to paralyse the action of the Admiralty and to render the central government inefficient and corrupt*; and the cumbrous 1 Naude, 0^. cit. 379. a lb. 440. ' A. T. Mahan, The Influence of Sea Power upon History, 68. * Pringsheim, op. cit. 2, 3. An enquiry in 1685 proved that the officials of the Admiralty allowed whole cargoes to be smuggled without interfering, as they dared not offend the various town authorities who were interested in these ventures. The most important posts were sold for money to inca- pable people; in times of crisis the officials were often not to be found, 2o6 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. system of management which was adopted for the East Indian and other companies ' was incompatible with the main- tenance of an effective rule over distant dependencies. The Portuguese continued to retain something of the missionary aspirations of the Crusaders in the organisation of their colonial empire, and the Spaniards had an insatiable desire for power ; the Dutch deliberately confined their energies within a very restricted sphere ; and because they would not progress, they were unable to retain what they possessed. It is impossible to win a victory over energetic rivals by always remaining on the defensive, and the Dutch were forced to relinquish piece- meal the advantages they had once secured ^ 122. The politicians in the latter part of the seventeenth The French century, who indulged in forecasts of the future and Internal of the civiliscd world. Were very apprehensive eve opment. ^j- ^.j^^ dangers to which other nations were ex- posed from the growth of France. The military resources of Louis XIV inspired his contemporaries with awe, and the palace which he erected at Versailles impresses succeeding generations with some idea of his magnificence. Powerful at home, the French monarchy seemed able to establish its the book-keeping was careless and the accounts were in disorder. There was no question of anything like a unified customs regulation. The central government had as a mle no officials of its own to carry out its decrees, the execution of which was left to the provincial or town officials, who thought it their duty to put the interest of their province or town before that of the general interest of the country. On the management of the companies' affairs abroad compare Stavorinus, Visages to the East Indies, i. 278, also in. 475. ^ Wilcocke's notes to his Translation of Stavorinus, op, cit. I. 89. Leroy Beaulieu, De la Colonisation chez les peuples modemes, jg. " The parallel between England and Holland is of much interest, espe- cially in connection with the history of experiments in Free Trade. It is to be noted, however, that the English imperial sentiment and eagerness to expand are wanting among the Dutch. Further, English trade is not based on advantages secured by treaty, and has not the exclusive character which made that of the Dutch an object of jealousy. CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 207 influence at any moment in the most distant parts of the globe ; for it had secured a footing in India and had commenced to found a series of settlements in the Antilles and along the great rivers of North America — the Mississippi and St Lawrence. Till the middle of the eighteenth century it appeared likely that France would ultimately inherit the territories .which had been opened up to Europeans in the age of discovery. But these expectations were mistaken ; France has never obtained a great colonial empire, and as we look back we may be able to see some of the reasons why, with all her great resources and eager national ambition, she failed to make the most of her opportunities in the seventeenth century. It is easy, but somewhat unmeaning, to say that the French have no genius for colonisation; as we review the work of such pioneers as Cartier or Champlain, or read of the enterprise of Breton fishermen and Normandy merchants', we feel that there were abundant elements for founding and maintaining vigorous settlements in distant lands. The re- ligious orders in the West, and military leaders like Dupleix in the East, showed a capacity for dealing with native populations such as few Englishmen have ever displayed j and the pros- perity of the French colonies in the Tropics— in the Antilles and at Mauritius — proves that there was no inherent incapacity on the part of the nation for carrying out such undertakings with success. The defect did not lie in the genius of the people, so much as in the habits of political and economic life that had been formed in the course of many years. The revival of French industry and commerce under Charles VII and Louis XI had been brought about by royal and governmental action ; under these monarchs the French learned to rely on kingly direction and encouragement instead of personal effort ; and Francis I seems to have been responsible in no small degree for giving a mistaken turn to the national ambition. ' Gaffarel, Les Colonics fran^aises, p. 80. 2o8 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. His eyes were fixed on Italy ; he was eager to obtain Italian possessions, and his ideas were all coloured by reminiscences of Italian glories. The new world was being opened up; the sailors of Rouen and Dieppe' were competing with the Portuguese on the African coast and wAh. the Spaniards in America; 'but Francis I would have none of it. He stimu- lated and revivified the moribund Levantine commerce of the southern ports', and during his reign the town of Lyons became the centre of an enormous trade in articles of luxury'. Immense palaces, surpassing those of Florence and Venice, were built in Paris and throughout the country, both by the king and by "the nobles who imitated him ; France began to take the lead, which she has never lost, in matters of fashion and taste. Though the interests of the importers and those of the native artisan were somewhat in conflict, there was a frequent effort from the time of Francis I onwards to plant the manufactures of cloth-of-gold, glass, silk, and tapestry, so that the king and court might be supplied by home producers, and not by importation from abroad. France was by nature self-sufficing and independent of foreign countries for the ne- cessaries of life; it was the policy of the king to make her independent with regard to artistic productions also*; and on the whole, subsequent rulers have continued to encourage those branches of industiy which were first developed under the impulse they received from Francis I. In the sanguinary struggle of the wars of the League, France was once more devastated as she had been in the Hundred Years' War; and the statesmen of the time were therefore compelled to concentrate all their energies on repairing the ravages of that sanguinary struggle; they could not attempt to take up the work of colonisation seriously or to compete for a commercial empire while there was such terrible social disintegration at home. Henry IV was a king who threw ' Pigeonneau, ii. 45. ^ lb. 11. 126. « Jb- II. 28. * U. u. 58. CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 209 himself heartily into the task of reviving internal prosperity, and once again the economic life of France was restored by royal initiative. In Sully the Crown had a financial adviser of conspicuous ability, who introduced reforms into the fiscal system of the country and greatly reduced the burden to the taxpayers ; at the same time he provided such a revenue that Henry could introduce some new industrial experiments, and undertake important public works. In all these matters the Crown could rely on the assistance of Olivier de Serres and Laffemas, who were authorities in regard to scientific agricul- ture and commercial and industrial development respectively. Henry IV, during the few years when he was undisputed master, did not give complete adherence to the views of either of the competing doctrinaires, but he laid down the lines of that systematic development of internal resources by which the French monarchy was to attain to its greatest glory. His most important work was that of developing internal commerce' by improving the rivers and constructing canals; he spent immense sums on the repair of roads and the building of bridges so as to facilitate the transport of grain; he also did much to reduce the provincial restrictions which had hitherto fettered the trade in corn. This in itself gave a decided impulse to agriculture; every effort was made to encourage the nobility to settle as residents on their estates, and the Thecttre d' Agriculture of Olivier de Serres gave them the fullest instruction as to the best methods to pursue in the management of their land. There were, however, many obstacles in the way of change for the better ; it was hopeless to expect that the peasantry would adopt improved methods of their own accord; and hence it seemed wise to maintain a certain amount of natural economy — in the metayer system' — so that the influence of the proprietor as an interested partner might ^ Fagniez, Viconomie sociale de la France sous Henri IV, i8a. ' J. S. Mill, Political Economy, bk. II. c. viii. C. W. C. II. 14 210 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. be directly brought to bear on the mode of cultivation". The homestead system, which has proved a practical barrier to capitalist farming, was retained in France; but the seignorial powers failed to exercise an educative influence on the peasants or to set an example by introducing new methods of cultivation and other agricultural improvements. The conditions of industrial life in the sixteenth century gave rise to a great deal of complaint, and powerful forces were at work which demanded the regulation of the crafts in Lyons' and other towns on the model of the corps de metiers at Paris. Henry IV, in accordance with the principles of Laffemas, organised the industrial system of the whole country on very definite lines. The exceptions which were allowed were due to the direct exercise of royal authority and the creation in the various crafts of masters who had not served an apprenticeship; the Crown also exerted its powers by granting special patents for inventors, by the appointment of artisans to the Court, and by the establishment of large numbers of workmen in the Louvre where they were free from interference by the corps de mHiers". These inter- ferences with the rigidity of the system were unpopular and were of doubtful advantage ; but the general tendency was to strengthen the hands of the wealthy oligarchies in each trade*, and thus, while mediaeval forms were preserved, to facilitate the introduction of capitalistic organisation in industry. However unsatisfactory the system may seem in the retrospect, it proved, with the assistance of protective laws, to be the means of greatly ^ The alternative would have been to allov/ the peasantry to rent land for money, but the introduction of this system would have tended to widen the severance between the two classes who were concerned with the land, and the numbers both of non-resident proprietors and of unen- lightened cultivators would have been increased. '■* Hauser, OuvHers du temps passi, 139. ' Hauser, ep. cit. 135 — 140. ♦ The wealthy oligarchies had been chiefly instrumental in securing in- creased regulation. Hauser, op. cit. 127. CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 1 1 1 developing the native trades; while considerable pains were also taken by Henry IV to plant the silk manufacture' in new regions and to introduce a fustian manufacture as well". The extent to which the material prosperity of France was actually dependent on royal authority became apparent when Henry IV was removed by the dagger of Ravaillac. Under the government of Marie de Medicis much of the old disorder returned ; but when Richelieu assumed the reins of power he reinforced with fresh vigour the industrial policy of Henry IV.° He also had such faith in the resources of the country that he consciously aimed at developing a naval and mercantile marine*, so that France might hope to compete with Holland and England for commercial supremacy and colonial empire. In neither case did he obtain the success he anticipated ; great commercial companies were organised, in imitation of those of Holland'; but the financiers who subscribed the capital could not furnish the practical business ability" which was necessary to render these undertakings a commercial success in the Baltic or other fields where Dutch traders were already estab- lished'; the French Crown conferred privileges and powers, but the fostering care which had regulated actual industry could not call a non-existent commerce into being". The compara- tive failure of French efforts at colonisation was partly owing to maladministration and partly to other causes. The pioneers ^ Fagniez, op. cil. 105 fol. ' lb. 142. ' Levasseur, oJ>. cil. II. 151. * D'Avenel, Richelieu el la Moiiarchie absolue, III. 167. 5 Bonnassieiix, Les grandes coinJ>agnies de commerce, 166. ^ The practical merchants were too deeply attached to the trade of par- ticular cities, Rouen, St Male or Rochelle, to throw their energies into schemes that concerned the nation as a whole. Pigeonneau, 11. 34.6. ' Sargent, The Economic Policy of Colbert, 82. 8 "Un gouvernement pent utiliser et diriger un courant national; il ue peut ni le creer, ni I'arrcter." D'Avenel, op. cit. III. iiy. Compare also p. Masson, Uisioire du comiiicne fran^ais dans le Levant au xvii'"' slide, 2i2 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. had, unlike the Dutch, a very keen sense of a national mission and destiny, they had ample privileges granted them by the Crown, and the men of Normandy^ were enterprising sailors, but the people generally hung back from the effort to trans- plant French civilisation into distant lands. Much of the success of the English colonies was due to those who were, from one cause or another, dissatisfied with the conditions of life at home. Puritans and Roman Catholics and Quakers were alike concerned in the founding of settlements which proved to be places of refuge for Englishmen to whom their native land was uncongenial. But the Frenchman, who was dissatisfied with the social system at home, would have found no place for him in New France^; and others, who would have been welcomed there,' saw little to attract them to emigrate. Pioneers had begun to establish themselves at Montreal before Richelieu came into power ; but though he took up the matter in earnest and entered into one scheme after another, he failed to attract a regular stream of emigrants. The companies of New France' and of the Antilles* were called into exist- ence, and thus late in the day the first serious efforts were made to found a French colonial empire; when the attempt was once begun it was carried out on an extensive scale, for encouragement was given to the trading intercourse which the Norman sailors had established with Senegal ^ and possession was formally taken of Madagascar^ Some of these schemes were hampered for want of capital, and others suffered from the insufficiency of the French marine and the inade- quate communication between the colonies and the mother ' Pigeonneau, op. cit. II. 44'2. 2 Coligny attempted to found Huguenot colonies both in Brazil and I'lorida, but neither attempt attained much success. Pigeonneau, op. cit, II- 329- ? Bonnassieux, op, cit. 350. * Gaffarel, Les Colonies frati^aises, 206. ° lb. 10. Bonnassieux, op. cit. 223. " Gaffarel, op. cit. 14a. CHAP, iii.j Rival Commercial Empires. 213 country". The establishment charges were also very heavy, and the Court favourites" who were willing to expatriate them- selves for a time, were not always the men who were fitted to preside over the destinies of a struggling colony. -Richelieu, with his unbounded belief in the resources of France'', had given his approval to ambitious schemes which he had no sufficient means of carrying into effect. Fortunately for his country he was succeeded by a man of more restricted ambitions who was a great master of detail. When Colbert was entrusted with the charge of the finances of the realm he proved to be an admirable administrator ; and his reforms in the levying of taxation were most successful. But he had an undue belief in the power of administrative machinery to exercise a beneficial effect on industry and commerce ; in some cases there was an absurd waste from his efforts to introduce model manufactures; in others there was much disturbance from his drastic attempts to improve those that already existed. Over-regulation and over-organisation affected every branch of industrial life*, and seriously hampered the development of commercial enterprise; while his measures for agriculture gave it no chance to revive' after the disad-' ' D'Avenel, op. cit. ill. 225. ^ Seances et travaiix de VAcad. des Sciences Morales, CXXII. (1884), p. 482. ' Pigeonneau, op. cit. II. 379. * " Unfortunately for the progress of industry in France, state aid and patronage, especially under despotic rule, inevitably implies state inter- ference. Judging from the character of Colbert, we should expect such, interference to be pushed to its furthest limit under his regime; that such was the case his letters amply prove. Here is his view on the subject: ' On this matter I would have you know that the only means of rendering our manufactures perfect and of establishing a good system in our commerce is to render them all uniform. The way to accomplish this is to- insist on the practical execution of the general regulations of 1669; the more so that obedience is easy, and that in the end the workmen will find in it their real profit.' " Sargent, Economic Policy of Colbert, 50. ° The general policy of Colbert involved the subordination of agricul- tural to industrial interests, since he aimed at procuring a large supply of 2r4 ]V(stcrn Civilisation. [noOK V. vantages to which it had been exposed from the fiscal burdens imposed by Richelieu. Colbert's efforts to foster industry in the way it should go proved a failure; an economic despot had need to be omniscient, and Colbert was not wise enough to play the part of Providence with success. Hardly any economic system would have had a fair trial in the circumstances of the day; political ambition left no scope for steady and systematic attention to economic develop- ment. The policy of Louis XIV would have drained the mag- nificent resources of France at any time; to the artificial scheme which Colbert had built up it was positively ruinous. The strain of foreign war was exhausting on one side; while the internal policy that was pursued in regard to the Huguenots struck a serious blow at some of the principal seats of French manufactures, and destroyed the industries to which so much attention had been given. Europe continued to tremble before the projects of Louis XIV ; but the break-down of Colbert's system had left the great monarch powerless to carry them into effect. In every aspect the governmental initiative and administrative organisation proved baleful for France; with a fixed ambition to rule the destinies of Europe, her monarchs neglected the opportunity of securing a firm footing in the New World, and gave but little support to the enterprising men who were cherishing wider ideals for their native land. Her very wealth tempted her statesmen to be content with a self-centred economic policy; by protectionist measures against outsiders they sought to encourage a large home supply of manufactures of every sort ; but they saw no occasion to attend to the permanent well-being of the agriculturists, though this was essential for the maintenance of a food supply, and also for nurturing a population adapted for colonisation. food at low rates for the manufacturing population. There was a constant change of regulations in regard to the corn trade, according to the varying circumstances of different provinces in different seasons. Naude, Cetreide- handehpolitik, 39 — jS. CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires, 2\% Colbert's system hardly had a fair chance, but its utter collapse is none the less a renewed demonstration of the economic difficulties which attend even the far-seeing absolute ruler. 123. Two hundred years after the establishment of direct communications with the East Indies and the _^ „ ,. u / The English discovery of the New World, there was still much Mercantile uncertainty as to the precise form in which ^y^*^™- Western Civilisation would be brought to bear upon them. During the eighteenth century this question was settled for our age at any rate ; England ousted France from her strong position both in the East and in the West, and came to be the principal heir of competitors who had each shown in turn their inability to retain their hold over these distant lands. In the East the Portuguese had succumbed to the Dutch ; the Dutch had proved incapable of rising to the situation ; and the French missed the opportunity of supplanting them. It was the good fortune of England that she was able to take advantage of the openings that were oflfered her as they occurred, but it is not easy to detect the precise reasons of her success. There were, however, two features which distinguished England from her rivals in the earlier part of the seventeenth century ; while there was considerable scope for personal energy, there was also a solidarity of sentiment throughout the English nation, and popular enthusiasm demanded the building up of maritime power ; " her subjects were occupied during the greater portion of Elizabeth's reign in teaching their queen the use of a navy' "; and the maladministration of this service under James I and Charles I, despite their real interest in it, not only involved the Stuarts in difficulties with their parliaments, but was indirectly decisive as to the issue of the Civil War^ The Commonwealth, by its larger and judicious expenditure" on the navy, was really giving effect to a widespread popular ambition, ' Oppenheim, A History of the Administration of the Royal Navy 1509— 1660, p. 115. 2 Jb. 240—243. ' Jb. 303. 2i6 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. to which there was nothing that corresponded either in Holland or France. And just as it may be said that the Crown and the Commonwealth rather followed than directed the national bent in this political ambition, so does it appear that there was no need for authority to attempt to call forth commercial or colonial enterprise among Englishmen. Trading interest and the love of personal adventure were widely prevalent in Eng- land ; the^ Government was required at times to control and to protect, but not to initiate new undertakings. This vigorous spirit was hampered by the lack of material means to carry out its projects ; England in the seventeenth century had neither such a large mercantile marine', nor such abundance of capital as Holland. But even as regards pecuniary resources, English subjects were better provided than the English Crown. The great engineering works in France had been started at the royal expense ; but such public works as the draining of the Cambridgeshire Fens or of Hatfield Chase were committed in England to local magnates and private adventurers". The secret of her ultimate success seems to have lain in the vigor- ous enterprise of individual Englishmen and the strength of patriotic feeling. At all events, it is clear that England did not suffer from ^ Oppenheim, op. cit, 307. ^ There had been, through the later Middle Ages, considerable scope for individual enterprise as the craft gilds, which would have been opposed to it, were carefully kept in hand. The town authorities had been jealous in restraining the powers of these gilds, and Parliament in the fifteenth century pursued a similar course. In the time of Elizabeth they practically dis- appeared, as industrial legislation had been nationalised ; and unnecessarily rigid as the new system seems to us, it was yet comparatively flexible. The Commons were inclined to resent any attempt on the part of the Stuart kings to exercise an effective control over particular branches of industry by the appointment of patentees. Freedom for individual enterprise, both personal and associated, was consonant with the habits and institutions of the people; they would not be coerced into adopting one particular model, and there was, under the circumstances, little encouragement to attempt the introduction of cumbrous administration into the English colonies. CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 217 the special political weakness which affected the Dutch; the particularism of the various cities and provinces rendered effective administration impossible', and prevented the growth of such patriotic sentiments as actuated all classes of English- men. The first settlers in Virginia were eager to extend the range of English influence and to Anglicise a portion of the New World^, and English seamen were proud to try to hold their own against hereditary enemies like the Spaniards and the French. Dutch enterprise was purely commercial in its incep- tion ; the merchants of Holland had no ambition to rule other lands, they were merely concerned with their business in- terests. But though commercial gain was a main motive in English colonial activity, it was not kept in view so exclusively as to limit the hopes and ideals of the leaders in the movement. There was also a great difference between the manner of determining on the economic policy of the country in France and in England respectively. The highly centralised system of regulation which prevailed in France enabled the kings and their advisers to exercise an extraordinary influence ; and the tastes and ambitions of the French monarchs gave a special and not very fortunate direction to industrial development,, but the English Government was much more ready to follow the guidance and advice of English merchants. The require- ments of the Court diverted French energies into the manu- facture of costly luxuries; though the English Court might admire French taste and indulge in French goods during the Restoration period, it did little to direct industrial energy into, these channels in preference to other trades. In England the national ambition, which one monarch after another adopted, as his own, coincided with the interests of the mercantile' 1 English naval administration was often corrupt, but the Dutch system was so complicated that it was necessarily inefficient. Oppenheim, op. cit. I. 305. ^ John Smith, Adverlisements, c. 14, in Works, p. 957. Hakluyt's Voyages, in. 303. 2i8 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V, community, while the kings became more reluctant to offend the moneyed men to whom they were forced to look for oc- casional supplies ; thus a close alliance between the monarchy and the traders was gradually compacted. Under these circumstances a scheme of economic policy was devised, which in its main outlines dominated English legislation and ad- ministration for more than two centuries. It was clear that alike for purposes of defence and offence the success of England in rivalry with other nations must be achieved with the help of naval skill; while the available revenue of the Crown was largely dependent on taxation, and the Government was compelled for its own sake to attend not only to the development of shipping, but to the improvement of agriculture as well. The policy, which had been thought out for England, was applied on a larger scale as new areas were added to her dominion and could be dealt with as part of her territory. The lines of this economic policy, which was maintained through the seventeenth century and most of the eighteenth, are clearly discernible in the Elizabethan period, before England had any pretensions to be a colonial power at all. Every effort was made by Burleigh to develop the maritime power of England; the seafaring population and the subsidiary industries which are necessary for the provision of naval stores had his constant thought. A stringent navigation policy might have created a fleet for a time, but his object was to increase the resources from which maritime equipment might be steadily drawn in the future. Among all the governmental changes from the Tudors to the Hanoverians, there was no period when the necessity of maintaining the maritime efificiency of the country was left out of sight, but the exigencies of the revenue system prevented any sacrifice of agricultural to commercial interests. After the time of Henry VHI the Crown was very dependent on parliamentary grants for the ordinary expenses of government, and the taxation was chiefly levied upon the CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 219 landed proprietors ; it was a matter of immediate interest to the administration that the country gentlemen should be in receipt of large rents from which taxation might be paid ; and this could only be satisfactorily attained^ if agriculture was profitable. Fiscal considerations gave greater cogency to the arguments of those who were alarmed at any movement which was prejudicial to the rural population. Efforts were made to give encouragement to arable farming and to compel the gentry to settle on their own estates, and schemes were ap- proved for banking out the sea and the rivers which flooded low-lying land, so as to increase the food-producing area of the country. The English colonies in North America were habitually spoken of as 'plantations,' and this word seems to carry the implication that they were regarded as extensions of England"; they were not to be treated as separate entities but as parts of one whole, to which the familiar principles of economic policy should be made to apply. The territory which Cabot discovered and the stretch of coast which was claimed by England did not offer attractive facilities either for commercial stations or for mining ; but the land afforded admirable oppor- tunities for farming, and the seas for fishing ; so that the design of developing rural and maritime wealth could be carried on in this new field. The actual progress made under Elizabeth and James was exceedingly slow, and the several settlements that were established in the seventeenth century differed in their legal and political character. But economically they were founded on very similar principles. They were ' In the Elizabethan statute of apprentices the interests of agriculture and of employments subsidiary to agriculture had a distinct preference as compared with the industry of the towns. This distinguishes English policy very clearly from that of Colbert. The development of sheep-farming at the expense of tillage was always regarded as a political danger, and favour was shown to the interest of tillage by the Corn Bounties Act of 1689. Naude, op. cil. iii, 121. * Cunningham, Growth of English Industry and Commerce, 11. 144. 220 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. emphatically a new England, which was to be treated in such a fashion that the total maritime and territorial resources of the realm might be increased and that the Anglo-Saxon race might hold its own in the struggle with other world powers. The disabilities to which the colonists were exposed in the eighteenth century were very real grievances, and many people find it difficult to appreciate the true character of the underlying principles on which the growing empire was regu- lated in the seventeenth century. The English colonies were not exploited in the interests of the mother country; they were territories to which Englishmen came in order to establish their homes and to make the most of the region where they settled. The restrictions imposed on them were connected with one fundamental maxim, which is hardly on the face of it unreasonable, and the colonies were prevented from engaging in hostile competition with the mother country'. So long as they paid little or nothing to the expense of defending the realm of which they formed a part it seemed reasonable that they should be precluded from developing on lines which tended to diminish the resources of the mother country. Subject to this principle of restriction, their progress was encouraged, and it was felt that their prosperity was an added strength to the realm ^ The effort to form a plantation was arduous ; and more than one expedition suffered severely before the preliminary difficulties were overcome, and the settlers became independent of im- ported supplies of food. But the motive of English coloni- sation was not that of conquering a territory and obtaining access to its mineral wealth, as the Spaniards had done, but of expanding the area which was peopled by Englishmen. ' See opinions quoted by G. L. Beer, The Comniercial Policy of Eng- land towards the American Colonies in Columbia College Studies, III. 366, also Cunningham, op. cit. II. 153. ' E. Lord, Industrial Experiments in Colonial America in John Hop- kins University Studies (1898), p. 86. CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 221 Like other European nations in the East Indies, the English aimed at commerce rather than at colonisation ; there are, however, striking contrasts between the policy they pursued and that of their predecessors. The English East India Company was in a way a monopoly ; it had special territorial and judicial privileges, and it showed itself jealous of the interference of interlopers, but it did not pursue the Dutch policy and deliberately limit the trade. The directors in London were persistent in their efforts to induce their agents abroad to make a large investment in Indian commodities for sale in Europe, and many of their servants were keenly interested in promoting internal trade in India'. The Dutch hoped to gain by artificial restrictions, while the English Company on the contrary conceived that the best way to make a profit lay in the direction of an expanding rather than of a limited trade. In course of time, too, the English merchants departed farther from the Dutch system, since they were led to adopt the policy which Albuquerque had sketched for his compatriots. They gradually and hesitatingly accepted a larger and larger measure of territorial power as the best means of securing their commercial footing without extravagant expenditure in the defence of their trade'. It has been pointed out in a preceding paragraph that the extended commerce of the Dutch reacted favourably on the industries of the United Provinces ; and considerable pains were taken by the English to reap similar advantages : the traditional scheme for promoting the welfare of the country was carried out under a fresh stimulus and with increasing success. The necessity of keeping up maritime communi- cations with distant lands gave remunerative employment for English shipping, and the plantations afforded a new market ' Cunningham, op. cit. II. 274. " In early times the English appear to have been even more careful than their predecessors to preserve peace. Penny, Fort S. George, Madras, P- 34- 222 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. for English manufactures. There were symptoms, too, of a tendency to study the methods of Colbert and to imitate the policy he pursued; the efforts in which Parliament engaged to protect and to promote native industry and to introduce new employments, which might enable us to supply our own requirements instead of purchasing goods from abroad, do not differ in principle from the schemes which were adopted in France, though they often took a distinct form. The great industrial gain to England at the close of the seventeenth century came about by the action of and at the expense of France. The. expulsion of the Huguenots drove to our shores some of the workmen whom Colbert would gladly have retained ; and the arts which they practised were transferred with them from French to English soil. In setting aside local jealousies and welcoming these alien refugees. English- men showed that they were willing to copy the policy by which Holland had been so much enriched. The commercial scheme which England had adopted, so far as the East India Company was concerned, would hardly have been carried out persistently if Englishmen had not deliberately discarded the bullionist system which Spain pursued'; they adopted instead a new view as to the means by which a mass of the precious metals — the sinews of war — might be best obtained. England did not contain mines of gold or silver and her colonies had no precious metals; hence it was only by traffic that she could procure treasure, and her wool trade had enabled her to obtain an ample supply of silver in the early Middle Ages. Statesmen began to realise that commerce might be so regulated as to induce a constant influx of silver ; they endeavoured to promote the export of English commodities to countries that had few goods to offer in return, in the confident expectation that a payment for these exports would be made in bullion; the mercantilists agreed that when the " balance of trade " was favourable, treasure must flow into ' Cumiiu^haiu, op, cii, 11> 211. CHAP. III.] Rival Commercial Empires. 223 the country. A hearty reliance on this principle enabled Englishmen to lay aside the policy of rigidly restricting the export of the precious metals which had wrought so much mischief in Spain; they were not bullionist but mercantilist. We have to some extent outlived the aim they set before them, and no longer attach the importance they did to the possession of treasure ; but it is important to notice that the means they adopted for pursuing this object were perfectly compatible with the constant expansion of commerce, and that they were won- derfully successful in attaining what they had in view. Working steadily and slowly for the development of maritime resources and natural advantages and appropriate industry, England reached a high degree of material prosperity, and obtained the sinews of naval and military power The posses- sion of great wealth of many kinds enabled her to attract considerable quantities of treasure in the course of trade. In the seventeenth century England was a profitable field for the investment of foreign capital ; but with the increase of her trade the formation of capital went on more and more rapidly ; the moneyed men began to overbalance the landed interest, and England abounded not only in wealth but in treasure. The foundation of the Bank of England ^ase, a great impulse to the growth of a healthy credit system', so that, when the financial importance of Amsterdam began to decline, London was ready to take its place as the monetary centre of the world. At the time when England secured a great opportunity of guiding the destinies of India and America, ' This proved one of the greatest of the advantages which England had in the struggle with France. The system of Law appears to have involved a confusion between currency and capital (Levasseur, SysQme de Law, p. 26); but the multiplication and forced circulation of paper money altogether failed to realise his expectations and reinvigorate the economic life of France. The relations of Law's bank with the French Government were much closer than those which subsisted between the Bank and the Government in Enijland; the failure of his system directly increased the embarrassment of the French Crown. 224 Western Civilisation. [BOOK V. she also had command of the material means of bringing her influence to bear. The success of England becomes less astonishing when we see how closely it was connected with the political conditions and economic system which had determined the aims of the Government and the habits of the people. The English over- took and surpassed their competitors, not because they had any special genius for the work, still less because they were the mere favourites of fortune, but because they were true to themselves, and eager to learn from their neighbours. They were ready to be guided by the experience of others; to imitate their successes and to profit by the lessons of their failure. England secured an empire in the East, such as Albuquerque had desired for Portugal; while her commerce abroad reacted on her internal development so as to en- courage the pursuit of agriculture as a profitable calling by resident gentry and to promote the manufacture of the products of the realm. This practical wisdom, combined with the soundness of the economic policy which was adopted, conspired to place this country in the front rank of European nations. The French had been the representative of Medi- aeval Christendom in its struggle with Mohammedanism in the East; but in the eighteenth century England took the lead among the rising nationalities, and it is by means of the influence of English-speaking people that Western Civilisation has spread throughout the world in modern times. BOOK VI. THE EXPANSION OF WESTERN CIVILISATION. CHAPTER I. I. THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION. 124. In the latter part of the eighteenth century there was a burst of inventive genius in Great Britain. Many improvements were rapidly intro- invention, and duced, and the useful arts, as practised from '*^ effects- time immemorial, were revolutionised in a few years. This was no mere accident, but was at least partly due to the fact that the conditions of economic life had become more favourable to such change than they had ever been before. The age of geographical discovery had paved the way for the age of invention; England had succeeded in surpassing each of the rivals who during a century and a half had striven with her for the commercial supremacy of the world ; her predominance afforded the English inventors of the eighteenth century unexampled opportunities for turning their talents to account. Holland, which had been the leading economic power of the seventeenth century, was no longer the carrier of the world, c. w. c. II. 15 226 Western Civilisation. [BOOK VI, and during the first half of the eighteenth century her manu- factures had declined in importance. The over-centralisa- tion of authority in France had reacted injuriously on all branches of industry and agriculture in that country; it had destroyed the initiative of the people and brought about the decadence of the realm. English shipping had increased as the Dutch declined and had opened up distant markets for the national manufactures, especially for hardware and for textiles. The East Indies were willing to accept unlimited supplies of cotton cloth ; and the continent of Europe and the colonies of America were largely dependent on Great Britain for woollen goods ; manufacturing could be conducted on a larger and larger scale without immediate risk of glutting the widespread demand by overproduction. So long as com- merce had been organised as an intercivic affair, or on the old regulated lines of exclusive privileges in limited markets^ there could not have been any such stimulus to the invention and introduction of machinery as the world-wide markets naturally afforded. But more than this : the mines of the New World and the successful commerce with the East had given England the ma- terial means for the formation of large amounts of capital, which were now available for employment. There had been much admirable ingenuity among seventeenth century engineers and mechanics, but they were hampered by want of capital ; their projects could not be carried out". In the eighteenth century London had become the monetary centre of the world, and it was no longer impossible to venture on the long and ' After the Revolution of 1688 the English trading companies found it much harder to maintain their restrictive rights. Cunningham, Grmoth 0f Industry, II. 282. " Compare the projects for improving the internal communication of England by water. Even in the latter part of the eighteenth century the Duke of Bridgewater had the greatest difficulty in procuring the necessary funds for his first undertaking. Smiles's Lives of Engineers, I. 222. CHAP. I.] The Industrial Revolution. 227 costly experiments that were often needed to render some mechanical improvement a financial success. We are not detracting from the genius' of Watt or Arkwright if we say that they seized and made the most of opportunities, such as no other men had ever had before. Had they lived under the conditioas which were in vogue in preceding centuries, both as to demand for goods and the supply of capital, these great inventors could only have enjoyed the meagre distinction which future generations accord to men who were in advance of their times. It has been pointed out above, that the great geographical discoveries of the fifteenth century were the result of long-con- tinued and conscious effort, directed to a clearly understood aim ; great expeditions had to be organised to sail on unknown seas and establish friendly relations with distant potentates. Explorers were forced to wait on courtly patronage and royal initiative ; but mechanical invention has run a different course. The coincidence of the two phenomena, a world-wide demand and a large supply Of capital, enabled humble and unknown men to push on step by step ; political prestige and elaborate organisation were not so essential as in schemes for colonisation; mechanical skill and personal ingenuity had at last obtained their chance. The new industrial era, which the age of invention brought in its train, has offered a free field and given the greatest rewards to individual enterprise. It is commonly said, that the physical advantage of England in the possession of enormous supplies of coal and iron side by side^ have enabled her to out-distance her rivals, not only in ' See below, Appendix, p. 276. ' The advantage England derived from this source of wealth, in her struggle with France, was very great. Coal had been worked in Roman times, and there was a considerable coal trade with London and with foreign countries in the seventeenth century. But the cost of carriage rendered it impossible to work the Lancashire, Yorkshire, or Derbyshire coal-fields to any considerable extent till canals were introduced. When the difficulty of smelting iron with 15— J 228 Western Civilisation. [BOOK VI. commerce but in industry ; still, the proximity and quantity of coal and iron do not in themselves account for her success com- pletely ; in the case of such inventions as Arkwright's they do not account for it at all. The favourable conditions which English manufacturers enjoyed, in the eighteenth century, and the reliance on individual enterprise which had been traditional in Great Britain, were not unimportant factors in rendering this island the workshop of the world. The Industrial Revolution has nowhere exerted its full influence as yet ; we cannot regard it as an era that is in any sense closed even in any one country, while there are many lands that are only beginning to feel its effects. There can be little doubt, however, that the industrial methods which it intro- duces will sooner or later be adopted wi?h more or less completeness in every part of the globe. In no territory can the rulers afford to hold aloof from the march of material progress ; they might do so in times of peace, but they cannot in case of war ; the mechanical appliances of modern warfare — including the railway as a means of massing troops,— are indispensable to those who desire to preserve political inde- pendence successfully; and the only hope of effectively handling the weapons of war lies in developing native skill. It is impossible even to depend entirely on the supplies of the coal was solved as a practical thing, so that coal smelting could be a commercial success, there was a great increase in the demand for the fuel, and new fields could be profitably worlced. But it was the invention of the steam-engine by Watt that enabled England to take full advantage of her mineral wealth, as she had never previously done. The coal and iron trades developed in combination and with enormous rapidity ; both were requisite for. the construction of machinery, and coal was needed for providing the power by which it could be continuously worked. It thus came about that the commercial supremacy to which England attained in 1760 reacted on her manufactures and gave a new importance to her mineral wealth. The age of invention and the introduction of steam-power combined to give her not only a commercial, but an industrial supremacy as well. CHAP. I.] The Industrial Revolution. 229 munitions of war that may be procurable from foreign nations. Modern mechanical skill and modern methods of organising industry are forcing themselves on all the peoples of the world ; and this imitation under compulsion is not likely to be checked within any period we can forecast. The age of invention is having a very deep influence on the thickly populated countries which were brought into contact with Western Civilisation at the epoch of the great discoveries ; Asia and Africa had been but little affected by intercourse with Europe till this new movement began. It would have been possible to carry on commerce between England and India for centuries, without bringing any novelty into the social life of the 'changeless East.' But the introduction of modern industrial appliances and organisation is a different matter ; the building of railways and the erection and working of other machinery has come about through the intervention of capitalist direction and control ; and modern methods of business administration tend to modify the habits of daily life- and work of Eastern peoples. No attempt can be made as yet to summarise the precise nature of the changes which have taken place in every part of the world as the result of the age of invention ; it must suffice to indicate the general trend of these new economic forces, so far as we can gauge it. To do this intelligently it will be necessary to concentrate attention on the recent history of England, as that is the country where the changes originally began, and where there has been most opportunity for the reaction of the Industrial Revolution on various sides of social and political life. We may thus detect the prominent tendencies that may be looked for in other parts of the globe, though they will of course be greatly modified according to the special circumstances of each country. By examining the results of the age of invention as we may see them in England itself, and as we may trace them in English policy, we can form some idea of the lines on which the slower movements in other lands are likely to proceed. 230 Western Civilisation. [book VI. 125. The true character of the Industrial Revolution The loss of ™^y ^^ most easily seen if we contrast the industrial sta- conditions of English industry in the middle of ' ' ^' the eighteenth century with those that were current in the staple trades of the country about seventy years later'- At the earlier date there was an extraordinary stability in the economic life of England ; manufacture was on a very small scale as compared with the giant production of a later date ; but it had a firm footing, and there was little danger of violent fluctuations or of serious competition. By far the most important industry was the weaving of cloth, both woollen and worsted ; closely connected with this, were the preparatory processes of carding or combing and spinning, as well as the separate callings of shearmen, cloth-workers, and dyers. This great industry catered for foreign markets, and there were, of course, occasional periods of depression, owing to interruptions of exportation ; but on the whole the steadiness of the trade was remarkable, and was due to the fact that England produced her own raw materials, chiefly if not exclusively, and that the reputation of English manufacture stood so high that the goods could almost always be sold at remunerative prices. On the one hand, there was not much risk of a wool famine ; and on the other, the demand for so excellent an article was not likely to fall off. Those who were employed in the trade could usually count on doing a regular and steady business ; the man who started as a clothier or merchant", might have little prospect of making a fortune rapidly, but it was most improbable that he would fail altogether. In the early part of the present century, the cotton trade had grown from relative insignificance to great importance and had out-distanced the woollen trade. Drapery was no longer 1 The period between the triumph of the English arms at Plassey and Quebec, and at Waterloo, may be talcen as giving the limits. . 1759—1815. * The term clothier is ambiguous ; it applies to cloth merchants in the West of England, and to weavers in Yorkshire. GHAP. I.] The Industrial Revolution. 231 the principal article of English export. There was a large market for cotton yarn in Germany, and for cotton cloth in the East ; the raw materials in this industry, however, were not of home production. English workers were dependent for a supply on Eg)?pt and later on the Southern States, and the frequent interruptions, to which the trade was liable, rendered cotton- spinning highly speculative. There were sudden changes in the conditions of business ; and while many men made large fortunes, there were numerous capitalists who had great diffi- culty in maintaining their commercial existence. The instability of the cotton manufacture was brought into clear light during the war with the United States in 1812', and became still more obvious half a century later, during the cotton famine con- sequent on the Civil War between the North and the South. The progress of mechanical invention, and the success of English producers in catering for distant markets, have involved this serious drawback, — that there is far more instability in industry than there used to be in the pre-revolutionary era. The fluctuations are more violent, and there is also much greater probability that some foreign compej^tor may be success- ful in ousting the English producer from markets which he has hitherto supplied. The commercial supremacy of Great Britain in the eighteenth century led to rapid industrial growth; and by that develop- ment her textile and hardware trades have become her chief resources ; they now constitute the basis of much of her com- merce and the means of purchasing supplies of food. The rela- tive instability of her industry, now that manufactures form such a vital factor in her national economic life, is a serious danger to the continuance of the material prosperity of Great Britain as a political power ; and the uncertainty attaching to modern industry also has a very detrimental effect on the condition and ' The difficulty of procuring raw materials by importation had been one of the causes for the industrial decline of Holland. Pringsheim, op. cit. 38. 23^ Western CiviUsatioit. [Book VI, comfort of thousands of workmen personally. Fluctuations in trade must mean inconstancy of employment and such variations in the rates of wages that it is almost impossible for the workman to maintain his ordinary standard of comfort. The industrial changes which have been forced on by the age of invention have deprived the working classes of the means of warding off the mischief which this element of irregularity entails. In the pre-revolutionary days, there was a very close interconnection between industrial and rural employments. This was especially true of the staple trade of the country — the manufacture of cloth. Many of the weavers were small farmers with a little grazing land, while others could eke out their subsistence by occasional labour in the fields during harvest and at other busy seasons. As weaving came to be more and more attracted to the industrial centres, and to be organised by capitalists who provided weaving sheds in which the hands worked under super- vision, there was less opportunity for combining agricultural work with cloth-making. The introduction of the power-loom drew the industry still more into factories and completed the divorce of the weavers as a class from the soil ; they could no longer rely on a rural by-occupation for the means of subsistence, but were forced to be dependent on wages alone, at the very time when wages had come to be very irregular. In this way, the introduction of machinery accelerated the aggregation of the population in factory towns. The prejudicial effect of this change is most clearly seen in the case of the Yorkshire weavers, who strove to resist it by all the legal means in their power ; but industrial employments of other kinds and in other places were somewhat similarly affected. Artisans, who had had allotments from which they could procure garden produce, were deprived of this outside source of supplies and were reduced to the position of mere wage-earners, when the ex- pansion of the great towns like Sheffield covered the available space with busy shops'. In the pre-revolutionary days the 1 Cunningham, Growth of English Industry, II. 480. crtAP. i.j The Industrial Revolution. 233 majority of the skilled workmen of the country seem to have had a second string to their bow ; in the early part of the present century they appear to have become wage-earners pure and simple. The concentration of industrial enterprise in large centres has been an inevitable result of the age of invention and has many economic advantages ; it gives great facilities for effective supervision^, while it enables the capitalist to turn natural supplies of power to good account'; none the less must it be recognised that the effects on the hands were temporarily injurious from the iirst, and that the permanent loss to the rural districts has been very great. So long as weaving was widely diffused throughout the country, there was in every district plenty of work for those women and children who liked to betake themselves to the spinning of wool' ; this served as a by-employment by which a substantial contribution could be made to the family income of rural labourers and of farmers. The concentration of the trade, and still more, the introduction of spinning machinery, deprived the agricultural population of this opportunity of earning a livelihood; the period of transition was tided over by a liberal distribution of poor relief, which had disastrous results in pauperising the rural districts; but the net result, at the close of the Napoleonic War, was similar in rural and urban life, — the labourer was everywhere reduced to the condition of a mere hand, who was wholly dependent on his wages for the means of subsistence, and who had no means of supplementing his earnings from any other source. 126. This serious industrial change occurred at a time ' See above (p. i8i) on the Gilds and capitalist organisation. * This is especially true in regard to water, which was the motor-power chiefly used in the first phases of the industrial revolution. * Cotton-spinning was a comparatively small aftair, and was confined to a small area before Arkwright and Hargreaves revolutionised it by their inventions. 234 Western Civilisation. [BOOK VI. when English agriculture was also being revolutionised, and when the general trend of progress in the listic* o^Janll management of land was proving disastrous to cuiture"*^ *^"' *^ ™''^^ labourer. In many parts of the country some sort of open field cultivation continued to be practised in the eighteenth century; the yeoman farmers had holdings of thirty or forty acres each, and these consisted of separate strips, intermingled with those of other cultivators. All landlords and others who were interested in promoting agricultural improvements re- garded this primitive system of tillage as a serious obstacle to the changes they contemplated; and the process of en- closure was pushed on rapidly, so that each farmer might have his own land in severalty, and be able to work it to the best advantage, according to his own ideas*. This rearrangement might have been beneficial to all parties, but it was so costly, that the small farmers had difficulty in paying their share of the expense ; and during the period of transition, a great many of the little holdings appear to have been consolidated. The yeoman farmer, whether freeholder or tenant, who worked the land himself, with only occasional help, was rapidly superseded by the capitalist farmer, who habitually employed labourers for wages. Some of the small farmers. prob- ably sank in the social scale to the position of mere labourers, who as a class, also seem to have suffered by enclosing, at all events, in cases where they had been permitted to put a little stock on the common waste. Generally speaking, the labourers lost their chance of rising in the world ; this had always been open to them so long as small holdings were available, which they might sooner or later be able to stock and to work. The progress of enclosure deprived the rural labourer of an effective 1 Enclosures had taken place in the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries, in order to develop sheep-fanning and at the expense of tillage, but in the eighteenth century they were introduced for the sake of improved tillage. CHAP. I.] The Industrial Revolution. 235 ambition, at the very time when the loss of employment in spinning was pauperising his family. We may thus see that the changes which followed on the age of invention resulted in the development of similar economic conditions both in town and country. Throughout England we find the triumph of capitalist organisation. The domestic^ system was passing away so far as the clothing trade was concerned, and the yeoman farmer was rising to a different grade, or was disappearing altogether. Both in town and country life there were capitalist employers, who con- trolled and supervised the work of labourers; in town and' country alike the labourers were strictly dependent on the em,ployer for the means of subsistence, and had no means of supplementing their earnings by applying themselves occa- sionally to other occupations. The age of invention ac- celerated the change which, had been going on slowly for centuries", and brought about the complete reconstruction of society, economically considered, on a capitalistic basis. 127. We have already seen that, at its first introduction, the, , capitalistic organisation of industry proved to be incompatible with the existence of the gration of Na- gilds and other institutions of mediaeval civic tionai Econo- ° mic Life. life ; in some , places they checked the mtro- duction of capitalism, in others they were completely super- seded by the new scheme which gave greater scope for the division of labour. The antagonism between the old associations and riew methods becomes more obvious when we see the disintegrating influence of the modern system at work on a large scale. Capital, when it learned to employ the new forces which were put at its service by the age of invention, ' This term, as commonly used does not include all those artisans who worked at home, but applies to the economic system, where the weaver worked on material he purchased, and sold the result of his work to the cloth merchant. * See above p. 180. 236 Western Civilisation. [BOOK VI. outgrew the English system of regulation, which had been established in the interest of the nation as an economic whole. During the early part of the present century, the structure which had been consolidated in the age of Elizabeth was discarded bit by bit, until at last all legislative attempts to pursue the special interest of Great Britain, as distinct from and opposed to that of other countries, were definitely aban- doned. Economists claimed that national prosperity was best attained by leaving capital absolutely unfettered. In the be- ginning of the present century, Parliament was inclined to accept this opinion as axiomatic ; and it is worth while to notice the effect of this maxim and to trace the successive steps by which the great Elizabethan system of regulation was rapidly undermined. The first important agitation arose in connection with the cotton trade. This industry, which had previously been pursued on a very small scale, had developed enormously owing to Arkwright's inventions ; the cheapness of cotton yarn and cloth had stimulated the demand, and, despite the im- provements in the processes of production, there was a much greater demand for labour in connection with the expanded trade than there had been in the old days. The application of machinery to this manufacture had not -injured the labourers at all; it had provided an increased and not a diminished field for employment. The fluctuations in the trade, however, which rendered employment irregular and caused frequent changes in the rates of wages, had reduced the workmen to the lowest depths of distress. The men were anxious to in- troduce greater stability into the conditions under which the industry was carried • on, and attempted again and again to secure, by arbitration, a list of the prices which should be adhered to; they recognised, too, that it was practically im- possible for the masters generally to abide by the rates of the list, if any single employer began to cut down wages. In the hope of obtaining a remedy for this state of things, CHAP. I.] The Industrial Revolution. 237 the workmen fell back on the Elizabethan Act for the regula- tion of wages — a measure which had long before ceased to be effective, but which seemed to bear directly on the case, and, at least, gave a legal character to their demand. They asked that the provisions of the statute should be set in force^; but when the attention of Parliament was called to this obsolete enactment, the House of Commons took an unex- pected view of the situation ; instead of re-enforcing an existing law, they swept away the clauses which had been intended to protect the labouring classes, by providing that wages should be periodically assessed and the . rates fixed according to the plenty or scarcity of the time. It is not certain that this measure had ever been generally enforced ; attempt had been made to put it in operation in a systematic London^, though the system seems to have been allowed to fall into desuetude during the seventeenth century and Parliament could hardly have succeeded in re-enforcing it in the nineteenth; but the repeal of these clauses marks a change in the current view of the duty of the Government towards the workman. In the time of Elizabeth, magistrates were expected to assess fair wages; in 181 1, this safeguard against the mischief which competition may do in reducing wages to starvation rates was swept away. Disputes in the woollen trade were the cause of the repeal of the apprenticeship clauses of Elizabeth's great labour code. Many of the weavers in the West of England had not complied with the requirements of the Act by serving a seven years' apprenticeship; the legal weavers, who had undergone this long training, demanded that the provisions of the Eliza- bethan Statute should be enforced against the ' illegal' workmen. This the capitalist employers of the West of England determined not to do, as they had no complaint to make of the 'illegal' ^ Cunningham, Economists as Mischief Makers, in Economic Review, IV. p. 8. 2 E. A. McArthur, Regulation of Wages in English Historical Review (July 1900), p. 449. 238 Western Civilisation. [BOOK VI. weavers, many of whom were competent workmen ; for the long term of apprenticeship was not a good guarantee of real efficiency, at all events so far as weaving was concerned'. The legal weavers had started an agitation for enforcing existing, though obsolete, laws ; but in the course of the dis- cussion that followed, parliamentary opinion became more and more opposed to their demands. The principal question raised was in regard to apprenticeship ; and the House of Commons finally took the extreme step of withdrawing all the legal encouragement which had hitherto been given to this method of industrial training. The advocates of laissez faire believed that in those trades where it was working well, the seven years' apprenticeship could hold its own, without legislative support ; but later events have proved they were mistaken ; the capitalist organisation of industry is not favourable to apprenticeship, and the system has practically disappeared ^ The Yorkshire weavers, who looked on the binding of apprentices as a barrier to the farther inroads of capitaUsm on their "domestic system," were perfectly right in their forecast of the results of repealing the measure ; the change has been the most drastic of all the innovations caused by the industrial revolution. The introduction of the factory system and the depletion of the rural districts have also tended to bring about the dis- integration of the household as an economic whole. In pre- revolutionary days the children had been kept at home and helped in domestic work or outdoor tasks in farm or garden; and so long as apprenticeship lasted there was a natural training at home for the industrial duties of adult life. Each household, moreover, was an economic whole', as the ^ The art could be learned in two years, and the long term was inconvenient to the masters in the case of idle youths, and pressed hardly on the youth who was doing man's work, but not getting man's pay. " On present methods of entering different trades, compare S. and B. Webb. Industrial Democracy, 11. 454 — 507. ' The contrast between the mediaeval and modern methods of regulation is instructive. The craft-gilds, by exercising a right of search, could bring CHAP. I.] The Industrial Revolution. 239 various members contributed their quota of work, and obtained support from the common stock. The factory system has changed the character of the family as an economic group ; the women and children may go out to earn wages at the factory; domestic employments must necessarily be neglected; and the children, as self-supporting by their own earnings, assume a position of independence which would not have been natural in the old days. As a consequence, parental responsibility for maintenance of the family ceases at an earlier age than was formerly the case^; but the sense of duty in this respect was seriously weakened by the action which the guardians of the poor in rural districts felt forced to take during the wool famine of 1793 a.d. At a time when food was scarce and dear the women and children in rural districts were prevented by lack of material from adding to the family income by spinning, as they had been accustomed to do. The guardians in one district after another granted allow- ances to supplement wages, as a means of tiding over what seemed to be a temporary difficulty; but the industry never revived, and the application of machinery to the spinning of wool killed it off altogether. The action of the poor law authorities in assuming so much of the burden of supporting families was a most serious departure from the principle, which had been assumed from time immemorial, of recognising and enforcing the responsibility of parents for the upbringing of their children. The last remnants of the regulations which had been pressure to bear on men working at their homes as to the condition under which work was done, and the payment and treatment of workmen. The factory Acts and factory and mining commissions aim at supplying similar supervision and are probably much more effective ; but the household is no longer the unit to be taken into account, and the master of the household is no longer the responsible party. The whole series of factory Acts assumes the existence of new conditions of industry, and helps us to see how complete the disintegration of the household had become. ' The evidence before the commission on mines in 1840 a.d. brought out the necessity of protecting children against their parents. 240 Western Civilisation. [BOOK VI. framed with the object of building up a national industrial system, were swept away, as a result of a parliamentary com- mittee' which reported in 1824 a.d. In pre-revolutionary times, when nations were engaged in keen industrial rivalry, such as subsisted between France and England, the authorities were particularly careful to prohibit the emigration of skilled artisans, who might carry trade-secrets with them and plant some valuable art in another country. Great efforts had been made to keep English weavers at home, and to stop artisans from emigrating to the colonies''- Circumstances had so far changed, however, that it seemed unnecessary to maintain these restric- tions ; machinery, rather than manual labour, was now the dominating feature in industrial success. The limitations on the employment of workmen abroad caused special incon- venience to engineers, who were practically prevented from erecting machinery in foreign countries, and no serious effort was made to retain the prohibitions in the Statute Book. There seems to have been an impression that England could .maintain her superiority in manufacture without any such adventitious aid; but the fact that the rules were allowed to drop, shows how completely the old methods of building up national industry to the exclusion of possible rivals had been discarded. This particular change was of great importance in another respect; it removed the legislative hindrances which had stood in the way of founding a new colonial empire on sounder principles than those of the eighteenth century. Mr E. G. Wakefield and a group of enthusiasts were eagerly advocating the planting of Australia as an expedient for relieving the plethora of labour and of capital from which, as they believed, England was suffering. He argued that the colonies should be rendered, so far as possible, self-sufficing communities, equipped ' The most important result of this enquiry was the repeal of the Com* bination Acts ; on these, see below p. 247. ' See below p. 277. CHAP. ].] The Industrial Revolution. 241 with an urban as well as a rural population, and that their prosperity would react favourably on the material wealth of the mother country. He was not able to persuade the Government to interest itself energetically in promoting coloni- sation ; the public were, for a time, indifferent to the expansion of England, but at all events, they ceased to be jealous of the new settlements. All attempts to subordinate the economic development of the colonies to the interests of the mother country have been long since abandoned. The prohibition of the emigration of artisans was one of the last surviving elements of the national system of industrial regulation, but this was finally swept away by a great repealing measure in 1825 ' A.D., and the field was cleared for building a new colonial empire. The laissez faire principle, — that regulation was not neces- sary to promote prosperity and that it might often prove injurious, — was at length applied, though not without hesi- tation, to the mercantile marine, which had been the most important factor in creating England's greatness. The main- tenance and improvement of shipping, as the mainstay of the power of a maritime nation, had been the foremost considera- tion in the economic policy of the country since the time of Burleigh; but in the first half of the present century, this legislative interference was abandoned; it seemed to be no longer necessary, and, in any case, it was of doubtful advan- tage. During the eighteenth century, the development of commercial intercourse had been regarded as of less import- ance than the fostering of English shipping; but under the teaching of Adam Smith, public men began to regard inter- course as in itself a good thing, and to hold that the supposed advantage which accrued from.stimulating shipping was illusory, especially when the loss due to limiting the opportunities of exchange was taken into account. The first great relaxation in the Navigation Acts was made in 1796 a.d., in favour of the 1 5 Geo. IV. c. 95, C. W. C. II. 16 J42 Western Civilisation. [book VI. United States; and experience seemed to show, that free communication with the independent country was far more advantageous than the restricted and regulated commerce with the colonies had been. A few years later, in 1820 a.d., the London Chamber of Commerce took the matter up as a general principle of policy, and insisted that the interests of trade demanded the fullest freedom of intercourse between countries, rather than the special encouragement of our own mercantile marine. The object which had so long been the corner-stone of British policy was deliberately rejected, and the navigation system was rapidly modified, in accordance with the new views. The adherents of the old system of national economics took their last stand in regard to the food supply; it had been the traditional practice in England for centuries to foster agriculture, and so to ensure the existence of sufficient corn for the population'. This was a line of policy that was peculiarly English ; , the profitableness of sheep-farming in the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries had seemed to be a national danger, and special pains were taken for the encouragement of tillage in the Tudor times. The fiscal convenience of govern- ment in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries had told in the same direction; it seemed desirable to provide for the welfare of the agricultural interest, since the taxation of the country fell so heavily on the land. There was a strong ^ The teaching of Malthus had caused a singular change in the ordinary attitude of the public towards the increase of population. In the pre- revolutionary period, there had been frequent anxiety about the alleged decline of population, and some discussion as to the means of stimulating its increase. The rapid development of industry had, as Sir James Steuart insisted, brought about this result so effectively, that the popular mind was scared by the dread of over-population. Further consideration shows that both these fears are illusory; the impulse to increase suffices to take advant^e of any opportunity offered by the means of subsistence, but it does not necessarily bring about such an increase of population as to lower the standard of comfort of any class. Modern Civilisation, 173. CHAP. I.] The Industrial Revolution. 243 phalanx of traditional opinion and of vested interests which combined to pass the Corn Law of 1815 a.d., in the hope that this measure would maintain the conditions which had come into existence during the war, and had given an unhealthy stimulus to corn-growing in Britain. This protective measure failed to accomplish the object with which it was framed; it did little to benefit the agricultural interest generally, though it seems to have been beneficial to the landowners as a class : on the other hand, it hampered our commerce and checked the development of our, manufactures ^ The success of the Free Trade movement was inevitable; and the genius of Cobden secured a very rapid triumph for the principles he had espoused, by the repeal of the Corn Laws in 1846 a.d. The abandonment of the traditional scheme of economic policy in regard to the food supply — the most vital of national interests — was the final blow before which the old system succumbed. At that date, national wealth and prosperity ceased to be a distinct aim towards which national efforts could be wisely directed; the triumph of individual enterprise, against all forms of restriction and regulation, was at length complete. The triumph of individualism over nationalism in internal affairs involved a complete change in the economic attitude which Englishmen took towards other countries. The greatest advantage to Great Britain, under the new conditions, lay in having the freest possible intercourse with other countries, so as to obtain access to the largest markets possible, and to procure supplies on the cheapest terms. It was not to her interest to continue to pursue the exclusive commercial policy by which her naval power had been built up; and her acceptance of a place in a cosmopolitan Economic System was loudly hailed as the harbinger of an era of universal peace. The jubilations of the Free-traders and Peace party have proved premature ; but yet they were not wholly absurd. The desire to pursue an exclusive commerce has been a frequent 1 Cunningham, Growth of English Iiidustry, li. 591. 16 — 2 244 Western Civilisation. [BOOK VI. occasion of war in the past ; national economic rivalry and a war of tariffs keep alive a spirit of hostility which may break out unexpectedly and suddenly in actual fighting. The aban- donment of her traditional system by the greatest of commercial nations has already diminished the causes of conflict so far as England herself is concerned. Foreign traders generally have little to gain through a loss to England of any of those portions of her Empire where she has been free to carry out her new commercial policy. Free trade has not secured peace, but it has done much to remove occasions of active hostility. At any rate the discarding of an exclusive economic policy by the country in which nationality was attained at such an early time is noteworthy. It at least raises the question whether nationality gives the final form for the organisation of industry and commerce. It suggests the speculation that frequent intercourse between different parts of the world may so increase, that all countries may come to be more and more interdependent economically; and that larger and larger sections of the community may find that their interests are suffering from the maintenance of national economic schemes, and may desire instead to be free to make the most of their oppor- tunities as members of a Cosmopolitan System. 128. Attention has been called in earlier chapters of this Re ada ta- ^ssay to the fact that there have been three tion and Re- main types of social structure, which have formed the basis of economic organisation — the family, the city, and the nation. The self-suflScing households of great landed proprietors were superseded, as the basis of in- dustrial life, by the growth of cities ; the city with its exclusive policy, passed away, before the rise of nationalities. The industrial revolution has tended to introduce a thoroughgoing individualism: it makes for the disintegration of the family and it is opposed to nationalism. But it may at least be doubted whether nationalism is a final form in economic development ; and the maintenance of English power under new conditions CHAP. I.] The Industrial Revolution. 245 has discredited the perspicuity of the mercantilists who acted on the opinion that the business pursuits of individuals should be habitually subordinated to the interests of national wealth. Neither the family, the civic, nor the national types of organisation can claim the predominance which each in turn has formerly exercised; they may, however, each have useful economic functions to discharge. There is no immediate prospect that any of them can be dispensed with altogether, for all may contribute effectively to individual well-being. The importance of the family and the home in connection with the upbringing of each new generation, is obvious and need not be dwelt upon ; it is recognised by all grades ; not only by Trades Unions whose policy shows that they are fully alive to the importance of family life as an element in the well-being of the working classes', but also by civic authorities and private philanthropists who are concentrating attention on the problem of so housing the poor, in town and country, that families may be able to live in decent conditions. The city, too, is the appropriate organ for attending to many requirements, which are of vital significance to the individual citizen; provision for lighting, for the supply of water, for rapid transit, for sanitation, and for opportunities of healthful recreation in public parks, are essential to the well- being and efficiency of the inhabitants as individuals. The vast aggregations of population, which have been brought together since the age of invention opened, have rendered these problems more difficult, and there is an ample field for the activity of municipal governments in dealing with them effectively". The nation also has economic functions to discharge, which cannot be dealt with so satisfactorily by any organ of local government. In so far as it is desirable to secure favourable conditions for labour, it is advisable that there should be a 1 Cunningham, Politics and Economics, 100. ' Modern Civilisation, 182. 246 Western Civilisation. [BOOK VI. similar rule through the whole area in which there is a free flow for labour and capital'. The work of factory inspectors and inspectors of mines, has done much to prevent the deterioration of the population. They have been appointed to enforce laws which lay down a minimum of safety and sanitation and a maximum of hours; in this way there has been a gradual amelioration of the conditions in which work is carried on. It is the duty of the Government of a country to look far into the future^, and to consider the maintenance of national resources, while it is not necessarily the interest of any capitalist, however enterprising, to take account of future generations. The final result of the Industrial Revolution, so far as it can be traced in England, has been, not the destruction of the fundamental types of social organisation', but their adaptation to modern requirements and changed circumstances. At th6 same time some institutions have arisen that are so distinct from anything that has preceded them, that they may be regarded as wholly new. Of these, the most important are the Trades Unions. The labour organisations of the Middle Ages, at all events in England, were strictly municipal ; the modern labour association has no such localised character, but is adapted for creating international federations, and for pursuing cosmo- politan aims. Both in its genesis and in its constitution, the Trades Union is very different from the ancient collegia and the mediaeval craft gilds which are its nearest analogues. ' See above on the definition of a country, p. 158. * A new economic importance attaches both to the city and the nation, since the system of public borrowing has become so common. Each is able to draw on its probable future, for tlie sake of iimnediate requirements, on far easier terms than is possible for any individual. ' On the whole, the old civic institutions have been destroyed; but some remain, and considerable efforts are being made to give them a new economic importance. We may notice this tendency in the proposal to utilise the Livery Companies in connection with technical training at the present time. CHAP. I.] The Industrial Revolution. 247 Trades Unions have arisen tentatively or permanently, as a means of protecting labour from the dangers to which it is exposed, when the action of capitalists is quite unfettered and there are no safeguards against reckless competition; and Unionism has gradually felt its way towards a more positive programmed So long as the State professed to undertake the duties of assessing wages and of providing for the efficient training of workmen, there was some reason for objecting to the action of private individuals, associated together for interference in matters of public concern. But the repeal of the Elizabethan industrial code left the workman exposed to all the uncertainty and misery caused by the introduction of machine industry and the sudden fluctuations and ruinous competition which followed in its train. There had been a traditional suspicion of workmen's combinations, and, during the political scare of 1799 and 1800^ a.d., another attempt was made to put them down altogether, as they seemed to be possible centres of sedition. The conditions of secrecy, under which the societies were forced to work, contributed to give them a tyrannical and criminal character', and placed them at a special disadvantage in any attempts to obtain a legal status. As a matter of fact, however, they were only contending for a more thoroughgoing application of the principle of laissez /aire; if the individual ought to be free to act in his own interest, he ought also to be free to combine with other individuals for the pursuit of their common interesf*. In 1825 a.d. the 1 It may now be summarised as the struggle for a,Standard Wage and Normal Day, to be secured by legislative action. * Cunningham, Economists as Mischief Makers, in Economic Seview, IV. 1 2. * Webb, History of Trades Uniotiism, 72. Mrs L. Bankes, Bond slaves. * The freedom of combination for all sorts of economic objects, is the last triumph of individualism. In the days of slave labour, combination might mean a servile war. Even among the free labourers of Athens, there seems to have been very little association ; while the collegia had a chequered existence st Roine- In the Middle Ages the craft gilds, with 248 Western Civilisation. [book vi. Combination Laws were repealed, under the mistaken belief that it never could be for the real interest of individual workmen to combine for trade objects, and that they would soon discover this fact, when once they had perfect freedom of action in the matter'. But the steady increase in the numbers and power of labour organisations, during the last seventy-five years, has given another instance to show how completely mistaken the most skilled observers may be in their forecasts on political and social affairs. The Trades Unions have, for the most part, discarded the restrictive policy which they were inclined to follow at first', and try to pursue a course that is compatible with the attainment of the highest possible efficiency". In so all their dignity, were often Itept in hand by municipal authority or royal regulations; the possibility that they might prove an economic danger was clearly understood. In our country and days attempts at suppressing such organisations have ceased to be possible, even if they were desirable ; the freedom to form voluntary associations for economic objects has been won ; but there may still be graVe anxiety about the wisdom of the Unions, and of the policy they pursue. If these associations concentrate attention on the special interests of one section or class, and -are not ready to abandon any line of action which is injurious to the public as a whole, there must be class antagonisms on the largest scale, entailing frightfiil economic loss. If they have self-restraint enough to take the well-being of the whole community as a principle controlling their action, they will prove their fitness for a share in government by themselves adopting the principle which was authoritatively imposed on voluntary associations and com- binations in earlier times. ' This was the opinion of Francis Place and Joseph Hume, under whose guidance the House of Commons was induced to include the Combination Acts in the great Statute of Repeal in 1825. Wallas, Life of F. Place, 211, 217. ' For instances of this action see Webb, Industrial Democracy, 392 ; on the objection to machinery, see Modern Civilisation, 126 — 7, also Outlines of English History, 226. ' The Manchester School did not take sufficient account of the fact that improved conditions for labour may often bring about increased efficiency of labour, and that under certain circumstances the indirect effect of shortened hours may be to increase and not to diminish production. On the whole, however, they were right in taking the greatest possible amount CHAP. I.] The Industrial Revolution. 249 far as they keep within these lines, their action is innocuous, while they have introduced some useful correctives to the mischiefs which accompanied the transition to capitalist organisation. They have set themselves to introduce greater stability, so as to diminish the violence of trade fluctuations, with its disastrous result on the lot of the workman ; and they have also endeavoured to maintain the workman's standard of comfort, and to oppose all influences which directly or indirectly tend to diminish his welfare. It is sometimes asserted that the improved condition of the English working classes is due to the "general progress of Society," and that there would have been similar results if factory Acts and Trades Unions had never existed ; the statement is certainly unprovable, and it is, on the face of it, highly improbable. Mere individual competition may tend to the progress of society, but it does not necessarily take account of the probable position of the next generation, or of the prosperity of the wage-earning class generally. The State has stepped in with legislation and inspection, and the artisans have organised themselves to secure important elements of well-being, which individuals, as such, would have hardly had the power to obtain. Despite the miserable circumstances of many of the poor, there is yet reason to believe that the new social conditions introduced by the Industrial Revolution are favour- able to the welfare of the working classes, both as regards ma- terial surroundings and personal character. It is easy to idealise of production as a test of the beneficial or the hurtful effects of industrial changes. Any combination, be it of labourers or of capitalists, that by its demands or rules limits the total of production and thus reduces the possibilities of enjojrment is justly suspected of being a public nuisance. There may be adequate grounds for such action, but at least it demands a very full justification, and there is a primd facie case against it. There is also a real danger that, since economic relations and organisations are becoming more and more cosmopolitan, there may be no political power which is capable of dealing effectively in any one district with organisations which have such wide ramifications. 250 Western Civilisation. [BOOK VI. the past, and to paint a picture of the independent and happy weaver, living in a pretty village, working on his own account, and assisted by his wife and family. But the more we examine the details, the more we shall see reason to suspect that the life of the manufacturer in pre-revolutionary days was not one which would rouse the jealousy of the average modern artisan. The standard of comfort was low ; and the weaver, who could earn good wages, was content to spend much of his time in mere idleness; in the narrow circle of village life, he could have no intelligent interests in politics or sport, while he was cut off from all opportunities of musical or literary cultivation. We know, from surviving examples, how miserable were the rooms in which he did his work, and there is no reason to believe that his children always found him a just and self-restrained master ; the primitive factories adopted the normal arrangements of domestic industry, so far as sanitation and ventilation are concerned. The factory system brought to light the thoroughly unsatisfactory state in which men, women and children were living and working, and made it possible to attempt a remedy. There doubtless has been serious los§ to the individual, who has found that he is no longer an independent man, but a hand controlled by the tyranny of the factory bell ; but the discipline of regular work and hours, and the training which comes by association in work, have contributed to the formation of an admirable type of character. As we look back to pre-revolu- tionary days, through all the misery of the transition period, we may doubt if there is any point in which the artisan and his family were better off then than they are to-day. This result has not been due, however, to the blind play of economic forces ; so far as these were concerned they only caused social disintegration and individual degradation. It is the machinery which has been devised to control these blind forces which has been mainly instrumental in bringing about this general amelioration, and has rendered it possible to care for the interest of the masses of the population, present and future. CHAP. I.] The Industrial Revolution. 251 129. Every scheme of nationalist economic policy had assumed as axiomatic, that there were certain kinds of material prosperity, which it was desir- tions in '^^' able to cultivate in the interests of national English « , , . , , ^ , „ Finance. Strength ; and that it was the duty of the Govern- ment to induce the business energy of the people to take those directions which would be beneficial to the country as a political power. Under the influence of Adam Smith, this doctrine fell into disrepute. Since the community is an aggregate of individuals, it seemed that the general wealth was best attained by leaving each man to pursue his own affairs ; it was felt too that if general prosperity were increasing, there would be facilities for procuring any particular form of wealth that might be desired. The recognition of nationality as the guiding principle in all economic organisation had been an important step in advance, but so soon as the country became doubtful of the wisdom of controlling all the economic activities of Englishmen with the aim of fostering the power of the realm, the whole system of national regulation fell into abeyance. Enactments to direct the course of industry, to encourage shipping, and to obtain a sufficient food supply at home, were, as we have seen, abandoned one after another. Para- doxical as it may appear, it is yet strictly true to say that for commercial and industrial purposes, England has ceased to be a "nation" in the economic sense of the term. The change has, however, introduced considerable difficulties in regard to the financial system of the country. From time immemorial, the chief expenses of government, so far as they were defrayed by taxation, had been borne by the land; customs were comparatively unimportant, so long as the trade of the country was trivial, and excises were not levied before the Great Rebellion. The landed proprietors bore the principal part of the burden of taxation, and after the Restoration they showed an increasing jealousy of the moneyed interest, who managed to enjoy great fortunes, while they 252 Western Civilisation. [BOOK VI. contributed but little to the expenses of the nation. Fiscal convenience rendered it easy to assess and collect contributions from those who had a fixed stake in the country ; while Locke taught that the burden of taxation must ultimately fall on the landed proprietors, and that it was best and cheapest to levy it upon them directly. The highly protective Corn Law of 1815 a.d. was in part an attempt to remove the unfairness which was due to the pressure of taxation ; this fell unduly on the landed interest, while agri- culturists were also burdened by the obligation to pay tithe, and the necessity of supporting the pauperised population in rural districts. The Act failed to accomplish its object of rendering the landed interest more able to bear the unfair share with which it was charged. The cost to certain sections of the community proved so great, that it was impossible for Govern- ment to persist in this clumsy expedient for rectifying the injustice of the fiscal system. Considerable progress has been made, however, in solving the difficulty in a better way; arrangements have been devised which have proved fairly successful in assessing and collecting revenue from citizens whose wealth does not consist in real estate. The excise and customs have come to be very large branches of revenue, and they are paid by consumers of every class, rich and poor, rural and urban. Still more important in its principle is the income tax, which forces the capitalist to contribute from the profits of his business, and the rentier to pay a portion of the revenue from his savings. The machinery for the collection of this branch of Inland Revenue can be used for adjusting the incidence of taxation, to a considerable extent; though it is not easy to fix on any standard of fairness or unfairness in apportioning public burdens between the landed and the moneyed interests. There is however one obvious advantage which arises from the existence of the income tax ; it has become possible to discard the nationalist economic policy without serious financial danger. In days when landed proprietors CHAP. I.] The Industrial Revolution, 253 were the only class that could be reached by the collectors of revenue, it was necessary to safeguard their interests ' j but the income tax gives the means of deriving revenue for the State from the profits of capital invested abroad; it removes the financial motive which formerly gave rise to jealousy lest colonial progress should interfere with the sources from which national revenue was drawn. So long as moneyed Englishmen continue to prefer their own country and make it their home, it is a matter of comparative indifference to the Government, whether their capital is invested in India, or the colonies, or in this island ; it still pays its quota of revenue to the Crown. The re-organisation of our revenue system, which was accepted by the country in 1874 A.D., is compatible with the development of English economic activity, not merely on national, but on cosmopolitan lines. England has been the pioneer of the age of invention ; by herself accepting the results of the industrial revolution, she has been fitted to take a principal part in diffusing these industrial improvements and introducing rapid means of communication in all parts of the globe. The work she has already accompHshed, directly and through her great offshoots in America and Australasia, give her a unique importance in the history of the world, while it has forced her to adapt her own economic life to a cosmopolitan environment. A country has been defined for economic purposes as an area within which there is a free flow of labour and capital ; but Englaiid recognises and imposes no limits of area ; she has allowed the emigration of her skilled labourers since 1825 a.d., and has become fiscally indifferent to the fields which may be chosen for the investment of capital. For good or for evil, she has abandoned a national economic policy, alike in commerce and industry, in agriculture and finance. ' This is particularly noticeable in the treatment which Ireland received in the seventeenth century. Cunningham, Repression of Woollen Trade, in English History Review, I. 287. ^54 CHAPTER II. GENERAL TENDENCIES AND PARTICULAR CONDITIONS. 130. The rapid material progress which began in England last century is being communicated to the rest of awe^'tendency the world. The benefits which the new pro- of Economic ccsses of industry and means of intercourse offer are so great that peoples, like the Japanese, who have long remained in an almost stationary condition are glad to imitate the progressive races of the West, and to introduce mechanical inventions of every kind. In other cases, such as that of China, the necessities of military defence have compelled princes to adopt modern weapons, and to borrow some assistance from European instructors. Enter- prising capitalists are ready to force their way into any part of the world, where there is a prospect of developing natural resources, which will yield a profitable return on their ventures. Mechanical improvements and the capitalist organisation of industry — with which machine-production is most conveniently associated — are superseding the primitive industrial arts and earlier types of economic life in every known region of the globe. Some of these changes are inevitable; it may often be a matter of regret, but the great economic forces, when once they are allowed to come into operation, will not be gainsaid ; and it is improbable that the movements which begin when a Chap, ll.] General Tendencies, Particular Conditions, 25S country is drawn into the circle of trading intercourse, can be arbitrarily arrested at any point. When barriers are once broken down, the substitution of money payments for natural economy, of competition for regulated prices, and of capitalistic supervision for gild organisation, is likely to go on apace ; it is difficult to conceive of any means by which these changes can be checked so that the old social forms and customary usages may be preserved intact. It is easy to denounce the " greed " of prospectors and pioneers who open up some new country ; but their gains are not merely personal, since their enterprise is only rewarded^ when they succeed in meeting a general demand by catering for the requirements of the inhabitants of the thickly populated European countries. We live in times when claims to exclusive privilege are subjected to careful scrutiny; civilised peoples are insisting that the resources of the earth shall be utilised to their fullest extent; they resent the claim of any barbaric or half-civilised people to retain territory when they are careless about turning it to good account. It is in the interest of the race as a whole that the possibiUties of life on the globe should be fully enjoyed ; and those who prefer to live as hunters or nomads on land that is suitable for tillage will never be able to hold their own in the struggle for subsistence. If any tribe or community refuses to bring its energy to bear in turning the land to the most profitable use, it is likely to be ousted by others who are ready to undertake the task. 131. There are many persons who believe that these changes are deleterious and who look towards the future pessimism with the gloomiest sense of foreboding. They ?"^ Anarch- believe that every step of progress means that a larger and larger portion, of the population of the globe is drawn into a keener struggle for existence ; that every improve- ment in the industrial arts conduces to providing a larger food 1 Modem Civilisation, 141. As Mr Booth urges, profit is not so much a motive as a guide. Life and Labour of the People in London, ix. 1 70. 256 Western Civilisation. [BOOK VI. supply, but with severer toiP; and that the race is steadily tending towards a desperate plight when the numbers will be far greater than at present, and the misery of all more intense. But this pessimistic view of the future of the race rests on the assumption that man is the slave of his grosser impulses. Each advance in material progress in the past has opened up an opportunity which may be used either for the diffusion of increased comfort, or for the mere multiplication of numbers on the existing level of comfort, or partly for one and partly for the other. There is a current opinion that such advantages are sure to be misused for the increase of the numbers at the old standard, but this is not necessary or inevitable; still less is there any reason to believe that the increase of population mil go on mechanically sp as to drive the masses to a lower level of life". So far as we can judge, the standard of comfort of the skilled artisan in America and in England is higher than it has been at any previous period of the world's history; and the labouring classes possess so much political power in these countries that the efforts they are making to maintain or to raise that standard will not be easily thwarted. So long as this is true of the most advanced communities we need not fear that material progress must necessarily lead to the increased misery and degradation of the race. The mere increase of numbers and the capitalist organisa- tion of modern society are, however, inconsistent with the aims that many individuals cherish for themselves personally. The classical economists ideaUsed a condition of affairs in which every man should be free to pursue his own interest as he con- ceived it ; and they urged that this is advantageous for the com- munity as a whole, since it conduces to the production of the greatest mass of goods. A more thoroughgoing individualism insists that in the existing state of society the majority of the population are deprived of all opportunity of making their ^ On the law of diminishing returns, see Modern Civilisation, 77 — 79. » Ibid. 174. CHAP. II.] General Tendencies, Particular Conditions. 257 way in life, and are condemned from their birth to toil in a fashion which may be advantageous to others, but is not in their own interests at all. As the line between the employing and the labouring classes becomes more clearly drawn, and as there is increasing difficulty in passing from one grade to the other, together with diminished facilities for rising into the more important positions in the employing class, there is less scope for the individual to carve out a career for himself. Persons of exceptional ability are still able to force their way to the highest rungs on the social ladder, but those with ordinary attainments and abilities can hardly hope ever to advance to the grade above them. There are larger and larger numbers of people who feel that they have never had a chance of improving their position, and who resent the institutions of society which have condemned them and so many of their fellows to a life of drudgery. Anarchism is not a mere inexcusable madness ; it is a very real danger to existing society because it is the logical outcome of certain widely current beliefs as applied by many individuals to their own circum- stances. The mass of available wealth is of little account to such men, except in so far as it is available for them to enjoy during their own lives ; they demand freedom for individual self-development, and do not admit that they are called upon to sacrifice themselves personally either for the sake of the existing order or for generations to come. However excusable this attitude of mind may be, such ultra-individiialism is inconsistent with the maintenance and progress of human society ; we must not neglect either the personal or the social side of the matter. It is true that the institutions of any society are to be judged by the effect they have on the character of individuals ; but it is also true that the worth of the individual is to be gauged by his ability and readiness to contribute to the well-being of society present or future. That the sphere for independent action is being narrowed by capitalist organisation is a real hardship to the c. w. c. IX. 1 7 2S8 Western Civilisation. [BOOK VI. individual ; but from the social standpoint it is advantageous because it is disciplinary, and renders the man more efficient than he would otherwise be. We must remember, too, that the highest development of character is quite compatible with consciously accepting a place in the social order and making the most of it. It is a mistake to assume that the limitation of opportunity, which is brought about by the increase of numbers and greater complexity of society, must necessarily involve personal degradation. Those who contemplate the greater command over the means of production which has been placed within our reach by the age of invention, cannot but feel a sense of dis- appointment that so little has resulted for the happiness of the human race. Still, though we can no longer sympathise with the light-hearted optimism of the classical economist, we need not fall into the opposite blunder of decrying material progress as if it were merely mischievous, or necessarily in- volved serious evils. It does open up the possibility for an improved standard of comfort, though the occasions it offers may be neglected or misused ; it leaves less scope for individual independence, but this does not necessarily imply a deterio- ration of personal character. 132. At the same time, it is to be noticed that the mis- Controi ver ^^^^^^ ^" 36, 38, 141, 280; monastic organisation, 37; Rule, 141; monasteries as nuclei of towns, 38 «. Beneficia, 51 286 Index. Bergen, 113, 179 • Berwick 279 Beverley, 95 Biervliet, 197 Bills of Exchange, 86, 176, 177 Birca, 109 Biscayan harpooners, 202 Bishop of Rome, 19, 30, 31 ; see Papacy. Bishops, mediaeval, 19, 20, 21, 91; public influence of, 21, 22, 23, 29, 30; in North Africa, 121 Black Death, the, 10, 102, 139, 143, 144, 280; trade after, 14O Black Sea, the, no, 125, 126, 127, 178 Bohemia, 47, 68, 86 Boileau, £tienne, 96 Book-keeping, 205 «. Bordeaux, 47, 58 Bosphorus, the, 3 Boston, U.S.A., 282 n. Bougie, 123 Boulogne, 47 Bourges, 155 Brabant, 197, 199 Brahmanism, 66 Brandenburg, 1 49 ». Brazil, 188, 190 »., 203, 212 n. Breton fishermen, 207 Bridges, 5, 39, 40, 146, 209; Barn- staple, 146; Forth, 271; London, 98 n. ; Mayence, 48 Bridgewater, Duke of, 226 «. Brie, 94 Bristol, i8r«. Britain, 21, 37 ; in Roman period, 6, 227 «., 275 ; English invasion of, 275 ; mineral wealth of, 227 «. British Constitution, the, 280; Em- pire, 244 ; economic policy, 242 ; Government, 223 «. ; industry, 253 ; naval power, 243 ; rule, 266 Brokers, 180 Bruges, 73, 99, 113, 179, 180, Brynja, 279 Building trades, 98»., 281; terms used in, 128 //. Bullion, ir, r4, 43«., 53, 84, 86, 173, 192, 196, 222; buUionist policy, of Spain, 195, 196 ; buUionist system, 222, 223 Burg, 59 Burgundians, 20»., 29, 30 Burleigh, Lord, 53, 218, 241 Bury, 92 «. Byzantium, 41 «., 128 ».; Empire, 277 «.; statesmen, i68; see Con- stantinople. Cabot, 219 Cadiz, 191 Caesarius, 20 ». Caffa, 125, 134/2. Calicut, 131, 183 Calimala, Arte di, g^n., i6;», , 182 Caliphate, the, 114, 115, 116, 118 Camera, 86 Canada, 54»., 266 Canals, 5, 39, 40, 209, 227 «. Cannanore, 184 Canon Law, 67, 68, 85, 153; Canonists, 152, 175 Canossa, 19 Canynges, William, of Bristol, 156 «., 175 Cape Bojador, 131 Cape of Good Hope, 178, 199, 201 K. Cape Verde Islands, 131 Capital, 8, io«., 14, 15, 136, 137, 158, 162 seg., 168, 170, 178, 196, 198 »., 203, 204»., 2IT, 212, 216, 223, 223 «., 226, 227, 236, 240, 265; in ancient Rome, 165 ; in the cloth manufacture, 165 «.; deficiency of, in 171)1 cent., 14; a disintegrating force, 167; fluidity of, 164, 177; free flow of, 158, 246, 253; fresh applications ofj 165 ; investment of, 201, 223, 253; abroad, 253; "sunk" and "fixed," 164 ».; transference of, 176 Capitalism, 153, 163, 169, 235, 238; mediaeval, 164 Capitalist administrative machinery, tndex. 287 171; application of, 14-16; com- panies, 177 «., 181; in cloth, 165 ; direction, 229 ; employers, 181-2, 235, 237; farming, 210, 234; German, in Spain, 194; manufacturers, 195 ; merchants, 181 ; oligarchies, 125; triumph of, 235 ; organisation of agriculture, 234 seq.\ of industry, 195, 210, 232, 238, 254, 259; military or- ganisation, 1 71-2; of society, dangers inherent in, 166, 256 ; policy, 181 ; effective supervision, 255; waste of, at Rome, 14 Capitalists, 54«., 88, 89, 97, 98, 99' "3. 136. 156. 163 «•. 170. 171, 175 «•> 176. 179, 180, i8o»., 182, 195, 204, 231, 233, 246, 247, 248 »., 252, 254, 259, 260, 262; of Augsburg, 175 «. Capitularies, 41, 44»., 45, 48, 61, 104. 133; S3> S4i 59. 61, 66, 76, 82, 104, 108, 109, III, 113, 114, 119, 120; compared with Alfred the Great, 41 k. ; Church and State under, 45 ; commerce under, 46 seg.; contrasted with Theodoric, 42 ; currency, 50 ; debt of English civilisation to, 54; the economic household under, 51; Empire of, 171 ; endower of monasteries, 44 n. ; Mediterranean fleet of, 47; as model king, 41, 44, 44 ». ; economic policy of, compared with Burleigh's, 53; the vi//a under, Siseg. Charles Martel, 114 Chateau Gaillard, 73 «. China, 186, 200, 254 Christendom, 2, 3, 4, 6, 7, 9, 10, II, 18, 19, etc., 138, 139, 140, 143, 146, 151, 152, 158, i6s, 167, 189, 197, 279 ; assimilation of pagan elements by, 71; dis- ruption of, 13, 138, J43, 157, 160, 268 ; Eastern, 32 ». ; ec- clesiastical organisation of, 74, 76 ; economic institutions of, 70 ; labour regulation in, 16; homo- geneity of, 66; provinces of, 138; secularisation of, i^Ssej., 145 ».; social system of, 67, i6i Christian IV, of Denmark, 198 «. Christian chivalry, 130; conception of price, 28-9; colonies, 67; duty, 273 ; economic doctrines, 9, 10 ; ideal of civic duty, 45 ; in- fluence, 27, 118, 140; principles, permanent, 273 ; teaching, 7, 8, 10, II, 16, 23, 25, 27, 35, 45, etc.; theory of slavery, 133-4 Christianity, 2, 7, 7«., 8, 9, 18, 36, 105, io8, 118; contrasted with Islam, 26«., 118; civil liberty 288 Index, and, 31 H.; "established" by Charles the Great, 44 ; in the East, io«. ; influence of, 18, aj; Latin, 29, 31 ; militant, 3, in Crusades, iii, 113; Norsemen converted to, 1 1 1 ; as regenerating social force, 69, 118 Christians, Nestorian, 184 Church-building, 70-72, 98 ». Church lands, 194 «. Circulating medium, 169; see Cur- rency. Cistercians, 38, 71; see also Citeaux. CM, in French towns, si «., 58 Citeaux, 71, 141 City, the, 158; see also Town; as economic unit, 99, 244, 245- City-states, Greek, 7, 75, 150; mercantile policies of, 149 Civic economy, 89; life, 107, 150; organisation, 93 ; patriotism, Dutch, 204; policy, 99, 148-9; nationalising of, 159 Civil Law, the, 68?*., 152, 154 Civilisation, ancient, 1; Arab, 120; Greek, 66 n. ; Phoenician, ibid. ; Roman, ibid., 275 Civilitas, 25 Civitas, 21, 2i»., 22». ; civitates, 21 Classes, the, agricultural, 174 ; employing, 257 ; industrial, 169, 174; labouring, 256-7 ; mercan- tile, 125, 169; trading, 154-5 Classical Economists, 256, 258 Clermont, 49 Clive, Lord, 265 Cloth, 94K., 99, 113, 128; cotton, 226, 231, 236; woollen, 230; worsted, 230; cloth dressing, 39, 165 n. ; manufacture, 232 ; merchants, 94, 230, 230 «., 235; cloth trade, 194 Cloth-of-gold, 208 Clothier, 230, 230 «. Clovis, 30 Cl^ny, 71, 141 Cnut, H2 Coal, 228 Coasting voyages, 185 Cobden, Richard, 243, 265 Coblentz, 39, 48 Cochin, 184 Codes, barbarian, 32 Coeur, Jacques, 155, 156, 175 Coinage, debasement of, the, 83, 169 Coins, 84, no; see Currency. Colbert, his economic policy, 157, i9o»., 203, 213, 2i3»., 214, 215, 219 »., 222 Coligny, 212 «. Collection of revenue, 156, 163 «., 167, 172 Collect! vist trading, 123 Collectores, Papal, 87; royal, 88 Collegia, 6, 24 n., 65, 97 »., 246, 247 «. Cologne, 21, 39, 48, 58; Jews at, 49 Coloni, i2«., 58 Colonial Empire, 204, 2ri, 220, 240, 241, 270; in the East, 200; French, 207, 212; Portuguese, 206; Spanish, 190, 196 Colonies, British, 198, 216 «., 222, 240, 242, 253, 265, 266; of aliens, 282; in America, 226; French, 207, 212, 213, 267; Ger- man mercantile, in the Baltic, 112; Spanish, 193, 199 Colonisation, 11, 12, 132, 162, I75»., 214, 227; English, 241; motive of, 220, 221 ; why successful, 224; French, 207, 208, 211 ; Greek, 158; Norse, no, iio». ; Phoenician, no, no«.; Teutonic, SS. 5S»-; schemes of, 227 Columbus, 131, 132, 13s ». Combination, 248 n. ; of artisans, 29 ». ; freedom for, 247, 247 n. Commerce, in, 145, 154, 162, 213, 221 ; active, 6, 183,201; British, 253 ; under Charles the Great, 46 seg. ; cosmopolitan, 130 ; sti- mulated by Crusades, 92 ; Dutch, 202; Eastern, 183; French, re- vival of, 207; internal, 209; inter- civic, 9, 226 ; Levantine, 208 ; monastic, 36, 39; Scandinavian, 112 Index. 289 Commercial life in Baltic, 109 ; colonies, 93, 124; dep6ts, 128, 185; Portuguese, 188; enterprise, i7S»-, 213; expansion, 270; in- tercourse, II, 137, 181; interests, 217-8; monopolies, 174; motive in Crusades, 72; exclusive, 243- 4; regulation, rudimentary, 63; routes, 128; supremacy, 211,225, 227 «. Commission, dealing on, 179 Commissions, Factory, 238 «. ; Mining, ibid., 239 «. Common Estimation, 80 Communes, the, ^, 90-2, 94; rise of the, 89 seq. Communication, means of, 157, 226W., 245, 253-4, 260; trading lines of, 127 Companies, capitalist, Vl'in., i8i ; Livery, 246 ».; merchant, 157, 179 1 trading, English, aSn. Company, East India, see under India; of New France, 212 Competition, 176, 177, 220, 230, 237, 249' 255. 259, 277; foreign, 231 ; rents settled by, 102 ; wages, ibid. ; reckless, 247 Compositions, money-, 102 Concessions, 192 n., 194 n. ; trade-, 179; of tribute, 186 Congiegeld, 204 ». Constantine, 3 Constantinople, i, io»., 26, 41a., 49, 68«., 90, io7»., no, 117, 125, 126, 127 Consuls, of trading cities, 122 Contractus Trinus, I53«. Copper, 113 ; mining, 175 «. ; -work, 281 Corbie, 44 «. Cordova, 120, 194 Cordwainers, 65, 95 Cork, no Com, I2»., 198, 198 »., 201, 209, 242, 243 ; com trade, 204 «., 205, 213 «.; transport, 198 Com Bounties Act, 219 ». Corn Laws (1815), 243, 252; repeal of. ^43 Corporations, industrial, 157 ; see also Corps de Meiers, Gilds. Corps de Metiers, 96-7, i8i, 210 Corpus Juris Civtlis, 152 Cosmopolitan commerce, 130 ; economic policy, 253, 265 ; re- lations, 248 K. ; system, 243-4, 264 ; interests, 262 ; police, 262, 267 ; welfare, 263 Cosmopolitanism and nationalism, 261 seq., 265 Cost of production, 81 Cotton, 124 ; cotton cloth, 226, 231, 236; famine, 231; trade, 230, 236; spinning, 231, 233 ».; yam, 231, 236 Council of Paris, 32 — of Trent, 144 — Papal, 140 Country, economic definition of, 158, 246 »., 253 Courts, civil, 152 ; ecclesiastical, ibid, and 85 ; of Piepowder, 95 Craft-gild ; see Gild. Credit, io»., 14, 164, 170, 174, 202; credit system, 223 Crusades, crusading, 66, 68«., 92, 107 «., 108 seq., 117, 119-21, 123-4, 124 »., 125-6, 129-30, 132, 136 »., 139, 158, 164, 189, 206, 279 ; Second Crusade, 86 ; Fourth, 126; commercial motives in crusading, ibid, and 72, 108; impetus to shipping, 125-6 Cuenza, 194 Cultivation, 136, 276 ; open-field, 234; see Tillage. Curator, 29 Curiales, 73 n. Currency, the, 50, 83, 84, 177, 223 «.; under Charles the Great, 5° Customary prices, 82, 259; rates, 102-3 Customs, 34, 48, 76, 88, 157, 185, 187, 192, 205 «., 251, 252; see also liez/emte. Tolls. Cypres, 127 Dagobert, 38 C. W. C. II. 19 290 Index. Damnum emergens, 176 Danes, 36; Danish pirates, 115; raids upon monasteries, 40 ; settlement in Ireland, no Danube, canal from, to the Main, 46; valley, 113, 115, 128 Danzic, 188 «. Debts, of the Crown, 174 ».; re- pudiation of, 202, 203 Defensor civitatis, 22, 28, 29 Demand and supply, 78, 177, 178, 227 ; demand for labour, 236 Denarii, 50 Denmark, 3, 197; German colonies in, 112 Deportation of population, 278, 278 «. Depositaries, 86 Depots, commercial, ioj«., 128, 178, 185 Derby, 1 10 ; Derbyshire, 227 «. Dialogus de Scaccario, 87 Dieppe, 208 Dignity of labour, 35, 36 Diminishing returns, law of, 256 ». Diocletian, regulation of prices under, 28 Discipline, industrial, 250, 258 ; self-discipline, 273 Discovery, of the New World, 129; voyages of, 183 Disintegration, economic, of the household, i%8n.,'m; of nation- al economic life, 235 ; social, 145, 146, 260-1, 274 Diversarum arlitim Schedula, 280 Division of labour, 235 Domesday Book, 61 n. Domestic industry, 202 «., 235, 238, 250, 261 Dominicans, the, 121 Dordrecht, 197 Dover, 84 «. Drapers, 96, 230, 277 Dublin, no Dupleix, 207 Dutch, 189, 197, 198 «., 200-2, 204-6, 212, 215, 217, 282 ; carrying-trade, 198; 203 ; com- mercial system, 198, 204; fisher- men, 203; monopoly, 198, 203; naval administration, 2r7«. ; pas- turage, 197; policy in India, 221; prosperity, 203 ; shipping, 196 seq. ; East India Company, 206; West India Company, 203; 199, 200, 204, 226; trade, 198, 198 «., 202, 2X1 ; wool, 197 Duties, import, 202; see Customs. Duty, civil, Christian ideal of, 16, 45. 273 Dyeing, dyers, 230, 280 East, the, low., 73, 124, 126, 127, r29, 131, 155, 178, 183, 185, 200, 207, 215, 224, 226, 231, 279 ; the " changeless," 229 ; civilisation of, 267 ; Dutch in, 199 seq.; direct route to, 272; legislative codes of, X33; English Empire in, 200, 224 East, the Far, 263 , East India Co., 221, 222 Eastern Empire, 32 «., 43«., 44, 107 n. Ebro, 46 Ecclesiastics, 275 Economic policy, 12, 16, 53, 146 ■s^?-. I54> 158-9. 160, 175, 182, 189, 190, 192, 195, 209, 214, 217-19 «., 224, 241, 243, 251- 3, 264-6 Economy, civic, 89; household, 81, 99 seq. Edward I, 12, 73, 76, 84»., 88, 89, 92 Edward III, 88, 203 Edward IV, I56». Egypt, 1, 6, 49, 127, 134 »., 15s, 185, 186, 23r, 265, 268, 271, 282 Elbe, no Elizabeth, Queen, 53, 215, 216 «., 218, 219, 236 Elizabethan economic regulation, 236, 247 Emigration, 240, 241, 253, 277 Emmanuel, King of Portugal, 185 Emperor, men of, 112 Emperor and Pope, 2, 9, 67, 140 Index. 291 Emperor, Roman, 72, 139, 154, 109 Employers, capitalist, 181, 182, 235, 237. i»57 Employment, inconstancy of, 232 Enamel, 281 Enclosures, 234, 234 «. England, 11, 12, 34, 41, 47, 50, S3, 68, 72, 76, 86, 88, 89, 90, 94«., 96«., 98, 99, 100, loi, no, 128 »., 139, 146, 148, i6yn., i73»-. 174. 175. '77. i77»-. igo^., 197, 203, 206 »., 209, 2n, 215, 216, 219, 220, 222, 223, 223 «., 224, 225, 226, 226 »., 227, 227 »., 229, 240, 244, 246, 253. 254, 256, 263, 264, 26s, 266, 267, 275, 277, 281 ; Bank of, 223 ».; expansion of, 241; export of wool, 81 ; Jews in, 89 ; landed aristocracy in, 54 ; national unity of, 151 «.; Papal influence in, 85 English, agriculture, 218; as inven- tors and pioneers, 16, 225 ; capital, 204 «. ; colonies, 212, 216 «., 217, 218, 220, 221, 240, 241 ; in India, 221 ; manufac- tures, 199, 222, 228, 230; mari- time power, 203, 215, 218, 219; mercantile system, 215; shipping, 193, 218, 221, 226, 241, 251 Enterprise, commercial, 213, 243, 263; maritime, 109, 111, 124; Viking, 112 Environment, 268 Erfurt, 47 Ergastula, 53 , Eric, the Red, no Essay, 97 Estate, 174, 209, 219; abbey, 142; accounts of, loi; bailiff of, loi ;- Tuscan, 1^6 n.; manage- ment, 100, 139, 175 «. Eurasians, 187 Euphrates, 185 Exchange, 79, 80 ; , Bills of, 86, 176, 177; foreign, 84, 176, 187; tables, 84 «. , ; Exchequer, English, &7 Excise, 251 Explorers, 131, 227 Export trade, 81, 82, 86, 88, 231 Sxtenia, 52, loi Factories, Commercial, 63, no, 179; 189, 198; Christian among Mo- hammedans, 122, 127; German, in Baltic, 112; industrial, 232, 238, 250 Factory Inspectors, 246, 261 Fairs, 6, 6r, 84, 94, 109, 176, 178, 180, 278; at Troyes, 48; at Paris, 48 Family, as economic unit, 244, ,245 Farmer, capitalist, 210, 234; peasant, 276; small, 232, 234 Farming, the revenue, 163 Faubourg, 21 k. Fecamp, 39 Ferdinand and Isabella of Spain, 131. 151, '91 Ferrara, 128 Ferm, 87 Fife, 279 Finance, 155, 174, 253; Paj>al, &^seq., 87,. I7r, 176 Financiers, 153, 159, 169, 173, 202, 211 Firma uttius noctis, 82 Fishery, 202, 178, 197, 202, 219 Flanders, 4, 55, 66, 72, 88, 90, "9> i39> 148, 149' 165 »■. i97> 199, 202 ; clothing trades in, 39, 197; Galleys, 130 Florence, 73, 94, 94«., 99, 149, 165, 182, 202, 208 Florentines, 123, 128, 178 Florida, 212 «. Fluctuations in trade, 232, 236, 247 Food supply, 160, 213 «., 214, 231, 242, '243, 251, 255-6, 264 Foreign Exchanges, see Exchange. Forestalling, 29, 80 Fortification, military, 73, 128 «. Forth Bridge, 271 France, 4, n, 16, 22, 34, 36, 41, 55, 58, 66, 72, 73, 85«., 90, 96:«., 119, 121, 136 «., 139, ,r46, 148, 292 Index. 151. i54> 15s. i69»-> i77> 181, 197, 202, 206, 207, 208, 210, 211, 214, 215, 216, 217, 222, 223 «., 226, 227, 240, 263, 281; Isle de, 281 ; New, 212 Francis I, 207, 208 Franciscans, 121 Franks, 2, ion., 24, 25, 29, 30, 31. 32. 33. 34. 44 Prankish Empire, 23, 45, 47, 49, 91 n. ; slave-trade, 45 Frederick II, Emperor, 116 French colonial empire, 207, 212 Friars, 142, 143 Frith Gilds, 65 Fuggers, r56»., 175, 192 «., 203 Fulda, 44 ». Furs, trade in, 47, 113, 121, 201 Fustian manufacture, 211 Gama, Vasco da, 131, 183 Gascony, 88, 156 Gau, 22 n. Gaul, 12, 21, 25, 37 Gebhart, Bp, 59, 281 Geneva, 176 Genoa, 93, ^g, 121, 133, 125, 126, 128, I34»., 178, 196 Georgia, 54 ». German, 265 ; capitalists, 194 ; factories in Baltic, 112; finan- ciers, 202 ; merchants, 1 78 Germany, 4, 5«., 21, 41, sS. 66, 68, 72, 73, 98, 119, 136 «., 139, 146, 149, ISO, 151, 197, 202, 231, 263, 264, 281 Gesta, 23 Geselle, 98 Ghent, 73, 96, 197 Gilbert of Sempringham, 38 «. Gilds, 6, 63, 65, 93, 167, 195, 202 »., 233 »., 235; craft, 103, 165, 181, 182, 2i6«., 238«. ; jouirneymen, 167 n. ; masons, 98 n. ; merchant, 64, 96 n. Goa, 186, 187 Gold, 121, 131, 191, 222; ratio of to silver, 83; Cloth of, 208 Gothland, 109 Goths, 2o»., 26, 16 n., 30, 44, 173 «., 266 Governmental, initiative, 207, 214, 226; monopolies, 174, 192 Guienne, 156 Guinea Coast, 131 Gustavus Adolphus, ig8«. Granada, 130, 151, igr Great Britain, 225, 226, 228, 231, 236. 243, 259, 260 Greece, 6, 160 «., 281 Greek, city states, 75, 150, 266; colonisation, 158 Greenland, 86, no Greifswald, 112K. Grosseteste, Robt., Rules of, 100 Hadrian, i, 3 Hanse, 63 «. Hanse towns, 113, 114, 127, 156, 179, 188 »., 198, 198 «., 201 Hargreaves, 233 «. Haroun-al-Raschid, 46 Hatfield Chase, 216 Havana, 191 Helmershausen, 280 Henry I (Eng.), 95, 173 «. Henry II (Eng.), 65 ». Henry IV (Emp.), 19 Henry IV (Fr.), 147, 157, 190 «., 208, 209, 210, 211 Henry VIII (Eng.), 218 Henry, Prince, the navigator, 129, 135, 19° Heraclea, 21 «., 261, 263 Hidalgos, 195 Hilda of Whitby, 38 «. Holland, 151, 177, 180, i96fol., 209, 211, 216, 217, 225, 231 Holy Land, 108 Holy Office, 188 Household, as economic unit, 51, 54. ^> 238, 238 «. Household economy, 81, 99 seq., 278 Huguenot, 212 »., 214, 222 Humanists, 145 ». Hume, Joseph, 248 n. Hungary, 175 «. Huns, 20, 21 «., 59, 119 Index. 293 Iberian peninsula, 47, 189, 190 Iceland, 3, no, 113 Immunities, 39, 49, 50, 50 Incidence of Taxation, 76, 169 »., 452 Income-tax, 252 India, S4«., 66, 183, 187, 190, 221, 223, 229, 253, 260, 261, 265, 266, 267 Indian Ocean, 183, 184, 188, 189 Indiction, 33 Indies, East, 161, 183, 187, 196, 197, 198, 200, 200 »., 215, 221, 226; West, 54«., 131, 196, 203 Individual initiative, 216, 228, 243 Individualism, 244, 247 »., 256, ■273 Indulgences, 146 Industrial arbitration, 236; arts, 6, 7, 36; classes, 169, 174, 247! corporations, 157 ; depression, 230; revolution, 167, iSo seq., 225 seq., 233n., 238, 244, 246, ^49' 253. 263, 277 Industry, capitalist organisation of, 202, 210, 238, 254, 259; domes- tic, 250, 261 Ingenuits, 32 ». Inland Revenue, 252 Innocent III, 121 Interest on loans, 108, 176, 180, 260 Inter-municipal trade, 92, 113, 173, 226 Invention, age of, 225 fol., 232, Hi> ^53> 258, 264, 269, 270 Ireland, 3, 47, no, 253 «., 278 Irminon, Abbot, iio?2. Iron, 113, 227, 227 »., 228 Islam, 49, ii6, 118, 130 Isenbert, 98 «. Isle de France, 281 Isonzo, Battle of, 27 Jtalian bankers, 67, 86, 89, 176 Italy, 4, 27, 30, 39, 43, 47, 66, 72, 84, 90, 113, 119, 120, I2r, 126, 128, I36?»., 139, 148, 149, 150, 151, i6o»., 181, 2b8, 263, 277«., 281 Ivory, 121, 281 James I (of England), 215, 219 Japan, 15, 186, 200, 254 Java, 200 Jerusalem, 72, 126 Jews, 26«., 49, 75, 89, 143, 278 «. John the Good (King of France), John (King of England), 98 ». Jo^iah, 45 Journeyman, 96, 97, i8o; gilds, 167 n. Judaea, 268 Judices, 51, 52 Juniiiges, 39 Jumna, 47 Justinian, I2«., 30, 31, 49, 153 Kind, payments in, 82, 88, 100, I02 Kirkvirall, 4 Labour, as Christian discipline, 106; as drudgery, 35; dignity of, 35> 36 ; division of, 235 ; free flow of, 158, 246, 253; migration of, 182; of children, 233, 238- 9, 239 «., 250; of women, 233, 239, 250; organisation of, 103, 167, 248, 271; regulation of, 16, ^S7 Laffemas, 209, 210, 238, 341, 247 Lana, arte di, 94«., 165 «. Lancashire, 227 «. Landed interests, 91, 223, 252, 260 Languedoc, 90, 116, 120 Law, John, 223 «. Law, see Canon, Civil. Law merchant, 3, 91, 95, 153, 280 Law, Salic, 31 ; sumptuary, 195 Leicester, 1 10 Leo the Great, 20 Leo the Isaurian, 277 «. Levant, 108, 185, 201, 2S0 Levantine trade, 46, 50, 127, 208 Lewis of Bavaria, 142 Liguria, 28 19—3 294 indi ex. Linen manufacture, 199, ill Lisbon, 178, 188, 199, 204 ». Lisieux, Bishop of, 8i Lithuania, 3 Livre des MHiers, 96 n. Loans, 156, 169, 174 fol., idon. Locke, John, 31 »., 252 Loire, 40, 64 Lombards, 173 London, 65, 94, 95,. 98, 110, 113, '75> '79. m. 223, 226, 137, 242, 283 Louis XI, 154, 157, 207 Louis XIV, 13, 206, 214 Loiivain, 197 I-ouvre, 210 Lucrum cessans, 175-6 Ludovic and Lotliaire, 44, 45 Liibeck, 112, 113 Luther, 157 Luxury, 118, 128, 208, 217 Lyons, 22 «., 156, 172?;., 176, 180, 208, 2 10 Macchiavelli, I73«. Machinery, 14, 227 «. , 229, 232, 236,. ^47. 248, 263, 274, 277; administrative, 159, 213, 250, 261, 275, 282 Macon, 22 «. Madagascar, 200, 212 Madeiras, 131 Magdeburg, 47, 49 Majorca, 120 Afajores, 51 Malabar coast, 184 Malacca, 1 85 Malthus, 242 ». Manchester School, 248 «. Maneriiim, 10 r Marburg, 44 «• Margus, 21 n. Market, 58, 80, 94, 231, 2C0 ; colonial, 194; money-, 173, 176, 177, 180; foreign, 230, 231, 264, 265; limited, 226 Market Cross, 61 Marlborough, 95 Marseilles, 46, 123, 12O, 155 Masons, 98»., 128». Mauritius, 207 Maximum prices, 28, 45»., 194 Mayence, 21, 47, 48, 58 Medicine, 115, 119 Medicis, Marie de, 211 Mediterranean, 47, 108, 109, 114, 119, 124, 126, 130, 132, 155, 165, '87, 196, 198, 201, 272 Mercantilists, 43 »., 222, 223, 245 Mercanzia, 64 ». Mercatum legUimiiin, 61 Mercenaries, 155, 171, 172 Mercers, 94 Merchant Adventurers, 179 «. Merchant, GiId-,7« Gild Merchant, 64 Merchant, Law-, see Law Merchant, 9'. 95 Merovingian kings, 33, 36, 39, S3. Messina, 1 28 Mesta, 194 Metals, 121; precious, 11, 50, 83, 8672., 222, 223 Metayer, 209 Methuen treaty, 204 Metz, 2 1 Mexico, 191 Middlemen, 28, 50 Migration, 182, 277 Mines, 182, 192, 222, 226, 246; Commission on, 238 »., 239 «. Mining, 53, 62, 136, 192, 193, 219, 259; concessions, 156; copper, 175 ».; quicksilver, 175 n. ; silver, 1 75 n. Ministers' accounts, 53, 102 Missi, 59 Missionaries, in, 130, 270 Mississippi, 207 Mohammedan, 3, 18 «., 267/., 49, 108, 126, r34, 140, 155, 184, 188, 224 Monasteries, 35 seq., 56, 57, 58, 59, 67, 84, 100, HI, 142, 144,. 146, 147, 187 ; Agricullurtf' of, 36; artisans in, 37, 38; commer- cial and trading side of, 38-9; towns at, 58 Money, 74, 75, 78, 82, 83, 159, Index. 295 176; -aristocracy, 91; -bargaining, 259 ; -changing, 84 ; -economy, 54.74. 7S. 76. 77. 87, 89, 89«., 99. 13s. 137. 153. 'SO. 104. I0S> 167. 170, 260; -lending, 134 «., 167, 175; -market, 173, 170, 180; revenue, 75, 76 Moneyed interest, 91, 136 »., 169, 152; 260 Moneyers, 65 w. Monopoly, 127, 174, 183, 189, 200, 221, 260, 272, 277 ; Dutch, 198, 200, 203; prices, 29»., 176 Monsoon, 185 Montesquieu, 280 Montpazier, 92 Montpellier, 126, 155 Montreal, 212, 282 «. Moors, 47 Moravia, 47 Moral authority, 18, 140 Moriscos, 195 Morocco, \iseq. Teutonic Knights, in, 113 Textile trades, 14, 38 k., 116, 128, 193, 226 TheAtre df Agriculture, 209 Theism, 118 Theocracy, 118 Theodoric, 7.111., 23 fol., 41 fol. Theodosius, 31 Thessalonica, 2i«., 31 Tiberius, 34 Tillage, 37, 53, 102, 191, 193, 205, 2I9«., 234, 242, 255, 269 Tithes, 44, 86, 252 ; in Greenland, 86 Token money, 83 Toledo, 194 Tolls, 36»., 61, 91, 157, 198 «.; arbitrary, 48, 48n., see Customs. Town, as economic centre, 93 ; economic definition of, 56, 67> 72 ; survival of Roman, 60, 65 ; walls, 6i, 174; as money-lenders, 175; nuclei of, 38 k.; institutions in, 92 ; revenue of, 93 Touraine, 22 Tours, 22 Index, 299 Trade, 107; Balance of, ^^'i\ carry- ing, 178, 198, 203, 225; export, 81, 82, 86; fluctuations in, 232, 236, 247 ; intermunicipal, 92, 113; international, 221; monastic, 58; see Active, Free, Passive, Slave. Trades Unions, 245 fol., 261 Tractatus de mutatione moneiarum, 82 seq. Treasure, 11, iikk., 12, 53, ij^nn., 191, 222, 223 ; and military power, 1 1 n. Treaty, commercial, 122, 201, 206 n. Trent, 109; Council of, 144 Treves, 21 Tribute, 120, rSg, 271; concessions of, 186; in kind, 82 Tripoli, 124 Trondhjem, 4 Tropics, 207 Troyes, 20, 48 Truce of God, 144 Tunis, 123, 124 Tuscany, 136 »., 281 Tyre, 17, 126 Tyrol, 17s «. Umiliati, 165 n. Undertakers, 193 Unit, economic, city as, 99, 244, 245 ; family as, 244-5 ; house- hold as. Si, 54, 54 K., ^% loi, 235 «.; nation as, 157; 244-5 United Provinces, 196, 198, 199, 205, 221 United States, 42 «., 231, 242, 260, 263, 264 Universal Exhibitions, 263 Upsala, 4 Usurers, 83, 91, 167, 260 «. Usury, 45«., 153, 167, 168 Utilitas, 43, 43 n. Valenciennes, 96 Valladolid, 194 Value, 78, 79 Vandals, 29, 30 Venetia, 28 Venetian galleys, 187 ; shipping, 201 Venetians, 123, 126, 127, 130, 178, 183, 184, 186 Venezuela, 175 «. Venice, 73, 90, 93, 99, 125, 127, 128, 129, 179, 208 Ventures, 175 «. Versailles, 27, 81, 206 Vienne, 20 «. Vikings, \oi seq., 112, 132, 280 Villa, 6, 37, 52, 57, 100 Villein, loi, 135, 166 Villes-de-bourgeoisie, 92 Virginia, 217 Visigoths, 30 Voyages, coasting, 185 ; ocean, 178; of discovery, 183 Wages, 81 «., 97, i66, 280; assess- ment of, 237, 247; competition rate, 102, 232; starvation-, 237; standard, 247 «. Wakefield, E. G., 240 Wales, 73 Walter of Henley, Husbandry, 100 War, American Civil, 231 ; English Civil, 215; Hundred Years', 129, 139, 146, 154, 208; Napoleonic, 233, 263; of Dutch Independ- ence, 199, 208, 244; sinews of, 173, 222 Waterford, no Waterloo, 230 «. Water-power, 233 n. ; -supply, 245 Watt, J., 227 Weavers, 65, 95, 230 «., 232, 237, 240, 250; 'illegal,' 237; York- shire, 163 «. Weights and measures, 50 Welsers, 175 West Indies, 54 «. West of England, lion., ^37 West Virginia, 54 ^A Whaling, /202 \ Whitby, Hilda^of, 3|8«. William ^the Conqueror, '5^,' 88, 100, 130 I ( I ' I I I I William of Occam, 142, 143 Wills, 141 ' , ' 300 Winchester, 31 ««■ Wine, 39, 88, 121 Wisby, 112, lU"- Wismar, 112 «. Wit, John de, 204 Worcester, 182 Worms, 21 Ximenes, 13S Index. Yam, cotton-, 231, 236 Yeoman farmer, 234, 235 York, 21 »., 182 Yorkshire, 163 «., 227 »•> 230 «., 232, 238 Zamorin of Calicut, 183 Zeelanders, 188 «. Zeno, 29 »• PRJNfED IN ENGLAND BY J. B. PEACE, M.A. AT THE CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS :ii!';ii!Ja:!!'rii|!i!!!i!iiiiii;i!!| ■