C ܕܡܝܐ ܐ Jo ܚ ܠܐ ܝܐ ܢ ܐ ܝܐ ܪܝ BLA ……….. MATEU Y Ex Libris Thomas Spencer Jerome DF 277 8669 E5 1828 THE PUBLIC ECONOMY OF ATHENS. THE PUBLIC ECONOMY OF ATHENS, IN FOUR BOOKS; To which is added, A DISSERTATION ON THE SILVER-MINES OF LAURION. TRANSLATED FROM THE GERMAN OF AUGUSTUS BOECKH. VOL. I. LONDON, JOHN MURRAY. 1828. BAXTER, PRINTER, OXFORD. 3 THEN THE CENTER REAL E * 1439 w! R ง THE TRANSLATOR'S PREFACE. THE Staatshaushaltung der Athener, of which a translation is now offered to the public, was pub- lished at Berlin in the year 1817. It is preceded by a dedication to Niebuhr, the author of the Roman History, and a short preface, in which Mr. Boeckh, after stating that the knowledge of the ancient history of Greece is still in its infancy, and lamenting that it has so often fallen into the hands of mere compilers or verbal grammarians, considers that it is impossible to gain a complete knowledge of the whole subject before some sub- ordinate departments have been fully investigated. The following work he intends to be a contribution of this nature upon a subject of ancient history little understood. If," he continues, “it should appear to many that the length of this work is incommensurate with the importance of its object, 66 278593 vi the author is comforted by the consciousness of having aimed at brevity as much as clearness of style would permit, and he is afraid of having erred rather on the side of conciseness, thus frequently creating harsh and abrupt transitions, than on that of prolixity." After a few other remarks he pro- ceeds to speak of some inscriptions, on which it is necessary for the translator to say a few words. The latter half of the second volume of the original edition of his book is occupied by an Ap- pendix, which contains twenty-nine Greek inscrip- tions, illustrating the subjects treated of in the body of the work. They are accompanied by a most ample commentary; and some of them were, upon the appearance of the original work (in 1817), published for the first time. In this translation these are omitted, and for the following reasons. In the first place, the author has now undertaken to publish a complete collection of ancient Greek inscriptions, in which edition those which he had formerly published will all be necessarily included. Whatever therefore was most important in his former explanations he has repeated, with such vii improvements or additions as the subsequent en- quiries of himself or others may have suggested. Secondly, at the time when this work was pub- lished, the author was compelled to have recourse to incorrect transcripts made by Fourmont and others, of inscriptions which are now preserved in the British Museum, and have lately been copied with greater accuracy. These reasons have induced the translator to avoid increasing the bulk of this work with dissertations on subjects which, even by the professed classical reader, are frequently thought of secondary importance. It now becomes necessary to say something of the translator's share in the labour. The style of a translation necessarily depends in a great degree both on the similarity or dissimilarity in the idioms of the two languages, and on the style of the original work. Now it is a singular, but an un- questionable fact, that the idioms of the German and English languages are altogether different, and seldom admit of literal rendering from one to the other¹; a difficulty which in the present instance ¹ Madame de Stael (Allemagne tom. I. p. 194.) indeed says, "Les langues Teutoniques se traduisent facilement entre viii has been much aggravated by the many peculiari- ties in the author's style, little suited to the taste of English readers. To this if we add, the frequent want of proper terms in English for peculiar insti- tutions and usages among the Greeks²; an obstacle which the author could easily overcome in his own language by coining compound words, faciliore ad duplicanda verba Germano sermone; and also the elles; il en est de même des langues Latines;" but no one who ever attempted to render German into English can doubt of the truth of what is asserted in the text. The structure of the sentences and collocation of the words are entirely dif- ferent. The idiom of French is much nearer that of English, whatever may be said of the Latin and Teutonic lan- guages. 2 The original word has frequently been retained for the sake of avoiding ambiguity or periphrasis. Thus Atimia, Di- casts, Hoplita, Cleruchia, &c. It is true of most terms such as these just mentioned, what has been justly observed of words signifying public offices, that "although the relation denoted by them be the same in one or several important particulars, yet it scarcely ever holds throughout; and the most false notions are in consequence entertained by people of the nature of these corresponding offices in every country but their own." The term Liturgy has been used in a sense wholly different from its received acceptation; but the original word is the same; as λurovgyía, which originally signified a service for the public (as igovgyía in Herod. V 83. a sacred service), after- wards came to mean a service in a church. ix unconnected appearance of a narrative compiled of various facts, and from various authorities; these grounds may perhaps justify the translator's hopes that some of those imperfections of style may be overlooked, which it was so difficult for him to avoid. 3 In the third book the author, in speaking of the tenure of land in Attica, has occasion to quote a proposal or advertisement of a lease, from the ori- ginal document engraved on stone and still extant. The inscription is given in the Appendix from a very incorrect transcript made by Chandler, several of whose errors are there rectified. It has since been published in a more correct form by our author in his collection of inscriptions; but as the copy which he has used is in many parts very defective, there still remained some difficulties which he could not overcome. As the inscription is pre- served in the British Museum, the translator has made a more accurate copy of it, and taken the liberty of arranging the version in the text partly according to the latest improvements of the author 3 Vol. II. p. 15. see p. 223. X himself, partly according to what appeared on the inspection of the stone to admit of no doubt. In one or two instances the author has, in his later work, seen reason for modifying his first opinions these corrections have been inserted in the notes at their proper places. The author however had not (as far as the trans- lator is aware) been called upon to retract or defend his opinions upon any point of importance, before the publication of his work on inscriptions. The first number of this collection was reviewed by Pro- fessor Hermann, in a manner which called forth a reply from Professor Boeckh. This reply was an- swered by Mr. Hermann; which answer was in its turn examined (together with the original re- view) by Mr. Meier, one of the authors of the Attische Process. All these several documents were republished by Mr. Hermann in one volume¹, with a preface and notes and two appendixes; of which the second is on the subject of the Logistæ and Euthuni, the nature of whose offices is one of the Ueber Herrn Professor Böckhs Behandlung der Griech- ischen Inschriften von Gottfried Hermann. Leipsig 1826. - xi points in contest between these two professors. This last Essay contains a criticism upon our author's discussion of the subject in the present work; and as it arrives at conclusions diametrically opposed to the account there given, the translator thought that the importance of these officers in the Athenian government might excite the curiosity of some English readers, and had actually prepared a trans- lation of Mr. Hermann's treatise. But as the au- thor has since replied at great length in a literary journal, and appears to have successfully defended his former positions, it has been thought preferable to abstain altogether from the controversy. The translator has entered at all into this explanation, only lest he should be thought to have neglected a subject so much connected with the present work. The Dissertation upon the Silver-Mines of Lau- rion, of which a translation is given in the second volume, was published separately by Mr. Boeckh in the Memoirs of the Berlin Academy. It is fre- quently referred to in the notes to his chief work; The Rheinisches Museum, vol. I. • See however book II. note 179. P. 39-107. xii and, notwithstanding the abridgment given in the third book', may be considered as an interesting, if not necessary, addition to this work. He appears to have satisfactorily established his main point, that the mines were public property, and that the tenures upon which they were held was a perpetual lease under certain conditions (including the pay- ment of a rent of a twenty-fourth part of the gross produce), which was originally obtained by purchase. The price therefore of the shares or pits, which varied according to the state of the market, made up for the apparently small rent which was subsequently paid. By the oversight of this circumstance Mr. Mitford is led to accuse the Athenian State of neglect in the administration of its finances. Of all charges, perhaps, the govern- 7 Vol. II. p. 18. This may be a convenient place for mentioning that the term Fee-farm (Erbpacht), which occurs frequently in the present translation, is used only to mean a lease in perpetuity held upon certain conditions; without any farther notion or limitations which may be annexed to it in the language of modern lawyers. 9 History of Greece, vol. V. p. 15. The account given in Walpole's Memoirs relating to European Turkey p. 444. is however quite correct. xiii } ment of Athens is least open to that of a want of diligence in exacting the utmost amount of revenue which its legitimate resources could be made to afford. It is often the unpleasant duty of a translator to give currency to some opinions in which he does not concur, or which he may more strongly disap- prove; for it can rarely happen, however great may be our admiration of any work, that we can assent to all the doctrines which it contains. Unhappily the present book furnishes a forcible example of this mixture of objectionable with useful matter. It is much to be lamented that the author of this work, a man profoundly skilled in Grecian antiqui- ties, and possessing very considerable powers of reasoning and discrimination, should not have added to these rich endowments a more ample portion of modern science: and that in his remarks and dis- cussions he should exhibit few traces of those improvements in political philosophy which later ages have produced. With the exception indeed of some unimportant observations on a fanciful theory of Rousseau, and a few remarks suggested by striking peculiarities in the ancient institutions, xiv there is scarcely any thing which a well-educated Gre- cian of the time of Aristotle might not have written 10; if we exclude those singular doctrines for the disse- mination of which the world has since been chiefly indebted to the mercantile system of commerce. From the title of our author's work, it would be natural to infer that he was well versed in that science of which his subject forms a subordinate department. A very few pages are however suffi- cient to convince the reader that such is not the case. Thus, almost at the very outset of his work, we find him employing as convertible terms, wealth, money, and the precious metals", having previously 10 Otfried Müller (Orchomenos und die Minyer p. 13.) in a review of the modern works on Grecian history gives the following character of the present book. "Was eine Atthis seyn würde, nach Art der alten Atthidenschriftsteller, die das Bedeutendste von dem, was wir politische und heilige Anti- quitäten nennen, als wesentlichen Theil der Geschichte behan- delten, und mit neuerweiterter Ansicht und Gelehrsamkeitsfülle ausgeführt, muss auch blöden Augen, an der Staatsöconomie Athens, neuerlich zum erstenmal klar geworden seyn." Con- cerning the newly extended views to be found in Mr. Boeckh's work, the English reader will form his own opinion: but as to the profusion of learning displayed in it, it is satisfactory to have the testimony of one of the most learned writers in (what is unquestionably) the most learned country of Europe. "It is perhaps to the author's opinion that these three terms XV mistaken the efficacy of money for that of which it is the medium. Occasionally also he appears to be led to false conclusions by using the words profit and interest as synonymous 12; and in one place there is a serious argument to prove that the rent of land is regulated by the rate of interest ¹³. The 13 are synonymous that we are indebted for his laborious enume- ration of all the places of Greece in which the precious metals were found, and perhaps for his excellent Dissertation on the Attic Silver-mines, in the beginning of which he appears to attribute to them an importance and an influence on the pros- perity of Attica, which they did not in fact possess. See also vol. I. p. 17. and vol. 17. and vol. II. p. 192. 12 See vol. I. p. 65, 82, 147, 154. See also his bitter invective against the Athenian bankers and money lenders, whom he calls "the most infamous of human beings" (p. 171); though in the preceding page he highly praises their honesty. He also retails, with seeming approbation, the vulgar declamation of Lysias against the corn dealers (p. 112). See also vol. I. p. 139. and, above all, his remarks on the enlightened proposal of Xenophon for a more liberal conduct towards the aliens of Attica, vol. II. p. 398, 399. 13 Vol. I. p. 168. Sometimes the inconclusiveness of his reasoning depends upon an ambiguity of terms which disap- pears in translating. Thus a German word for rent of land is Landzins, literally land-interest; hence an incitement to a con- fusion of things really distinct in their nature. This word Zins is used in German to signify, interest, profit, rent of land, rent of houses, and tribute. The analogy between the interest xvi translator has thought it his duty to state thus plainly what must of necessity detract in some mea- sure from the value of the present work: it should however, in justice to its author, be observed, that such imperfections may more easily be overlooked in a person who has made another branch of learn- ing his peculiar study. And, while we see the appli- cation of the true principles of political economy to things under our own eyes and in our own country so frequently controverted, how much more difficult is it when we have to deal with ages long past, and facts either doubtful or incompletely known! • Unfortunately however the author's imperfect acquaintance with the general science of these matters has not only diminished the value of some of his arguments, but has also had a marked effect upon the distribution of his materials. This is more particularly seen in the parts where he had not, as in treating of the officers concerned in the manage- ment of the revenue, or the several items of the public income and expenditure, an obvious course of reasoning to follow. Accordingly in his discussions of money and revenue in general is a copious source of fallacy to our author. xvii on prices, rates of profits, interest, &c., his diligence has scarcely compensated for the want of theoretical knowledge; and the value of his first book, either considered by itself, or as a groundwork for his sub- sequent enquiries, has thus been much diminished. A large part of the first book is dedicated to an enumeration of the various prices of commo- dities in Attica", by comparing which with the actual prices of the same commodities, the au- thor hopes to ascertain the relative wealth of Attica and modern nations. Now although this collection is most interesting and valuable, it is evident that he has much overrated its utility, and has committed a great though natural error in supposing that any inference can be drawn from the similarity or dissimilarity of ancient and modern prices. The ratio between the value of any one commodity, and of gold or silver, may be a safe criterion in the same place, and for short periods of time; but for distant ages and countries this com- parison affords absolutely no information. For a comparison with prices in other countries at the VOL. I. 14 Vol. I. p. 83–147. b xviii same time, and for such a purpose as that to which the author has well applied it, in examining the authority of Polybius' statement with respect to the valuation of Attica, his list of prices may be used with advantage and security. But whether the precious metals, or labour, or any other standard, be adopted as a medium of comparison between the prices of commodities in ancient Greece and in modern Europe, the result must be equally fallacious and nugatory. For these reasons the translator has omitted to insert, as the author had done, the cor- responding value of silver estimated in modern coin after each statement of price 15. In the same book the author has likewise devoted a separate chapter16 to the consideration of the vaUTI- xòç тóxos or interest of money lent on bottomry: and on account of the large portion of Athenian capital which was thus employed in foreign commerce, this question is of considerable importance. From the instances cited by him, it appears that a very high premium was not unfrequently obtained upon capital 15 See also vol. I. p. 383. and p. 337. 16 Vol. I. p. 176. xix thus invested. But it is evident that no general conclusion with regard to the rate of interest can be drawn from these facts (vol. I. p. 81.); for this was doubtless a most hazardous investment for money, on account of the imperfect knowledge which the ancients possessed of astronomy, from their igno- rance of the compass, and the dangerous navigation of the narrow and stormy seas of Greece, as well as from the insecurity of laws and judicatures, demon- strated by the very institutions themselves which were meant as correctives of that evil 17. It has been already mentioned that the author frequently draws unwarrantable conclusions from the rate of interest. It may however be fairly doubted, whether, if the "rate of interest is that sum which the lender receives and the borrower pays for the use of a certain amount of monied capital, without any consideration for trouble in the collection of the income, or for risk as to the punctual repayment of the interest or principal at the stipulated periods 18," there was any thing which > 17 See what the author himself says, vol. I. p. 179. 19 Tooke's Considerations on the Currency p. 11. XX ! we could justly consider as a general or established rate of interest at Athens. There were no public securities nor means of investing money guaranteed by the national credit; and the insecurity of pro- perty, both from fear of revolution and foreign attack, must always have been so great, that it is difficult to think of any method of lending money in which there must not have been as to the punctual repayment of the interest or principal at the stipulated periods very great, but very vari- able, risks. With respect to money lent upon mortgage, which with us approaches next in safety to the public securities, the land in Attica was held upon so frail a tenure, on account of the liability to loss from invasion, that in this case again, a large yet uncertain indemnification for risk must have been requisite. In illustration of this it may be mentioned, that in a lease of some lands situated within a few miles of Athens, made 345 B. C., there is an express stipulation inserted with regard to the payment of the rent in case of injury from enemies 19 19 Boeckh. Corp. Inscript. No. 93. C xxi Since Mr. Boeckh's work has appeared the Popula- tion of Attica has been examined by Mr. Fynes Clin- ton in the Appendix to his Fasti Hellenici 20; by Mr. Letronne in the Mémoires de l'Académie des Belles Lettres 21; and in part by a writer in the Museum Criticum". The first of these writers coincides very nearly with Mr. Boeckh, although he does not appear to have been acquainted with his disserta- tion; on the two last as their results are somewhat different, the translator thinks it right to offer a few remarks. Mr. Letronne estimates the population of Attica, between 430 and 340 B. C. as follows: Athenians of all ages and both sexes 70,000 Resident aliens of all ages and both sexes. 40,000 Slaves of all ages and both sexes 110,000 By comparing this table with the results of Mr. Boeckh (vol. I. p. 52.), it will be seen that, al- though Mr. Letronne has made the number of the 20 P. 387 sq. ed. 2. 21 Tom. VI. 22 I. p. 215. xxii Athenians and resident aliens lower, the chief differ- ence is in the slaves, whose number is taken by Mr. Boeckh at 365,000. The manner in which he arrives at this conclusion is somewhat singular. In the first place he assumes that the number of the slaves ascertained by the census of Demetrius, which has been preserved by Athenæus, must be exaggerated. He then turns for some more authentic account to the Athenian writers: and he conceives that the true number may be discovered from a proposal of Xenophon, in his Essay on the Revenues, "that the State should purchase slaves, until there were three to each Athenian (i. e. 60,000);" the meaning of which is (he states) that the number to be bought, together with the slaves already in the country, would make up the ratio of three to one, "la quantité à acheter, jointe à celle qui existait dans le pays, doit compléter le rapport de trois à un dont il parle" (p. 195). This he collects from an expression which Xenophon afterwards uses, "that when the number of the slaves should have been raised to 10,000, the annual revenue obtained by letting them would be 100 talents." Hence he supposes that the utmost number intended by Xe- nophon was 10,000; and that the other 50,000 xxiii are male slaves in the vigour of body 25. This number he doubles for the old-men, women, and children; and he therefore fixes the total aggregate of slaves at 110,000 or 120,000. The meaning of this passage, which Mr. Letronne seems to have misunderstood, is explained in the present work; but it may be convenient to point out the error in his argument at once. Xenophon proposed to the State of Athens to purchase public slaves 24, until about 60,000 were procured; and that they should be let at a certain rate to private mine-proprietors, for the sake of producing a reve- nue to the community; that 1200 should be first ob- tained, and by applying the profit derived from these 23 These 60,000 able-bodied male slaves he disposes of in the following manner (p. 209) Slaves in the mines in the city and its outskirts in the country 12,000 36,000 12,000 In the fragment of Hyperides quoted by Mr. Clinton (p. 391.) from Suidas in v. åznqiraro, it is stated that the number of slaves in the mines and in the country was 150,000. 24 a Xenoph. de Vectig. 4.17. οὕτω καὶ ἡ πόλις κτῷτο δημόσια ἀνδράποδα. xxiv to the purchase of fresh slaves, the number might in five or six years be raised to 6000, who would yield an income of 60 talents a year, to be employed partly in the same manner; and when there were as many as 10,000, the annual receipts would be 100 talents; "but that the mines would afford em- ployment for many times this number, is evident from the large sums produced by the duty on slaves before the occupation of Decelea;" and he adds other reasons to shew that the mines could not be overstocked with labourers. As the argument, founded on the misapprehension here exposed, is made by Mr. Letronne the basis of his calculation, it would be unnecessary to add another word. The object of the writer in the Museum Criticum is to ascertain the number of persons dwelling in the city of Athens alone; and he arrives at a result very different from that obtained by Mr. Boeckh, who, by estimating eighteen persons to a house, reckons that the city of Athens with the harbours contained 180,000 persons 25. He argues as fol- lows. 25 Vol. I. p. 56. J XXV It is known from Demosthenes that half the annual importation of corn into Attica amounted to 400,000 medimni, and from Aristotle that two- thirds of all imported corn (i. e. in this case 533,333 medimni) were by law to be carried into the city. Then taking the consumption of a man at a choenix a day, and that of women, children, and slaves at two-thirds of a choenix 26, we have 91,428 for the inhabitants of Athens. This, he observes, is a very rough calculation, but he thinks that it is likely to come within 10,000 of the real number. Now it is manifest that this calculation proceeds upon two assumptions: first, that all the foreign 26 Mr. Clinton (Fast. Hell. p. 393. ed. 2.) has however shewn that two-thirds is too small a portion, and that twelve- thirteenths is more correct. He also observes that "the author (in the Museum Criticum) has assumed that the inha- bitants of Athens were exclusively subsisted upon foreign corn;" and shews upon another consideration that the country probably furnished 980,000 medimni to the town. This argu- ment is liable to the additional objection that it supposes the inhabitants of the country to be at the same time importers and exporters of corn. Mr. Böckh conceives, apparently with good reason, that slaves severally consumed a larger quan- tity of bread than freemen, see vol. I. p. 37. xxvi corn carried into the city was consumed there; and, secondly, that none but foreign corn was con- sumed in the city. These propositions cannot ap- parently be true, unless we suppose that Attica pro- duced a quantity of corn exactly sufficient, with the addition of a third part of the importation, for the consumption of the dwellers in the country: for it cannot be thought that the inhabitants of the country would send corn to the capital (nearly a seaport town), while they were themselves subsisting on foreign corn. Now it appears that it was not an un- common practice to send barley at least into Athens from the country 27, a fact which seems utterly inconsistent with the above-mentioned regulation, which we have on the unquestionable authority of Aristotle. Then again it is impossible to suppose that the seasons were so regular in Attica (to say nothing of invasion) that the amount of corn re- quired in the country was invariably a third part of the total importation. The difficulty seems how- ever to admit of explanation. M 27 See vol. II. p. 38. notes 87 and 88. The article chosen by the honey-smuggler for the purpose of concealment is barley. xxvii JA The meaning of the regulation with regard to the two-thirds 28 appears to be, as our author has ex- plained it, that the harbour-masters (ἐπιμεληταὶ τοῦ ἐμπορίου) were to compel all merchants touching at the Piraeus with corn on board to sell two-thirds of their cargo in Attica, not in Athens as opposed to the country. Now Demosthenes only states the amount actually imported, which therefore is independant of the third of the cargo of such merchants as wished not to sell the whole; that remaining part being carried away to other countries. It is therefore unnecessary to attribute this absurd regu- lation to the Athenians; which, if its nature had been as is assumed by the writer in the Museum Criticum, could never have been put in practice; and even if it admitted of no satisfactory explanation, 28 It is given by Harpocration apparently in the words of Aristotle:᾿Επιμελητὴς ἐμπορίου.---᾿Αριστοτέλης· Εμπορίου δ᾽ ἐπιμελητὰς δέκα κληροῦσιν, τούτοις δὲ προστέτακται τῶν τε ἐμπορίων ἐπιμελεῖσθαι, καὶ τοῦ σίτου τοῦ καταπλέοντος εἰς τὸ ᾿Αττικὸν ἐμπόριον τὰ δύο μέρη τοὺς ἐμπόρους ἀναγκάζειν εἰς τὸ ἄστυ κομίζειν. Also Suidas: Επιμεληταὶ ἐχειροτονοῦντο τῶν χορῶν ὡς μὴ ἀτακτεῖν τοὺς χορευτὰς ἐν τοῖς θεάτροις. ἄλλοι δὲ λέγουσιν ὅτι ἐμπορίου ἄρχοντες εἰσὶ κληρωτοὶ ἑκάστου ἔτους καθιστάμενοι, οἷς προσετέτακτο ἐπιμελεῖσθαι τοῦ καταπλέοντος σίτου εἰς τὸ ἐμπόριον τὸ ᾿Αττικὸν καὶ τοὺς ἐμπόρους ἀναγκάζειν εἰς τὸ ἄστυ κομίζειν. Hence both in the method of their nomination, and the duration of their office, these were strictly democratical magistrates. xxviii ought not to be made the condition of a problem which requires it not merely to have been a form of words, but a law constantly enforced and acted upon 29. In making the foregoing observations, the trans- lator is aware that he may be accused of outstepping his legitimate province, and of passing judgment upon opinions which he should only have been the instrument of conveying. On the whole work, it might perhaps be ascribed to the supposed partiality of a translator, if he were to express as favourable an opinion as he really entertains. He cannot however avoid remarking, that the author has collected and arranged an immense mass of in- formation on a most interesting subject; that he has spared neither time nor research; and that 29 There is also another reason against supposing that the regulation with regard to the two-thirds had the meaning given to it by the writer in the Museum Criticum, viz. that all the corn imported into the Piraeus must, before it went into the country, have passed through the city. Now there was no inlet by which much corn passed into Attica, except Oropus and the Piraeus. The former was chiefly, if not ex- clusively, used for the Eubœan corn; and we know from Demosthenes, that at least half of the quantity imported must have been unshipped in the Piraeus. xxix whatever reason the reader may sometimes see to question his opinions on these very doubtful and disputable subjects, his accuracy in citation and the good faith of his statements are implicitly to be relied upon. In gratitude then for so great toil and learning, the reader must overlook his occasional errors, and forgive the omissions and defects in the remembrance of what has been well and laboriously done---Τοῖς μὲν παραλελειμμένοις συγγνώμην τοῖς δὲ πεπραγμένοις πολλὴν χάριν ἔχειν. For himself the translator asks no other praise than that of a sincere and earnest desire for the promotion and diffusion of knowledge on these in- teresting subjects 30. ( SINGID 30 The translator has not attempted to follow any uniform system of orthography for Greek names; it seems indeed that the forms Solon and Plato, Samos and Cræsus, are as much established by custom in our language, as those of any words not in constant use. THE PUBLIC ECONOMY OF ATHENS. CONTENTS. BOOK I. Of prices, wages, and interest of money in Attica. 1. Introduction. 2. Contents of this Book. Gold and silver the standard of prices. 3. Gradual increase of the precious metals. 4. Of silver money, and of the silver talent in particular. 5. Of gold coins, and the gold talent. 6. The price of gold and other metals in comparison with silver. 7. Population of Attica. 8. Agriculture and native products. 9. Commerce. 10. Cheapness in ancient times. 11. Lands. Mines. 12. Houses. 13. Slaves. 14. Cattle. 15. Corn and Bread. 16. Wine, oil, salt, wood. 17. Meals; obsonium: meat, birds, fish, vegetables, honey, &c. 18. Clothes, shoes, ointment. 19. Implements and furniture of various kinds, arms, ships. 20. What sum was necessary for the maintenance of life, and proportion of the same to the national wealth. 21. Wages of labour. 64 22. Interest of money; money-changers; mortgage of land. 23. Bottomry. 24. Rent of houses, land, &c. VOL. I. B 2 BOOK II. On the administration of finance, and the public expenditure. 1. Whether the system of finance in the ancient states had the same importance as in modern times. 2. Objects of my enquiries. 3. Supreme authorities for the financial legislation and ad- ministration. People and Senate. Preparatory offices. of finance. 4. Apodectæ. 5. Treasurers of the Goddess and of the other Gods. 6. Manager of the public revenue, or treasurer of the admin istration. Subordinate offices for the administration. 7. Hellenotamiæ, funds for war, funds for the Theorica. 8. Clerks, checking-clerks. System of examining the ac- counts. 9. Whether a regular estimate and comparison of the Revenue and Expenditure existed. On the different branches of Expenditure. 10. Building. 11. Police: Scythians. 12. Celebration of festivals and sacrifices. 13. Donations to the people. 14. Pay of the public assembly and of the senate. 15. Pay of the courts of justice. 16. On some other persons receiving salaries from the public. 17. Maintenance for the poor. 18. Public rewards. 19. Arms, ships, cavalry. 20. Approximate estimate of the regular Expenditure. Of the extraordinary expences in general. 21. Military force of the Athenians. 22. Pay and provision. 23. Equipment of the fleet, and artillery. Sieges. 24. Calculation of the war-expenditure, with examples. L 3 BOOK III, On the regular revenues of the Athenian state. W 1. Different kinds of public revenues in the Grecian re- publics. 2. Duties arising from lands, houses, and similar property of the state, of companies, and temples. 3. Of mines. 4. Of custom-duties; the fiftieth. 5. Conjectures upon harbour-duties and the hundredths. Market tolls. 6. Twentieths. Tithes: Different sorts of the latter. 7. Poll-taxes, and taxes upon industry: Protection-money, Tax upon slaves, Tax upon prostitutes, &c. 8. General remarks upon these taxes, particularly upon the · method of levying and paying them. 9. Fees in the courts of justice, and fines. Prytaneia, Pa- rastasis. 10. Appeal-money; Paracatabole; Epobelia. 11. Of the fines (Tara) in general. 12. Examples of the different fines. 13. Of the public debtors. 14. Of the confiscation of property. 15. Tributes of the allies. Origin of the same, and of the relation which the allies bore to Athens. Amount of the tributes before the Anarchy. 16. General survey of the allies with reference to the tribute before the Anarchy. 17. Of the tributes and the allies after the Anarchy. 18. Of the Cleruchiæ. 19. Total amount of the annual Revenue. 20. History of the public Treasure. 21. Of the Liturgies in general, and of the regular ones in par- ticular. 22. Choregia. 23. Gymnasiarchy. Feasting of the Tribes or Hestiasis. 1 4 BOOK IV. Of the extraordinary revenyes of the Athenian state, and the peculiar financial measures of the Greeks. 1. Contents of this Book. Of the property taxes in ge- neral. → 2. Of the sources of prosperity in Attica, and of the public care for the same. 3. Individual instances of the property of Athenian citizens, and of the division of the national wealth among the different classes. 4. Nearer determination of the national wealth of Attica. 5. Of the Valuation. Ancient constitution with reference to the finances. Valuation of Solon, and the changes in it before the Archonship of Nausinicus. 6. Register. Register of lands; General register of pro- perty. 7. Valuation in the Archonship of Nausinicus. 8. What part of the valuation and of the property was raised as an extraordinary tax, with reference to the pro-- perty tax in the year of Nausinicus. 9. Symmoriæ of the property taxes after the year of Nausi- nicus. Of the advance of taxes, and of other things relating to the payment of taxes. 10. Of the taxes and Liturgies of the Resident Aliens. 11. Of the Trierarchy in general. 12. First form of the Trierarchy, or the Trierarchy of Indi- viduals. Second form of the Trierarchy, or the Trie- rarchy in part of Individuals and in part of two Syn- trierarchs, from Olymp. 92. 1. until Olymp. 105. 3. 13. Third form of the Trierarchy. Syntelia and Symmoriæ from Olymp. 105. 4. until the end of the 109th Olym- piad. rarchy. 16. Of the Exchange. Gay 14. Fourth form. Trierarchy according to the valuation by the law of Demosthenes after Olymp. 110. 4. 15. General observations upon the expences of the Trie- 1 5 17. Pecuniary difficulties, Subsidies, Plunder, Captures, forced and voluntary Contributions. 18. Loans. 19. Alterations in the currency. 20. Various other measures. 21. Xenophon's proposals for the advancement of the pros- perity of Athens. 22. Conclusion. A Dissertation on the Silver-mines of Laurion. Index. THE PUBLIC ECONOMY OF ATHENS. BOOK I. (1.) IF the character and importance of a nation were to be estimated only by the extent of its territory and population, the Athenian state would rank far below the hordes of the Huns and Mongols. But mere space and numbers are of little avail, without the presence of that spirit, by which alone the great body of a people can be animated and com- bined. To the operation of this cause must the superiority of the Athenians be ascribed; by this power their scanty bands overthrew the countless hosts of the Barbarians at Marathon, at Salamis, and at Platææ: and hundreds of subject states submitted to the dominion of one small city, as large armies obey the commands of one general. Not that Athens, while thus signalizing herself in the field, was regardless of the more beneficial pursuits of peace: and having conceived and executed all that was most beautiful in art and profound in philosophy, she became the in- structress of all liberal sciences and arts; the teacher alike of her own times and of posterity. The intellectual fa- culties however are not of themselves sufficient: to pro- duce external action they require the aid of physical force, the direction and combination of which are wholly at the disposal of money; that mighty spring by which 8 the whole machinery of human energies is set in mo- tion. For a state, and for a family, a regular and settled economy are alike necessary; and as the relations be- tween the state and its members have in great measure a mutual dependence upon the regulations of the public eco- nomy, so it becomes impossible to obtain a correct insight into the private life of the ancients, without a knowledge of their finances; nor of their financial system, without a minute enquiry into the internal organization of both their public and private economy. For these reasons I have undertaken to explain, as fully as my abilities and extent of knowledge will permit, the Public Economy of Athens, the greatest and most noble among the Grecian states. In the prosecution of these enquiries, truth has been my only aim; nor shall I regret, if it be made apparent from my labours, that the ancients as well as the moderns were not free from stain in their pecuniary dealings. Or are the histories of past ages to be written merely for the inspira- tion of youth; and shall the historian of antiquity conceal, that in those as well as the present days, nothing among men was perfect? Let us confess rather, that of the most excellent men of antiquity, many laboured under the fail- ings common to the human race; that in their less polished nature these vices broke out so much the more powerfully, as their hearts were less awakened to piety by the mildness and humility of a more benevolent religion; that, lastly, these faults (so long encouraged and cherished) under- mined and overthrew the lordly edifice of antiquity itself. Of the vast range of topics which here come under con- sideration, few have hitherto been subjected to a compre- hensive and accurate scrutiny. General views and ingenious speculations do not supply the place of sound investigation ; and the more scanty are our sources of information, the 9 more urgent becomes the obligation to use the materials faithfully, and from them to deduce general conclusions equally removed from flippant and vague superficiality on the one hand, and the affectation of learning on the other, which adorns itself with the specious tinsel of critical and grammatical display. Every other method either leaves the reader (as is the custom with most writers on ancient history) to wander among innumerable and almost isolated particulars, in appearance only connected together; or leads him into errors, which captivate and bias the judgment by their apparent beauty. Thus, for example, it has been attempted to account for the indifference of the ancients to productive labour and their inattention to matters of finance, by the dominion of religion over their minds; but (not to mention that piety accords better with a well than an ill regulated economy) the supposition itself is false; for neither do we find that the ancient states attached less importance to the public income and expen- diture, than is attributed to them at the present day; nor that individuals had a greater disregard for worldly pos- sessions. If the system of finance in the Grecian states was ill regulated, the defect must be assigned to other causes, which are to be sought for in their civil in- stitutions. With regard to the science of Political Eco- nomy, it was, I admit, uncultivated among the ancients: its relations were too simple to be made the subjects of a scientific analysis; for the ancients until the time of Aristotle (and he also in some degree), treated the sciences under very general heads, without allotting a par- ticular science to each separate department of practical life. For this reason, Aristotle in his Politics speaks both of Education and Finance, but only as incidental and subordi- nate topics in the Economics falsely attributed to this 10 philosopher, Political Economy is treated of scientifically, and in the manner of Aristotle, but briefly and imperfectly. Plato's work upon the Republic contains indeed nothing of a system of finance; for in such ideal states as that of Plato, a well regulated Economy was no more requisite than an explicit Code of Laws. The ancients moreover laid down the limits more strictly between those things which are capable of scientific investigation, and such as do not admit of it: but the art of finance, whilst it rests only on uncertain conditions, teaching us how to provide for perpetually varying wants from a perpetually varying revenue, and how to assign to both their due limits and proportions, in conformity with the powers and circumstances of the state, seemed to the ancients as not admitting of a scientific examination. Rules for practice were not by any means wanting, although they varied according to time and place, and were brought to unequal degrees of perfection. Sparta, with her simple form of government, was unfitted for the adoption of a regular system of finance; while in Athens the expenditure and revenue were so considerable, that attention to matters of finance soon became imperatively necessary. But it was not until the Persian war, that all the ramifications of her financial institutions were finally developed; and after the time of Alexander, they necessarily lost their peculiar cha- racter with the loss of national independence. To the in- terval between these two epochs my enquiries will therefore be confined: subjects both of earlier and later date, as well as the constitutions of other Grecian states, I only touch upon incidentally. In Athens however, and within the period just mentioned, the Public Economy of Greece is seen upon its largest scale; and all the democratic states of the Greeks had doubtless nearly similar institutions of finance, 11 with such variations only as were necessarily induced by the peculiar situation and circumstances of individual countries. For these reasons therefore we must the more regret, that writings such as Aristotle's "Constitution of Athens," and the work of Philochorus, from which de- tailed explanations of such peculiarities might have been looked for, have been for ever lost; and that others, as, for example, Xenophon's Essay upon the Sources of Revenue (TEgì Tógwv), have yielded an amount of information so lamentably deficient. (2.) The amount of money required for the public Service, and how far the Income received was capable of providing for it, together with the amount of the Revenue, and the proportion which it bore to the means of the People, cannot be ascertained without knowing the Prices of commodities, the customary Wages of labour, and the ordinary Profit and Interest of stock. Upon the last of these subjects it is unnecessary to say much after the labours of Salmasius: at the same time every indulgence should be shewn to any one who attempts to give an ac- count of the prices of commodities: for their necessary mutability, and the uncertainty of the few sources from which information can be derived, impede the investiga- tion at every step; the chief authorities on this subject being either the incidental statements of Comic poets, or the assertions of orators, who mould every fact to suit their particular purpose. Nor have my enquiries been as- sisted by the labours of any previous writer¹, as Barthé- • • Meursius De Fort. Att. cap. IV. or Gillies' Observations upon the History, Manners, and Character of the Greeks from the conclusion of the Peloponnesian war until the battle of Cha- ronea, in the Introduction, and single scattered notices cannot be considered as forming any exception. : ! 12 lemy 2 has allowed himself to be deterred by the apparent difficulty of the task; although not the Roman only, but even the Hebrew antiquity, has been subjected to such investigations³. It will be the object therefore of the first book to ascertain the rates of prices, wages, and interest. The precious metals, silver and gold, are the standard of prices; although it is obvious that silver or gold may be said with the same propriety, to be dearer or cheaper in comparison with other commodities, as other commodities to be cheaper or dearer in comparison with the precious metals. And in fact, when we hear in ancient times of a smaller quantity of the precious metals being given in ex- change for other commodities, it did not arise from the value of those commodities being less than at present, but from the value of the metals being greater. For the ag- gregate stock of all commodities requisite for the purposes of life, exclusive of gold and silver, doubtless upon an average maintained the same proportion to the demand as in modern times, with the exception only of particular articles, the use of which is not indispensably necessary for human existence: while the quantity of the precious metals has in the course of centuries been augmented by the con- tinued working of mines, at the same time that their dura- ² See Anacharsis, tom. VII. p. 286. 4ième éd. 3 Hamberger de pretiis rerum apud veteres Romanos dis- putatio, Gotting. 1754. 4to. Kessenbrink über das Verhältniss des Werths des Geldes zu den Lebensmitteln seit Constantin dem Grossen bis zur Theilung des Reichs unter Theodosius dem Grossen, und über desselben Einfluss. Berlin. 1777, 8vo. Both these writings received the prize. Michaelis de pretiis rerum apud Hebræos ante exilium Babylonicum. Comm. Soc. Reg. Scient. Gotting. tom. III. (1753.) p. 145. 13 bility and value have on most occasions preserved them from destruction. (3.) The quantity of the precious metals in Greece, more particularly that portion of them which was in circulation as coin, although at first it increased but slowly, afterwards experienced a more rapid augmentation, when the invasion of Xerxes had opened the treasures of the East; and prices rose in the same proportion; so that in the time of Demos- thenes the value of money appears to have been five times less than in the age of Solon. Both in Rome and in Greece at an early period, the quantity of metals, and particularly of gold, was very inconsiderable: in the time of Croesus, according to Theopompus, it was not to be procured in Greece. The Lacedæmonians, wishing to ob- tain some gold for a sacred offering, purchased it of Croesus, manifestly because they could not procure it nearer home¹. Alcmæon the Athenian laid the foundation of the wealth of his family, when Croesus permitted him to take as much gold out of his treasury as he could carry at once. Even in the seventieth Olympiad gold was still a rarity. Hiero of Syracuse, wishing to send a statue of Victory and a tripod of pure gold to the Delphian Apollo, was unable to procure the requisite quantity of that metal, until his agents came to Architeles the Corinthian, who had long bought up and collected gold in small portions, as the same Theopompus and Phanias of Eresos relate. In Greece proper there were not many mines of the precious 16 sqq. 47 + Concerning Rome, see Plin. Hist. Nat. XXXIII, 5 sqq. On the other points, see Theopomp. ap. Athen. VI. cf. p. 230. B. Herod. I. 69. sqq. p. 231 sq. 5 Herod. VI. 125. 6 Athen. VI. ubi sup. 14 metals. The most remarkable among these were the Athe- nian silver mines of Laurion, which at first were very pro- ductive. Thessaly contained mines of gold, Siphnos both of silver and gold, and Epirus, which bordered upon Greece, possessed silver mines; the same metal was also found in Cyprus. But the mountains of Pangea upon the con- fines of Thrace and Macedonia contained immense riches; from them flows the Hebrus, celebrated for its golden sands. And in addition to the gold and silver mines which were upon the mountains themselves, the precious metals were found on both sides of them, to the west as far as the Strymon and Pæonia, and to the east as far as Scapte Hyle?. Even in Pæonia, it was said that the husbandman turned up particles of gold in ploughing 10. On the eastern side were the important gold mines of Scapte Hyle, and the precious metals extended across the sea as far as Thasos, where very considerable and productive workings had been set on foot by the Phoenicians, who had also first esta- blished mining in that region upon the main-land, which was afterwards taken up by the Thasians, until the Athe- nians obtained possession of these mines ¹¹. Upon the western side in Macedonia the mines were so productive, that Alexander the First, the son of Amyntas, in the time of the Persian war, received from them a talent of silver 11 7 For more on this der Alten, p. 64 sqq. 8 Plin. Hist. Nat. XXXIII. 21. and others. 10 Strab. ut sup. 11 See book III. 3. subject, see Reitemeier über den Bergbau Concerning Laurion, see book III. 3. 9 Herod. VII. 112. Strab. VII. p. 228. (ed. 1587.) and else- where. Xenoph. Hellen. V. 2. 12. Plin. Hist. Nat. VII. 57. Athen. II. p. 42. B. Lucian. Icaromenip. 18. and the scholiast. Clemens Alexand. &c. 15 daily 12; but the chief places were Daton and Crenides, afterwards Philippi, which in the first year of the 105th Olympiad was taken possession of by the Thasians; sub- sequently however Philip of Macedon is said to have worked the mines with so much success, that they yielded 1000 talents a year, although previously they had not been very productive; and it was in this spot that, according to the common belief, the gold grew again 13. When there- fore ancient historians affirm 14 that Philip had a golden chalice, which he guarded with such anxiety, that he laid it under his pillow when he went to sleep; and again, that before the time of Philip a silver vessel was a rarity; it does not by any means follow that the quantity of precious metal extracted from the earth was inconsiderable, for extensive mines had long been worked both in Greece and the neighbouring regions, and much gold and silver had been brought over from the east; we can only infer from these statements, that little gold had been wrought for private use, and that luxury had not yet attained its greatest height. Asia and Africa furnished by far the larger proportion of the precious metals; some also was supplied from places which remained for a time in the possession of the Greeks; thus, for instance, there were gold mines at Astyra, near Abydos, which were still worked in the time of Xeno- phon 15, but subsequently were abandoned 16. Not to dwell upon Egypt and the rest of Africa, or many single spots 12 Herod. V. 17. 13 Strab. ut sup. Diod. XVI. 3, 8. Appian. Bell. Civ. IV. 106. Plin. Hist. Nat. XXXVII. 15. Pseud-Arist. Mirab. Aus. cap. 42. 14 Ap. Athen. VI. ut sup. 15 Xenoph. Hellen. IV. 3. 37. 16 Strab. XIII. p. 407. 16 where the precious metals occurred, I shall only notice some prominent points: Colchis, Lydia, and Phrygia, were celebrated as countries rich in gold: from the gold washings at Colchis arose the fable of the golden fleece¹7; and who has not heard of Midas and Gyges, and the riches of Croesus; the gold mines of Tmolus and Sipylus, and the golden sands of the Pac- tolus? Pythes, or Pythius, the Lydian, the prince of Celænæ near the sources of the Mæander, the richest and most unfortunate man of his time, possessed, according to report, from his mines and gold washings, 2000 talents of silver, and 3,993,000 golden darics, which Xerxes in- creased to 4,000,000 18. If we only take the third part of this amount as the true sum, what enormous riches are these for a petty prince. Upon the whole there were immense sums of money accumulated in Persia, which prove the abundance of the precious metals, although not in circulation. Cyrus, according to the account of Pliny 19, acquired 34,000lbs. of gold by the conquest of Asia, besides wrought gold and other vessels; and of silver, which is difficult to believe, 500,000 talents, i. e. probably Egyptian talents of eighty Roman pounds. Deducting whatever sums might be levied by the Satraps, or consumed in the provinces for the uses of the government, in the time of Darius the son of Hystaspes, there flowed yearly into the royal treasury 7600 Babylonian talents of silver20, each of which, according to Herodotus 21, is equal to 70 17 Strab. I. p. 31. XI. p. 343. and the commentators. Plin. Hist. Nat. XXXIII. 15. 18 Herod. VII. 28. and the commentators. 19 XXXIII. 15. 20 Herod. III, 95. 21 Herod. III. 89. ! 17 Euboic minas, altogether 88663 Euboic talents. In the text of Herodotus, however, the whole amount is reckoned at 9540, and only one MS. gives 8800, an error which it is now impossible to rectify. Besides this, the Indians paid an annual tribute of 360 Euboic talents of fine gold, which, reckoning the ratio of gold to silver as 13 to 1, amounts to 4680 talents of silver; so that, according to the text of the historian, the revenue of the king of Persia amounted to 14,560, or (if we only reckon what is stated in Herodotus according to the present reading), to 13,546 Euboic talents. From the productive mines of India, and from its rivers, of which the sand contained particles of gold (among which in particular the Ganges may be men- tioned), arose the fable of the ants which dug up gold 22. From these annual receipts the treasure of the king was accumulated, and an immense mass of the precious metals was thus kept out of circulation: it was obviously their principle to coin only just so much gold and silver as was necessary for commerce and the expences of the state 23. Even in Greece large sums remained out of circulation, accumulated in the treasuries. 9700 talents of coined silver were kept in the Acropolis of Athens, besides the gold and silver vessels. The Delphian Apollo had an immense collection of the most precious treasures. Gyges sent many gold and silver offerings to Delphi; among these were six golden goblets, 30 talents in weight, which were deposited there in the Corinthian treasury 24. Passing over the numberless gifts of others, I shall only make mention of 22 Herod. III. 102 sqq. Plin. Hist. Nat. XXXIII. 21. and Strabo in the 15th book in several places. 23 Strab. XV. p. 505. 24 Herod. I. 14. VOL. I. C 18 ! the pious munificence of Croesus 25; in addition to the presents which he made to other temples, he offered up a large quantity of silver at Delphi, a bowl of this metal containing 6000 amphoræ, four silver casks, a gold and a silver cauldron, round silver pateræ, a golden statue, three cubits high, 117 half ingots of gold, weighing altogether, according to Herodotus, 232 talents, of which, 4 talents were of pure gold, and the rest alloyed (Diodorus reckons inaccurately 120, each at two talents); a golden lion, weighing ten talents, from which, at the burning of the temple during the reign of Pisistratus, 3 talents of pure gold were melted away; a golden bowl, 8 talents and 42 minas in weight; and also, according to Diodorus, 360 golden cups, each of two minas; besides many other valuable gifts. The cups, the lion, and the female statue, three ells in height, Diodorus reckons at 30 talents, so that eight talents remain for the weight of the latter. If the several items are added together, the sacred offerings of Croesus, without counting many other precious ornaments, amounted in gold alone to more than 271 talents, exclusive of the gifts of which the weight is not mentioned. If we add the rest of the gold, the account of Diodorus, that subsequently gold coins were struck from it equal in value to 4000 talents of silver, does not appear exaggerated. These accumulated masses of the precious metals were however gradually dispersed, and chiefly by the effects of war. When the king of Persia took with him into the field money and valuables sufficient to load 1200 camels 26, the misfortunes of his army enriched the Greeks in a correspond- 15 Herod. I. 50 sqq. Diod. XVI. 56. To examine what Wes- seling says upon the latter passage would lead me too far. 26 Demosth. de Symmor. p. 185. 19 ing proportion; and history has recorded many instances of persons who in this manner laid the foundation of their prosperity. The great King and his Satraps were soon compelled to pay large sums of gold to the Grecian merce- naries, and to deal out presents and bribes. Sparta alone received more than 5000 talents from the Persians, for the purposes of war 27. All the treasures that Athens had collected were dispersed into many hands by the numerous buildings undertaken by Pericles, together with the ex- pences of which he was author, for works of statuary, for theatrical spectacles, and military expeditions. The sacrilegious Phocians coined 10,000 talents in gold and silver from the treasures of Delphi, which were all dissi- pated by the war 28; and, lastly, Philip of Macedon carried on his campaigns as much by the power of gold as of arms. Thus an immense quantity of gold came into cir- culation between the time of the Persian war and the age of Demosthenes; and the precious metals must necessarily have fallen in value, as they did subsequently, when Constantine the Great caused money to be coined from the treasures of the Heathen temples 29. How How great how- ever must have been the mass of the precious metals which was carried into the West by Alexander's conquest of Asia! admitting that the accounts of his historians are exaggerated, the chief point still remains unquestionable. Besides what was found in the camp and in Babylon, the treasures of Susa and Persis are reckoned at forty, or, ac- 27 Isocr. cvμpax. 32. 28 Diod. ut sup. Athen. VI. p. 231. D. 29 Monitio ad Theodos. Aug. de inhibenda largitate Thes. Ant. Rom. vol. XI. p. 14, 15. according to Taylor's explanation ad Marm. Sandwic. p. 38. 20 cording to others, at fifty thousand talents 30. The treasure of Pasargadæ is stated at 6000; of Persepolis at 120,000 talents; and upon the whole, according to the account preserved in Strabo, 180,000 talents are said to have been collected from all parts to Ecbatana³¹; 8000, which Darius had with him, were taken by his murderers. The generosity and profusion of Alexander are in accordance with such enormous sums. The daily meals of this sovereign cost 100 minas; he gave great rewards to his soldiers, and paid their debts amounting to 9870 talents; he offered 100 talents to Phocion, and presented 2000 to the Thessalians; the funeral of Hephæstion is said to have cost 12,000 talents, and Aristotle's researches into natural history 800 32. He levied in Asia an annual revenue of 30,000 talents, and only left behind him a treasure of 50,000 33. The riches of his Satraps were also excessive; Harpalus is said to have amassed 50,000 talents, although at Athens he only owned to the possession of 950 34. Alexander's successors not only accumulated enormous sums, but by means of their wars set them again in circulation. The plates of gold and silver in the palace at Ecbatana were mostly taken away in the time of Alexander: Antigonus and Seleucus Nicator completed the robbery; notwithstanding which, Antiochus the Great was able to coin nearly 4000 30 Strab. XV. p. 502. Arrian. III. 3. Justin. XI. 14. Curt. V. 2. Plutarch. Alex. 36. 31 Strab. ut sup. and others. 32 Concerning the debts of the soldiers and of Phocion, see Plut. Alex. 70. Phoc. 18. the other statements are well known from Rambach on Potter. vol. III. p. 186, 187. 33 Justin. XIII. 1. and the commentators. 34 Diod. XVII. 108. Lives of the Ten Orators, p. 264. in the Tübingen Plutarch. 21 talents from the few ingots of gold which remained, those of silver being more numerous, together with the gold obtained from the chasing of the columns of a temple 35 The immense taxes which were raised in the kingdom of Macedonia, and the unbounded extravagance and libe- rality of the kings, are a proof that there must have been an immense mass of money in circulation. The presents made by the kings of this time to the Rho- dians, when about the 140th Olympiad their town and island were laid waste by an earthquake, are almost with- out example 36. One festival of the Ptolemies did not cost less than 2239 talents, 50 minas 37. The expence which they incurred for their naval force and other public objects was extraordinary. Appian 38 states upon the authority of official documents, that the treasure of Ptolemy Phila- delphus, the second king after Alexander, amounted to 740,000 talents, either Egyptian talents of 80 Roman pounds, or the small Ptolemaic 39. If we take the former, which were about equal to the Attic, it gives, in the money of the present day, the enormous sum of £178,868,333; if they were the small talents, it amounts at least to a fourth part of this number. An account of this kind appears fabu- lous; but I venture not to call its credibility into question. Let it be remembered, that a great part of this treasure was wrought silver and gold 40; that the revenues of the Ptolemies were excessive, as the countries where their domi- nion extended were completely drained; the taxes and tri- 35 Polyb. X. 27. 36 Polyb. V. 88, 89. 37 Athen. V. p. 203. B. 38 Hist. Rom. proœm. 10. 39 Upon this point see the commentators of Pollux, IX. 86. 4º Cf. e. g. Callixen. ap. Athen. V. p. 196-203. 22 + 41 butes were collected by the farmers of the revenue, with the assistance of an armed force, consisting not of regular sol- diers, but of organized bands of robbers. The revenues of Colesyria, Phoenicia, and Judæa together with Samaria, were alone let by Ptolemy Euergetes for 8000 talents; and if a Jew purchased them, he had to pay a double amount, and moreover to furnish into the royal treasury ¹¹ the money required for the redemption of the confiscated goods of such persons as had not paid their taxes. In short, the precious metals in the times of the Macedonian Empire were spread in great abundance over the eastern shore of the Mediterranean; and if there had not been so much that was either wrought, or hoarded up in treasuries, their value must have fallen far lower in comparison with other commodities, than was actually the case. The universal dominion of the Romans afterwards trans- ported some part of the riches of the East to Italy, by which Greece was impoverished: thither also flowed the silver and the gold of western Europe. The golden stream-works and gold mines of Italy were neglected in comparison with those of France and Spain. The Po, and all the Alpine torrents, carried down gold: there were extensive gold mines in the territory of the Salassi, an Alpine nation. Not far from Aquileia, gold, nearly in a state of purity, was found at the depth of two feet, of the size of a bean or a lupine, of which only the eighth part went to dross, toge- ther with other impurer metal, which was however pro- vided in plenty by only digging to the depth of fifteen feet, as Strabo and Polybius relate. The neighbouring coun- tries were also possessed of gold-washings. In the reign of Nero, 50lbs. of gold were for a considerable period 4 Joseph. Antiq. Jud. XII. 4. 3 23 extracted daily from the mines of Dalmatia. France abounded in gold mines, of which some produced only a thirtieth part of silver: it had also silver mines. The mountains and rivers of Spain, as for example the Tajo, contained much precious metal, and had been worked by the Carthaginians before they fell into the hands of the Romans. Private individuals gained in plentiful times an Euboic talent of silver within three days; and the silver furnaces of New Carthage, which together with the mines kept 40,000 men in employment, produced to the Roman people 25,000 denarii per diem, or, as Polybius expresses himself, 25,000 drachmas. Gallaecia, Lusitania, and espe- cially Asturia, produced for many years 20,000lbs. of gold 42. The value of the precious metals did not however fall in proportion to their increase, as large quantities, wrought for works of art, were taken out of circulation. (4.) Coined metal, or money, is, as well as uncoined metal, a commodity; and it is obvious that in the ancient days of Greece, as well as in modern times, it would be an object of trade with the money-changers. If we exclude the arbitrary value which individual states are able to give to a particular kind of coin for the use of their own citizens, the current value of money is determined by the fineness of the standard: and upon this point, in reference 42 Every thing that is here said may be found in Strabo, in the third, fourth, and fifth books, in Pliny in the thirteenth, and in Diodorus in the fifth, particularly in chap. 27, and 36. Who- ever wishes to obtain more precise information with regard to the situations of the mines in ancient times, will find a satisfactory account in Reitemeier's Treatise über den Bergbau der Alten. I have only here incidentally mentioned the subject. Concerning the Spanish mines, Bethe, de Hispaniæ antiquæ re metallica, ad locum Strabonis lib. III. is worth referring to. 24 to the Greeks, and to Athens in particular, I will only say so much as appears necessary to make what follows intel- ligible to the reader. In Attica, and in almost all the Grecian states, and even out of Greece, the talent con- tained 60 minas, the mina 100 drachmas, the drachma 6 oboli. At Athens the obolus was divided into 8 chalcûs, and the chalcûs into 7 lepta. As far as the half obolus down- wards, the Athenian money was generally coined in silver: the dichalcon, or obolus, either in silver or copper; the chalcûs, and the smaller coins, only in copper. Upon a single occasion, in the early times of the Republic, copper was coined instead of silver, probably oboli, but they did not long remain in circulation 43. When in later writers, in Lucian¹¹ for instance, we read of copper oboli, they should not on any account be considered as ancient Athenian money. Among the larger silver coins, the tetradrachms are the most common, called also staters 15. The value of the Attic silver talent has been differently determined by different writers, as they set out upon the weight and fine- ness of different tetradrachms; for all agree that the early coins are better than the more recent. According to the enquiries of Barthélemy 16, which seem preferable to those of Eckhel 47, the ancient tetradrachms, coined in the flou- rishing times of Athens, weigh 328 Paris grains (nearly 46 43 See chap. 6. near the end. 44 Vol. I. p. 504. ed. Reiz. 45 According to Heron of Alexandria, who has been already quoted by others. The same is evident from Hesych. in v. γλαὺξ, cf. in v. γλαῦκες Λαυριωτικαί. Phot. in v. στατὴς, and Lex. Seg. p. 253. in v. zirgirais, comp. Harpocrat. in the same word, and lastly Lex. Seg. p. 307. in v. Teтgadgaxμov. 46 Anachars. tom. VII. table XIV. 47 D. N. vol. I. p. xlv sqq. 25 269 Troy grains, i. e. about 674 to a drachma), if we reckon in four grains, which they might have lost by wear in the course of so many centuries. The silver is nearly pure, for Athens did not, like other states, alloy it with lead or copper, on which account this money was particu- larly valued, and every where exchanged with profit 48. It appears however probable, that the average was not so high as represented by Barthélemy, even without allowing four grains for wear; and that it is safer to take the Attic drachma at 65 Troy grains; which, as the shilling con- tains about 80 grains of pure silver, is nearly equal to 9 d. of English coinage; whence the mina amounts to £4 0s. 6d. and the talent to £241 13s. 4d.ª It may be moreover observed, that as the Romans reckoned in sesterces, so the Greeks generally reckoned in drachmas; 48 Xenoph. de Vectig. 3. cf. Aristoph. Ran. 730-736. Polyb. XXII. 15, 26. G a The translator has taken the liberty of deviating from the author in adapting this calculation to English money, and has preferred the data furnished by Mr. Knight in his Prolegomena to Homer (§. 56.) to the estimate of Barthélemy, which is fol- lowed in the original. The statement referred to is this: "Drachmæ Ægineticæ, quas vidi conservatissimas, tum ipsius Eginæ tum Thebarum, Tanagræ, Elidis, et Phocidis, granorum xcv. plus minusve erant singula; et didrachmæ cxc. quum drachmæ Athenarum et Alexandri Magni lxv.; didrachmæ, quæ rarissimæ, cxxx. sint." The Æginetan drachma contained ten, the Attic six, oboli; therefore their values are to one another in a ratio of 20 to 12; the ratio of their weights (as stated by Mr. Knight) is 19 to 13. This therefore is an additional reason for not taking the average Attic drachma at more than 65 grains. The author at first makes an allowance for seignorage, but after- wards properly remarks, that we have no reason for supposing that the Athenians imposed any. 26 A and where a sum is mentioned in the Attic writers, with- out any specification of the unit, drachmas are always meant 49 Before the time of Solon, the weight of the Attic money was greater than in the standard that was afterwards used. The weights commonly employed in trade were also in later times heavier than those by which the money was measured. Comparing these facts together, it may be assumed with the greatest probability, that Solon intended 100 drachmas to be coined out of 75, but that the new money proved in fact rather too much debased, so that 100 new drachmas were only equal to 7233 of the old coinage; the old weights being however retained for every thing except money 50. In comparison with the heavy drachma of Ægina (dgaxµǹ taxɛĩa), the Attic is called the light drachma (ogaxμn EπT); the former was equal to ten Attic oboli; so that the Æginetan talent weighed rather more than 10,000 Attic drachmas 51. The Corinthian talent was equal to the latter in value 52; the Corinthians however had staters or decalitras of ten Æginetan oboli in weight 53, 300 of which were consequently equal to the Corinthian talent. The computation by litras was trans- mitted from Corinth to Syracuse; therefore the Sicilian litra, which was struck in silver, was equal to an Æginetan 49 Thus διακόσιαι, χίλιαι, δισχίλιαι, &c. in the orators and else- where. See Taylor ad Marm. Sandwic. p. 29, 30. 5º See note (A) at the end of the book. 51 Pollux IX. 76, 86. and the commentators. Hesych. in v. λεπτὰς and παχείᾳ δραχμῇ. ห 52 Gell. Noct. Att. I. 8. whether the words ráλavrov are genuine or interpolated: in the latter case they are a learned interpre- tation. 53 Pollux IV. 175. IX, 81. 27 obolus, according to the statement of Aristotle 54. Pro- bably the Sicilian nummus was the same as the litra. The accounts of Aristotle 55, who only estimates the nummus at 14 Attic oboli, and of Festus, who, according to the same proportion, reckons twelve nummi to three denarii (whereas the litra was equal to 13 Attic oboli), are perhaps inaccurate, although they may come near the real value of the coin, if, as is probable, the Syracusan nummi or litras, of the same weight as the Æginetan oboli, were struck from less fine silver than the Attic drachmas. 24 nummi of this kind composed, according to Aristotle, the old, 12 the new Syracusan or Sicilian talent, which last Festus makes equal to three denarii 56. According to our supposition therefore, the former was equal to four, and the latter to two Æginetan drachmas, both doubtless, like the decalitron, being coined in silver. Why so small a sum was called a talent, I shall not attempt to decide; remarking only, that by a similar idiom small golden drachmas were called talents 57. + The ancient writers frequently reckon in Euboic talents, which appear to have come into use in the Italian colonies of Magna Græcia, chiefly on account of the spreading of 54 Pollux IV. 174, 175. IX. 80, 81. cf. Salmas. de Modo Usur. VI. p. 242. 55 Ap. Polluc. IX. 87, 56 Pollux IX. 87. Suidas in v. ráλavrov, where, according to the correct observation of Scaliger, vouwv should be read instead of μvav, as well as in the intricate passage of the Scholiast to Gregor. Naz. which Jungermann quotes at the place in Pollux. A small talent of this kind, probably only of 12 nummi, is that which occurs in the account of the Gymnasia of the Tauromenitani in d'Orville's Siculis, and in Castello the Prince of Torremuzza. 57 See chap. 5. 28 3 the Chalcideans, and which for that reason frequently occur in the treaties of the Romans with other nations, as well as in Herodotus, who evidently composed or altered many parts of his History after his migration to Thurii. In addition to these values, it would be desirable, for the sake of many statements of which we must avail our- selves, to ascertain the amount of the Egyptian and Alex- andrian talents; but we here meet with obscure and con- tradictory statements. The chief difficulty would be re- moved were the difference between the Egyptian and Alex- andrian talents ascertained. According to Varro 58, the Egyptian talent was equal to 80 Roman pounds, and therefore must have been absolutely or nearly identical with the Attic, as the Attic mina was to the Roman pound nearly as four to three 59. This must have been totally dif GOG 58 Ap. Plin. Hist. Nat. XXXIII. 15. 59 The Roman senate reckoned the Attic talent, or 60 minas, as equal to 80 Roman pounds. Liv. XXXVIII. 38. Polyb. XXII. 26. According to the testimonies of the ancients in Eckhel, D. N. vol. V. part II, p. 6. there were 84 denarii in the Roman pound, and not till the time of Nero, 96. (see Eisenschmid de Pond. et Mens. p. 33.) but the old denarius of Augustus was to the Attic drachma as 8 to 9; consequently 743, or, in round numbers, 75 drachmas, were equal to a Roman pound. We sometimes read in ancient writers, that a Roman pound was equal in weight to 84 drachmas, which is sufficiently accounted for by the inexactitude of almost all ancient authors, who used drachmas and denarii, on account of their small difference (9 and 8) as convertible terms. According to Romé de l'Isle's accurate researches, founded upon the weighing of golden de- narii, the Roman pound weighed 6048 Paris grains: hence the Attic mina must have weighed 8064, whereas, if the tetradrachm is taken at 328 Paris grains, the mina contained 8200. It must however be remembered, that it was assumed that the tetra- 1 29 ferent from the talent mentioned by Pollux60, which was equal to 1500 Attic drachmas, but otherwise, like all talents, was divided similarly to the Attic. This is cor- roborated by the statement of Hiero, who only assigns a fourth part of the value of the Attic talent to the Pto- lemaic, which appears to have been the same same as the small Egyptian talent: the very same authority, however, reckons the Ptolemaic mina as the fifth part of the Ægi- netan, which again does not agree; not to mention, that, in the confusion of language which prevailed at Alexan- dria in later times, the name of drachma was given to coins of the value of an Athenian obolus. But, according to Festus 61, whose text is so corrupt that no reliance can be placed upon his authority, the Alexandrian talent was equal to 12,000 denarii. The safest way, in my opinion, drachm had lost four grains by time, which Romé de l'Isle, in computing the weight of the denarius, probably did not take into account; and then it will be found, that the difference nearly vanishes, and Romé de l'Isle's enquiries concerning the Roman pound agree tolerably well with the proportion of the latter to the Attic mina as three to four. It is besides worthy of remark, that Ideler's accurate determination of the Roman foot tallies remark- ably with Romé de l'Isle's determination of the pound. See Memoirs of the Berlin Academy of Sciences for 1812 and 1813. Thus perhaps the supposition that the tetradrachms had lost four grains of their weight might be modified (see note a, p. 25.), and on the other hand, some grains might be added to the Roman pound over 6048. The supposition of some writers, that the Romans had two different pounds, is entirely unfounded, at least as far as money is concerned. 60 IX. 86. where the commentators should be consulted upon what immediately follows. 61 In v. talentum, which passage however appears very uncer- tain. 30 is to consider the Alexandrian talent as something less than the Attic, although there were at Alexandria many other talents of less amount, which were used at certain times and for certain purposes. For, according to the assertion of Appian, the Euboic talent was equal to 7000 Alexandrian drachmas 62; but the Euboic talent, as far as I am able to discover, was only somewhat greater than the Attic; consequently the Alexandrian talent appears to have been to the Attic, nearly as six to seven. As to the Euboic talent, Herodotus 63, if the present reading is cor- rect, reckons that the Babylonian talent contained 70 Eu- boic minas, Pollux 7000 Attic drachmas 64. Here then the Attic and Euboic talents are considered as equal. According to Ælian 65 on the contrary, the Babylonian talent contained 72 Attic minas, a statement which is evidently of more weight than the uncertain account of Pollux; and it thence follows, that the Euboic talent was somewhat greater than the Attic. At the same time this statement may not be mathematically accurate; for ac- cording to it the Attic talent is to the Euboic as 72 to 75 (70 to 72), agreeably to Herodotus' computation of the Babylonian talent in Euboic minas. It is probable how- ever, that Solon, when he wished so to change the Attic money, that 100 drachmas should be coined from the same quantity of silver as had formerly been made into 75, in- tended to make the Attic silver talent equal to the Eu- boic, which had been for a long time in general circulation. According to this supposition, the Euboic talent would, 62 Appian. Hist. Sicil. II. 2. 63 III. 89. 64 Pollux IX. 86. 65 Hist. Var. I. 22. 31 : before the time of Solon, have been to the Attic talent in the ratio of 75 to 100. Since however the money of Solon proved actually to be to the ancient Attic money in the ratio of 72% to 100, strictly speaking, the new Attic silver talent must have been to the Euboic as 72% to 75, that is, as 70 to 72% but as, upon an average, the new Attic was to the old Attic talent as 73 to 100 6, in the same manner it might be assumed, that the proportion of the new Attic to the Euboic was, in round numbers, as 73 to 75, which nearly coincides with the ratio obtained from Herodotus and Elian, of 72 to 75, or 70 to 72. This method of viewing the subject agrees so well in all its par- ticulars, that it relieves me from the trouble of entering into a more minute investigation of the confused and cor- rupt passage of Festus upon the Euboic talent 67. On the other hand, the similarity of the Attic and Euboic talents 66 See note (A) at the end of the book. stater. 67 Euboicum talentum nummo Græco septem millium et quin- gentorum cistophororum est, nostro quattuor millia denariorum. Both statements are false. As to the cistophori, they weigh on an average 240 Paris grains, consequently they were less than the Æginetan double-drachmas, and greater than the Corinthian Nevertheless it seems to me probable, that the cistophori were regulated according to one of these two coins, a point which cannot however be explicitly investigated in this place. The weight of the cistophori stated above is not then perhaps suffici- ently accurate. I may remark here incidentally, that the ac- count of the Etymologist in v. Evßöïxòv vóμsoµa, which states it to have been named from a place in Argos, where Pheidon first coined gold, is fabulous, for the Euboic standard was too widely spread to have derived its name from thence; and if Pheidon had been the author of it, the Eginetan standard could not have been different from it. That Pheidon coined gold at all is also unquestionably a fable. 32 seems to be additionally confirmed by the circumstance, that, in the negociations between the Romans and Anti- ochus, the calculations were at first made in Euboic, and afterwards in Attic talents of 80 Roman pounds 68: for it is probable, that nearly the same standard of money was retained, as the whole amount might have been diminished, and was in fact diminished, by demanding a less number of talents than before. (5.) The value of gold is more variable than that of silver, which therefore may be considered as a standard of price for gold as well as for other commodities 69. In Eu- ropean Greece there were many gold coins in circulation, and more especially belonging to foreign states, of which I will now only mention the most important. Gold, and probably silver, was first coined in Lydia 70, in which country Croesus caused the stater called by his name to be coined, at a time when Greece was extremely poor in gold. If Polycrates of Samos really deceived the Spartans with false gold coins about the 60th Olympiad, which He- rodotus 71 indeed considered an idle tale, the Greeks at that time could have seen but little coined gold; for even the Lacedæmonians would not have been deceived by so clumsy a fraud. Soon after that period, Darius the son of Hystaspes coined darics of the finest gold 72, which passed over into the circulation of Greece. Their 68 Compare Polyb. XXI. 14. Liv. XXXVII. 45. with Polyb. XXII, 26. Liv. XXXVIII. 38. 69 It is upon this notion that Xenophon's encomium upon silver (de Vectig. 4.) is evidently founded. 70 Herod. I. 94. 71 Herod. III. 56. 72 Herod. IV. 166. It may be also observed, that there were silver darics. Plutarch. Cim. 10. 33 weight, which Philip of Macedon, Alexander, and Lysi- machus retained, was equal to two Attic drachmas, both according to the testimonies of writers who make them the same as the Attic golden stater, and the ascertained weight of coins now extant 73; whence their value is fixed by the grammarians at twenty silver drachmas, and five are rec- koned to a mina, and 300 to a talent 74, according to the ratio of gold to silver as 10 to 1. That the Athenian golden stater also weighed two drachmas, and was esti- mated at twenty silver drachmas, is proved by good au- thorities 75: according to this value, 5000 staters are in the calculation of Conon's property in Lysias computed at about 100,000 drachmas 76. But as no undoubted Attic stater has been preserved to our days 77, Eckhel has ques- tioned the fact of it's ever having been coined 78; not only however does Pollux 79 enumerate the golden stater among 73 Harpocr. in v. Aaguxòs, and thence Suidas, Schol. Aristoph. Ecclesiaz. 598. Lex. Seg. p. 237. Comp. Barthélemy Mém. de l'Académie des Inscript. vol. XLVII. p. 201, 202. Eckhel. D. N. vol. I. p. XLI. 74 Harpocr. Schol. Aristoph. and Lex. Seg. ut sup. Xenoph. Anab. I. 8. 14. Harpocration also states in this passage, that the Attic Chrysus was equal to 20 drachmas. 75 Polemarch. ap. Hesych. Poll. IV. 173. 76 Lysias pro Aristoph. bonis p. 639. ed. Reiske. The pro- perty of Conon amounted, according to this passage, to about 40 talents; and it consisted of 5000 staters, and three other sums of 10,000 drachmas, 3 talents, and 17 talents. If the 5000 staters are reckoned at 100,000 drachmas, the sum is equal to 38 talents, which agrees perfectly with the expression, "about 40 talents." 77 See Barthélemy ut sup. p. 206. 78 D. N. vol. I. p. XLI sqq. vol. II. p. 206, 207. 79 Poll. IX. 58. [The following passage of Aristophanes ap- VOL. I. D # 34 coins upon the authority of Eupolis, but we know with cer- tainty that gold coins were issued at Athens, and more espe- cially in the Archonship of Antigenes, one year before the Frogs of Aristophanes (Olymp. 93. 2.) that money was coined from the golden statues of Victory, which Aristopha- nes, as they were much debased with copper, calls wretched pieces of copper 80. The most common golden staters, be- sides those of Croesus, Attica, and Persia, were the Pho- caic and Cyzicenic, which have likewise been falsely taken for imaginary coins by writers on ancient money. The probable reason why none are extant, is, that the Mace- donian kings supplanted all the gold coins of the cities by melting them down, in order that, with the exception of the darics, there should be no gold coin which did not bear their image. The Phocaic stater occurs, both in inscriptions and in writers, as coined money 81; nor can it می pears decisive. It is from the Plutus (v. 816.) where Carion is describing the sudden increase of wealth caused by the arrival of the god of riches: στατῆρσι δ' οἱ θεράποντες ἀρτιάζομεν χρυσοῖς.] 80 Aristoph. Ran. 731. and the scholiast upon the authority of Philochorus, and Suidas in v. χαλείον. Suidas in v. γλαυξ ἵπταται, and Schol. Aristoph. Eq. 1091. state, that the Attic gold coins had the device of the owl. This may be very true; but the passages can prove nothing, as in the same writer, as well as in Hesychius in v. Aaigua, the mines of Laurion are taken for gold mines, and consequently the owls of Laurion for gold coins, whereas they are silver coins. See my Essay upon the Silver Mines of Laurion, in the Memoirs of the Berlin Academy for 1815. 81 Zτarnę Buxarùs Demosth. in Boot. de dote, p. 1019. 15. Qaxairns Thucyd. IV. 52. Two Phocaic staters as a sacred offering in Inscript. 150. (t. I. p. 231. ed. Boeckh.) placed toge- ther with other Phocaic coins, can no more be unstamped or imaginary coins, than the Æginetan stater in the same Inscrip- 35 be supposed, that silver pieces are meant, as the idea of a gold coin is inseparably associated with the name of Pho- caic stater. Its weight is unknown; it passed however as the least valuable gold coin 82. Also, that the Cyzicenic staters were coined money, is proved from many passages of ancient writers. In the oration of Demosthenes against Lacritus, a hundred Cyzicenic staters are expressly men- tioned as coined money 83. money 85. The same orator says of Mei- dias, that he had stolen more than five talents in Cyzicenic staters from the funds of the Paralos 84, where it is impos- sible that he can mean an imaginary coin. Lysias reckons among his ready money 400 Cyzicenic staters, with 100 darics and three talents of silver; and, according to another passage in the same orator, 30 Cyzicenic staters were actu- ally paid down 85. The troops in the Pontus, according to the account given in the Anabasis of Xenophon, were sometimes paid in Cyzicenic staters, and at other times in tion, the false staters in Inscript. 151. (ibid.), and the tetra- drachm in Inscript. 139. 82 Hesych. in v. Daxais, calls this rò xάxiorov xevolov, whether staters or parts of staters (perhaps exrai Dwxaïdes, as in Inscript. 150. (ut sup.) are meant. Concerning the Phocaic stater as a coin, see also Pollux IX. 93. & P. 935. 13. ὅτι ἑκατὸν στατῆρες Κυζικηνοὶ περιγένοιντο, καὶ τοῦτο τὸ χρυσίον δεδανεικὼς εἴη, &c. Χρυσίον and ἀργυρίον in the ancient writers always mean small, that is, coined or wrought, gold and silver. rr 84 In Mid. p. 570. 15. ὅτι τῆς μὲν Παράλου ταμιεύσας Κυζικηνῶν ἥρπασε πλείω ἢ πέντε τάλαντα. [The author corrects himself in the Addenda, and mentions that the meaning of this passage is not "that Meidias stole more than five talents in Cyzicenics, but that he stole more than five talents from the Cyzicenians, as is properly remarked by Ulpian."] $5 In Eratosth. p. 391. in Diogit. p. 894 sqq. cf. p. 903. 36 darics; these staters are also mentioned as coins in several inscriptions. Hesychius, Suidas, and Photius, also describe the impression of the Cyzicenic stater, which upon one side was a female figure of the mother of the gods, who was worshipped at Sipylus, and upon the reverse, the forepart of a lion; and can it be supposed, that by this any other Cyzicenic stater than the common gold one is meant? Lastly, Demosthenes 86 remarks, that 120 Cyzicenic staters passed in the Bosporus for 3360 Attic drachmas, one for twenty-eight; probably not because their weight was greater than two drachmas, but because the value of gold was then higher in that country, being to silver in the ratio of 14 to 1. Each gold stater probably weighed about two drachmas. Lysimachus and others, however, coined double and quadruple staters 87; and there were also half pieces of the same coin (xguro)88. Scaliger 89 considers the Damaretion to have been a half stater, which Damarete, the wife of Gelon and the daughter of Theron, according to Diodorus, caused to be coined about the 75th Olym- piad from the crown of a hundred talents, that the Car- thaginians presented to her at the conclusion of peace, or, according to Pollux, from the ornaments of the women, which they had surrendered to defray the expences of the war with the Carthaginians 9º. Other learned writers have expressed their astonishment at this supposition; but Sca- liger's remark is perfectly accurate; for the Damaretion 86 In Phorm. p. 914. 11. ὁ δὲ Κυζικηνὸς ἐδύνατο ἐκεῖ εἴκοσι καὶ ὀκτὼ δραχμὰς ᾿Αττικάς: and 13. τῶν μὲν γὰς ἑκατὸν καὶ εἴκοσι στατήρων γίγνονται τρὶς χίλιαι τριακόσιαι ἑξήκοντα. 87 Eckhel D. N. vol. I. p. 88 Poll. VI. 161. IX. 59. L. 89 De re numm. p. 13, 17. 9º Diod. XI. 26. Poll. IX. 85. Schol. Pind. Olymp. II. 29. 37 was equal in. value to ten Attic drachmas, and was thus only half the common stater. The Sicilians called this gold coin Pentecontalitron, from its weight 91, as Diodorus asserts. Since however 50 Sicilian litras were equal to 13 drachmas 5 oboli of the Attic standard, it is evident that the weight in gold of the Damaretion cannot be meant (which could only be a drachma), but the weight of silver which in Sicily was equal in value to the Damaretion. The Damaretion being equal to 10 Attic drachmas ac- cording to the decuple proportion of gold to silver, the Sicilians, among whom gold was probably higher, made it equal to 50 silver litras, at the ratio of 13% to 1. Golden Æginetan staters likewise occur92, but nothing is known of their weight. The meaning of the terms talent and mina, when applied to gold, has been frequently a subject of enquiry. Ac- cording to Pollux95, the gold stater was equal in value to a a mina; a statement which seems wholly inexplicable, unless, with Rambach 94, we understand gold coins of eight or ten drachmas in weight, which would certainly agree with the value of a silver mina. But Pollux is speaking with parti- cular reference to the common gold stater of two drachmas in weight; unless then he confuses the entire question, ac- cording to some method or other of computing, a weight of two drachmas of gold must have been called a mina. That however, in speaking of gold, an entirely different language must have existed, is probable from the circumstance that the same grammarian in two other places 95 calls three οι ᾿Απὸ τοῦ σταθμοῦ. ⁹ See Inscript. 150. §. 43. tom. I. p. 231. ed. Boeckh. 93 IX. 57. ⁹4 On Potter vol. III. p. 169. 95 IV. 173. IX. 53, 54. 38 Attic gold staters, or a chrysûs, a talent of gold. The reason which prevents me from receiving the emendation proposed by Salmasius 96 is, that Pollux repeats the same statement twice. I am therefore inclined to follow the opinion of J. F. Gronov 97, that a weight of six drachmas of gold was called a talent, according to an idiom customary upon certain occasions, perhaps, as it has been conjectured, because this was the value of a talent of copper, the ratio of gold to copper being as 1000 to 1. This small gold talent could only have contained three minas, each two drachmas in weight. This supposition is completely esta- blished by the fact of the talent of Thyateira being equal to three gold staters 98; and Eustathius even calls two chrysûs, and Hero of Alexandria one chrysûs, a talent. Probably the goldsmiths reckoned by these small talents; and when we read of golden crowns of many talents in weight, this smaller kind is doubtless intended. Who can believe that the Carthaginians presented to Damarete a crown of a hundred talents of gold 99, if a talent of gold were the usual weight of the silver talent, or even only a portion of gold equal in weight to the value of a silver talent? Are we to suppose, that the inhabitants of the Chersonese would have given a crown of 60 talents to the senate and 96 Instead of reus xęvrouc (r′) he writes reianorious or T', as 300 chrysûs, according to the decuple proportion of gold to silver, are equal to a talent of silver. If the text is to be altered, τρισχιλίους might be written for τρεῖς, from which the compendium of the former word is not very different; 3000 gold staters are equal in weight to a talent. 97 De Pec. Vet. III. 7. 98 Lex. Seg. p. 306. 99 Diod. XI. 26. > 39 people of the Athenians 100, if the silver and gold talents were of the same weight? and how vast must the size of such crowns have been? And even if we suppose that 100 talents of gold were equal to 600 gold drachmas, and 60 talents of gold to 360 drachmas, these crowns still remain of considerable weight. Excepting the crown of Jupiter at Tarracona, 15lbs. in weight, and that which the Car- thaginians sent to the Capitoline Jupiter in the year of the city 412, of 25lbs. of gold (1875 Attic drachmas), and the immense one in the time of Ptolemy Philadelphus, of 10,000 gold staters (which, at a festival in the time of that king, was laid upon the throne of Ptolemy Soter), together with another, 80 cubits in length, of gold and precious stones, I find no example of such large crowns as those two were, even if they only weighed 600 and 360 drachmas. In the Acropolis of Athens there were golden crowns of 17, 181, of 20, and 25 drachmas or rather more; also another of 26; four of which the joint weight was 135 drachmas; one of 29, others of 33, 59, and 85 drachmas. A crown, which the celebrated Lysander sent as a sacred offering to the Parthenon of Athens, weighed 66 drachmas 5 oboli. Two crowns, honorary gifts to Minerva of the Acropolis, weighed, the one 245 drachmas 14 oboli, the other 272 drachmas 3 oboli. Another for the same goddess weighed 232 drachmas 5 oboli. A crown, dedicated to the Delphian Apollo at the great festival which was celebrated every fourth year, cost only 1500 drachmas of silver; and con- sequently, if the workmanship is estimated at the lowest 100 Demosth. de Corona p. 256. 25. Concerning the crown at Tarracona, see Suetonius in the Life of Galba cap. 12. the gift of the Carthaginians to the Capitoline Jupiter Liv. VII. 38. Concerning the crown of Ptolemy see Athen. V. p. 202. B. D. 40 possible rate, can hardly have weighed a hundred drachmas of gold 101. According to these facts then, the talents in which the weight of the Carthaginian and Chersonetan crowns is stated, must have been small talents of six drachmas of gold. Yet there can be no question but that as much gold as was equal to the value of a silver talent, is often called a talent of gold; as also that a quantity of gold weighing 6000 drachmas was known by the same name; which therefore in this case is manifestly inde- pendent of any relation to the value of silver 102. (6.) The usual price of gold can be as well determined from the data already cited, as from other authorities. The most frequent proportion in ancient times appears to have been that of ten to one, as follows from what has been said concerning the stater which weighed two drachmas ; and although the lowness of this ratio does at first sight appear surprising, when we consider the scarcity of gold in early times, it must be remembered that the quantity of silver in circulation was very inconsiderable 103. The 101 Inscript. 150. §. 13. 141. §. 11. and 139. 1. 20. 141. §. 15, 20. 150. §. 16. 141. §. 10. 139. 1. 21, 22. 150. §. 14, 15, 12. also 150. §. 40, 10. 151. 1. 28, 29. and 145. ed. Boeckh. 102 Herod. III. 95. Menand. ap. Poll. VI. 76. Polyb. XXII. 15. the latter concerning the mina. The confused passage of Suidas in v. ßoλòs, and of Photius, quoted there by Küster, cannot be taken into consideration in reference to the value of the gold talent. 103 Compare also, on the subject of this proportion, J. F. Gronov. de Pec. Vet. II. 8. the same proportion is given by Hesychius in v. deuxμn xęvolov, according to the correct emenda- tion proposed in the notes, and Suidas in v. deaxen. In some regions of the East, gold was certainly cheaper: thus Strabo, in the 16th book, speaks of a country near the Sabai, where gold had only twice the value of silver, and three times the value of brass. 41 price of gold however gradually rose, partly on account of the proportionally greater increase of silver, until it arrived at ratios similar to those of modern Europe (from 13½ to 1 to 15 to 1), although these experienced occasional variations. When we find so late as in Menander 104 a talent of gold reckoned only equal to ten talents of silver, the price of gold at Athens must either have been depressed at that time by Alexander's campaigns in Asia, which opened the treasures of Persia to the Greeks, or Menander follows the original proportion, which remained in his memory after it had ceased to be actually in force, as it afforded a particularly easy calculation. In the Dialogue upon the desire of gain 105, which formerly, under the name of Hipparchus, passed for the production of Plato, and which certainly belongs to the age of Socrates and Plato, the value of gold is stated at twelve times that of sil- ver; Herodotus however reckons the proportion as thir- teen to one 106; according to the former the chrysûs was equal to 24, according to the latter to 26, drachmas of silver. To conclude from the value of the Damaretion, the proportion of gold to silver in Sicily had risen to 138, although Diodorus, following the ancient custom, esti- mates the silver value of the Damaretion at the ratio of ten to one. There cannot therefore be much risk of error in assuming that the Cyzicenic stater only weighed two drachmas of gold, but that at a certain period during the life of Demosthenes, it passed in the Bosporus for 28 drachmas of silver, the value of gold in comparison with silver having risen to 14. The price of gold at Rome 104 Ap. Poll. VI. 76. 105 P. 40 of my edition. 106 III. 95. 42 I was still more variable. At the payment of the Ætolians in the year of the city 564, when they were allowed, if they wished it, to pay a third part in gold, the proportion between the two metals was prescribed to them (mani- festly to their great disadvantage) at ten to one 107. In the year of Rome 547, the ratio of gold to silver was as 17 to 1, afterwards as 13 to 1. In the time of Cæsar, on account of the great influx of gold out of Gaul, it fell as low as 814; as at a former period, according to the account of Polybius, its price had fallen for a time in Italy a third part, in consequence of the rapid increase in the quantity of gold from the mines of Aquileia 108. We also find the ratio of 11 to 1; and in the 422d year of the Christian era, the ratio of gold to silver had risen to 18 109 The rise in the price of gold in Greece may have been owing to other causes than the increase in the quantity of silver in circulation. The increasing consumption of gold for ornaments, utensils, and works of art, especially for sacred offerings, would also have contributed to produce that effect. The greater activity of commerce must also have forced up the price of gold; for, from the want of bills of exchange, much ready money was necessarily carried from one place to another, for which purpose gold was the most convenient. The pay of the troops was given out in gold. The military chests therefore required a considerable store, and the demand for gold must have been very considerable during the continual wars. Probably much coined gold passed out of circulation by being accumulated in public 107 Polyb. XXII. 15. Liv. XXXVIII. 11. 108 Sueton. Cæs. 54. Polyb. XXXIV. 10. 109 Upon the price of gold at Rome, see Hamberger de pretiis rerum p. sqq. 43 and private treasuries. Sparta, during a period of several generations, swallowed up large quantities of the precious metals, as in Æsop's fable the footsteps of the animals which went in were to be seen, but never of those which came out 110. The principal cause of this stagnation pro- bably was, that the State kept the gold and silver in store, and only reissued them for war and foreign enterprizes 111; although there were instances of private individuals, who amassed treasure contrary to the law. Lysander sent home a thousand, or, according to Diodorus, 1500 talents, 470 at one time 112. Must we not then suppose that the Spartans stored up large quantities of gold, especially as it was generally used for the payment of the soldiers 113? Besides the pure silver and gold, many Grecian States had a coinage, which in other countries was either wholly or nearly devoid of value, and was only destined for the 110 Plat. Alcib. 2. p. 122. ad fin. 111 See book IV. 19. 112 Plutarch. in Nic. 28. Lysand. 16-18. Diod. XIII. 106. who however probably exaggerates, if we are to suppose that this whole sum was sent at once to Sparta after the conquest of Sestos. For the latter fact of the 470 talents, see Xenoph. Hellen. III. 2. 6. 113 According to Plutarch, most of what Lysander sent was stamped with the device of an owl; he then adds as a conjec- tural reason, that most money had the Attic device. On the other hand, Corsini Fast. Att. vol. II. 235. p. be consulted: may only Plutarch's words are not to be altered, but his state- ment is either false, or the money which Lysander brought home had not been raised from Athens, but from other States, where Athenian coins were in circulation. Upon the whole, most of the silver which was in circulation had been probably issued from the Athenian mint; and this perhaps is what Plu- tarch means to say. → རྟ་ 44 internal circulation (vóμioμa Exgiov). Of this description were all copper and iron coins, the current value of which was raised by public ordinance far above its proper amount. In Athens, with the exception of the smallest coins, no money of this description was ever used, excepting that in the Archonship of Callias (Olymp. 93. 3.) a copper coinage was issued, which was afterwards recalled 114, and some other instances occurred in the times of the Roman em- perors. Concerning the prices of copper, tin, and iron in Greece, I have been unable to find any definite statement. With regard to lead, the author of the second book of the Economics ascribed to Aristotle, relates that it was gene- rally sold for two drachmas, but that Pythocles counselled the State to obtain the monopoly of this native product of the mines of Laurion, and to sell it for six drachmas. The weight is not mentioned, but the commercial talent (TáλavтOV Éμπogixòv) is doubtless intended. If we assume that the commercial talent is the talent that was in use before the time of Solon, it is equal in weight to 8280 drachmas of the silver standard, about 93lbs. troy; which therefore commonly sold for nearly 1s. 6d. and after the proposal of Pythocles for about 4s. 5d. In Rome a hun- dred lbs. of common lead, which were only equal to 7500 drachmas, sold for seven denarii115; consequently the price was higher than the rate demanded by the Athenian State. (7.) Next to the quantity of money in circulation, prices depend upon the demand in comparison with the supply; and as the demand is determined by the number of the 114 See book IV. 19. 115 Plin. Hist. Nat. XXXIV. 48. I have said, that the lead of Attica came from the mines of Laurion; the proof of this assertion is given in my Essay upon these mines, in the Trans- actions of the Berl. Acad. of Sciences. 45 # people, it will be necessary to treat of the population. The area of Attica is not easily determined, for only the coasts have been laid down, and not even these with per- fect accuracy. According to the map of Barbié du Bocage, which is attached to the Travels of Anacharsis 116, Attica contains 36½, Salamis 148, Helena German geographical square miles, i. e. respectively 579%, 21%, and 5, together nearly 606, English geographical square miles. According to the map since published by the same person in 1811 ¹¹7, which is hitherto the most accurate, Attica contains 39, Salamis 19, and Helena, square miles, or in English miles, 625, 26, and 5, amounting altogether to 656. If then we take the English geographical mile to the statute mile as 4 to 3, the area of Attica and the two islands would upon this computation be about 874 square miles. 117 To ascertain how this small space was peopled, has en- gaged the attention of many writers. The early scholars not only assert in general terms that Attica was the most populous of all the Grecian States 118, but they also have given definite accounts which establish the same result. The credibility of these statements has been indeed called into question by Montesquieu 119, Hume 120, and other English and French writers, but has been not unsuccessfully de- 116 L'Attique, la Mégaride, et partie de l'Isle d'Eubée, 1785. 117 Carte génerale de la Grèce et d'une grande partie de ses colonies tant en Europe qu'en Asie, pour le voyage du jeune Anacharse, par J. D. Barbié du Bocage commencée en 1798. terminée en 1809. Paris 1811. The calculation of the area after this map has been made for me with great accuracy by Mr. Kloeden, who is well known as skilled in this point. 118 Meursius de F. A. IV. p. 24. 119 Esprit des Lois XXXIII. 7. 120 Essay upon the Populousness of Ancient Nations p. 237 sqq. 46 fended by others. Of the latter I will mention only Ste. Croix; who with the assistance of his predecessors has treated last and the most at large of this important subject 121, and has also taken into consideration the cir- cumstances which at certain periods produced an in- crease or diminution in the population; to these how- ever in the following enquiry I shall pay no attention, partly on account of the want of adequate authorities, partly because the object of this work does not admit of my enquiries going so far into details; nor will I animad- vert upon the unimportant errors of this learned writer, which have no influence upon the main point. I pass over all attempts to determine the population of Athens from its military force, since the data, which in this case it would be necessary to consider, are in a great measure too general, without any exact distinction between the classes of the citizens, slaves, and resident aliens, and also because in every State the persons incapable of bearing arms form a considerable number; on which account the native mili- tary force can only prove that a nation had not fewer inhabitants than this or that definite number, but not accurately how great the whole amount was. The whole population of Attica would be known, if we could separately ascertain the number of the Citizens, Resident Aliens, and Slaves, together with their wives and children. The largest part of the accounts extant are of the number of the citizens; but they differ widely accord- ing to the difference of the periods, and the greater or less accuracy of the statements; but that their number was considerable, may be collected from Xenophon 122, who states 121 Mémoires de l'Académie des Inscriptions tom. XLVIII, 122 Mem. Socrat. III. 5. 2. * 47 that the Athenians were equal in number to all the Boo- tians; that is, the citizens of the one country to the citizens of the other. All particular statements, with the excep- tion of one only, which belongs to the most ancient times, vary between twenty and thirty thousand. Philochorus 123 indeed related, that even in the reign of Cecrops 20,000 men had been enumerated, by which the writer probably meant citizens; but this however is manifestly a fabulous tradition, which probably belongs to a later census of the citizens. The following account of Pollux 124 is more worthy of attention. He states that each of the 360 old families, which were included before the time of Cleisthenes in the four ancient tribes, contained 30 persons, whence the fami- lies were called τgianάdes; from which it results that the number of citizens was 10,800. If to this it is objected that a determinate number is in such a case impossible, it may be fairly answered, that at some one period, when the constitution of the tribes was regulated, this number was taken as an average, although it did not remain so. In the same manner that the Romans called the captain a centurion, even if he commanded 60 men, a family might have been called a rgiaxás, although it contained 50 or more persons. That the number of the citizens amounted to 30,000, was a customary assumption from the time of the Persian to the end of the Peloponnesian war. Hero- dotus supposes Aristagoras of Miletus to speak of 30,000 Athenians who had the right of voting 125. Aristophanes : 123 Ap. Schol. Pind. Olymp. IX. 68. where the words Tv Tv ᾿Αθηναίων δῆμον καὶ τὸ πλῆθος are not opposed to one another, but πλños (whole number of the people) is a more accurate expression. 124 VIII. 111. 125 V.97. .4 48 in the Ecclesiazusæ 126, which was written after the Anar- chy, speaks even of more than 30,000; and the author of the Axiochus 127 states that the assembly in which the gene- rals were condemned after the victory of Arginusæ, was attended by a greater number than that just mentioned : these accounts however are manifestly over-rated. Arista- goras, to express himself with effect, would not fail to select the highest number; nor need the words of a comic poet be taken so exactly; and the author of the Axiochus probably had seen no accurate returns of the population, which, after the great defeats in Sicily, and a war carried on so long with alternate success, would doubtless have shewn a very different number. Even if we were to assume that in the above enumerations of citizens who voted in the assembly, many were comprised who had not properly any right of voting, but who assumed that privilege unlawfully, still we should never arrive at so high a number as 30,000, especially since all the citizens, even on the most important affairs, never attended the assembly. The accounts which are founded upon real enumerations are of a very different character. On an occasion of a distribution of corn, which, like all other distributions, was made according to the registers of the lexiarchs among the adult citizens of 18 years of age and upwards, and upwards, a scrutiny was instituted in the Archonship of Lysimachides (Olymp. 83. 4.) into the genuineness of their birth (yosóτns). There were then found, according to Philochorus, only 14,240 genuine Athenians; and 4760, who had assumed the rights of citi- zenship unjustly, were in consequence sold as slaves. Pre- viously therefore there were 19,000 persons who passed for citizens. The amount is perhaps stated in too round a 126 Vs. 1124. 127 Cap. 12. • 49 number to be considered as completely exact. Plutarch, who probably only follows Philochorus, gives 14,040 as genuine, assuming that 5000 were rejected 128. At the breaking out of the Peloponnesian war, besides 13,000 Hoplitæ appointed for service in the field, there were also 16,000 others in Athens, who consisted of the oldest and youngest citizens and a certain number of resident aliens 129; the number of citizens must therefore at that time have been higher. Whatever vacancies were caused by war and not replaced by a fresh growth, were filled up by the occasional creation of new citizens, as was the case for example during the Archonship of Euclid (Olymp. 94. 2.). Thus in the first speech of Demo- sthenes against Aristogeiton 130, we find the number of citizens reckoned as nearly 20,000. Plato, in the Critias, assumes the same amount for the most ancient times of 128 Philochorus ap. Schol. Aristoph. Vesp. 716. Plutarch. Pericl. 37. [The word in Plutarch is gálncav, for which Mr. ἐπράθησαν, Clinton (F. H. p. 52, 390.) reads ænλάbov; and in addition to the authorities which he quotes, see Photius in v. Qeris, Bekk. Anecd. p. 201. 17. and p. 439. 32. It appears that each borough enquired into the genuineness of its own members; and that those who were rejected by the votes of the burghers (ἀποψηφισθέντες) lost the rights of citizenship. If they then appealed to the de- cision of a court of justice, and were a second time rejected, their persons were sold, and their property confiscated.] 129 Thucyd. II. 13. • 130 P. 785. 24. The spuriousness of the second speech is ac- knowledged by both ancients and moderns. Dionysius doubts whether the first was the production of Demosthenes; and in Harpocration (in v. tagis) it is quoted with a suspicion of its authenticity. I leave this point undecided, but it certainly belongs to that period. For the usage of μov in the passage referred to, see Hesych. Suid. Harpocr. and Phot. in v. ¡µoũ. VOL. I. E 50 Athens, in which he has doubtless transferred the number that was commonly computed in his own time to the earliest periods of the State; and the modern Grecian writers, as Libanius for instance, follow the same state- ment 131. An occurrence of the same period exactly coin- cides with the statement in the speech of Demosthenes. When Lycurgus divided the property of Diphilus amount- ing to 160 talents, each citizen received 50 drachmas, which gives 19,200 for their whole number. The assertion that in the reign of Antipater (Olymp. 114. 2.) Athens contained 21,000 citizens 133, is inadmissible, as being taken from a later enumeration; and Diodorus 134 even goes so far as to suppose that there were 31,000, reckoning 23,000, instead of 12,000 as in Plutarch, who were de- prived of the rights of citizenship, and he assumes 9000 as the surplus, agreeing in the latter point with Plutarch. These 12,000 rejected citizens, some of whom had left the country, were restored to their rights in Olymp. 115. 3.135 Soon after this an enumeration of the people occurs, which is the very one to which the number mentioned in Plutarch of the citizens who remained and were disfranchised in 131 See Meursius de F. A. IV. According to the interpreta- tion of the Scholiast, the same number of citizens may be in- ferred from Aristoph. Vesp. 707. it is not however distinctly expressed in the words of Aristophanes. 132 Lives of the Ten Orators near the end of the Life of Ly- curgus. The addition, й és tives µvõv, does not deserve any atten- " tion. 133 Plutarch. Phoc. 28. 134 XVIII. 18. It appears to me that the passage ought by no means to be altered, as Diodorus so frequently exaggerates numbers. 135 Diod. XVIII. 66. 51 the reign of Antipater, was adapted. It was carried on by Demetrius Phalereus when Archon in Olymp. 117. 4.136 and yielded, according to Ctesicles 137, 21,000 citizens, 10,000 resident aliens, and 400,000 slaves. From this very important statement the whole number of the popula- tion of Attica has been variously determined. According to the usual rule of Statistics, the adults have been generally taken as a fourth part of the population. This gave for the citizens 84,000, and for the aliens 40,000. But when they came to the slaves, these calculators fell into an embarrassment; for, according to the same or a somewhat lower proportion, their number came out far above what could be deemed probable. Hume, wishing to shew that the population of ancient times has been greatly over- rated, contends with many reasons against this number of slaves, and ends by substituting 40,000 in the place of 400,000, whom he considers as the adults, to which it would be then necessary to add the women and children. But his arguments are partly inconclusive, and partly founded upon false suppositions. Thus all that he says. concerning the national wealth of Attica, that it was only equal to 6000 talents, is completely false; and, in the next place, slaves were not computed by adults or fathers of fa- milies, which is a term wholly inapplicable to slaves; but they were counted, like sheep or cattle, by the head, and were regarded in the same light with property, as Gillies 138 136 This is the right date which Ste. Croix has given, p. 64. 137 Ap. Athen. VI. p. 272. B. 138 Essays on the History, Customs, and Character of the Greeks, p. 15. of the German translation of Macher. This translation exceeds its original, which is really difficult, in mean- ness and vulgarity. 52 # has already observed, for they were in the strictest sense a personal possession. 400,000 is therefore the sum total of the slaves; and the population of Attica would amount, on this supposition, to 524,000 souls. Wallace's com- putation is higher, for he makes the whole population amount to more than 580,000, and Sainte Croix goes as far as 639,500. The latter writer erroneously adds 100,000 children to the number of slaves, and likewise 4 and not 4 for every male adult or father of a family, so that the free as well as the slave population is made more numerous. As however this proportion appears to be more correct for southern countries, the citizens with their families may be fairly taken at 94,500, and the resident aliens at 45,000. In order however not to proceed solely upon the period of Demetrius, but upon the mean average of 20,000 citizens, I reckon only 90,000 free inhabitants, and 45,000 resident aliens. With regard to the total amount of slaves, it is stated too much in round numbers for perfect accuracy; the historian doubtless added whatever was wanting to com- plete the last hundred thousand, although the correct number might not have been so great by several thousands. It will be sufficient to reckon 365,000 slaves together with women and children, which latter however were propor- tionally few. Adding to these 135,000 free inhabitants, we may take as a mean average of the population 500,000 in round numbers; of whom the larger proportion were men, since fewer female than male slaves were kept, and not many slaves were married. The proportion of the free inhabitants to the slaves can be consequently taken as 27 to 100, or nearly as one to four. In the American sugar plantations it was as much as one to six. This number of slaves cannot appear too large, if the political circumstances of Attica are taken 53 into consideration. Even the poorer citizens used to have a slave 139 for the care of their household affairs. In every moderate establishment many were employed for all pos- sible occupations, such as grinders, bakers, cooks, tailors, errand-boys, or to accompany the master and mistress, who seldom went out without an attendant. Any one who was expensive and wished to attract attention, took perhaps three attendants with him 140. We even hear of philosophers who kept ten slaves 141. Slaves were also let out as hired servants; they performed all the labour con- nected with the care of cattle, and agriculture; they were employed in the working of the mines and furnaces; all manual labour and the lower branches of trade were in a great measure carried on by them; large gangs laboured in the numerous workshops, for which Athens was celebrated; and a considerable number were em- ployed in the merchant vessels and the fleet. Not to enumerate many instances of persons who had a smaller number of slaves, Timarchus kept in his workshop eleven or twelve 142; Demosthenes' father 52 or 53, besides the female slaves in his house 143; Lysias and Polemarchus 120 144. Plato expressly remarks that the free inhabit- ants had frequently 50 slaves, and the rich even more 145; Philemonides had 300, Hipponicus 600, Nicias 1000 slaves 139 See for example the beginning of the Plutus of Aristo- phanes. 140 Demosth. pro Phorm. p. 958. 14. 141 Ste. Croix, p. 172. 142 Æschin. in Timarch. p. 118. 143 Demosth. in Aphob. A. p. 816. cf. p. 828. 1. 144 Lysias in Eratosth. p. 395. 145 De Republ. IX. p. 578. D. E. 54 in the mines alone 146. These facts prove the existence of an immense number of slaves. But Hume raises an objec- tion out of Xenophon. Xenophon 147 proposed to the State to buy public slaves for the mines, and particularly men- tions how large a revenue the State would receive from them, if it had 10,000 to begin with, remarking at the same time, "that the mines are able to receive many times this num- ber, every body will allow, who remembers how much the slave-duty produced before the occurrences at Decelea." From this statement Hume infers that the number cannot have been so excessive, for that the diminution by the war of Decelea only amounted to 20,000148, and the increase of 10,000 does not stand in any considerable proportion to so large a number as 400,000. It must however be con- sidered that after the war of Decelea the Athenians pro- bably ceased to keep many slaves on account of the facility of escape, and that a still greater number than ran away, may have been dismissed. Xenophon himself says that the number had been very great formerly, and he means that their numbers before the war of Decelea prove that the mines, of which alone he is speaking, could afford employment to many times 10,000. At the same time I will not deny that the passage has a very strange appear- ance, and is obscured by manifold difficulties; but this is the very reason why we should avoid founding any argu- ment upon it. There are two other statements, equally 146 Xenoph. de Vectig. 4. 117 Ut sup. 148 Thucyd. VII. 27. An important statement contained in a fragment of Hy- perides with regard to the slave-population, which has been overlooked by the author, is quoted by Mr. Clinton from Suidas in v. exspicato (F. H. p. 391.); where it is mentioned that the 55 called into question by Hume, which are far more in- comprehensible, viz. of Timæus, that Corinth once had possessed 460,000, and of Aristotle, that Ægina had contained 470,000 slaves 149. Nevertheless the numbers do not appear to be corrupt. That the Corinthians kept a very large number of slaves is proved by the expression Chanix-measurers (xowixoμérgai) by which they were dis- tinguished, nor is it possible that Ægina before and during the Persian war up to the time of its decline could have been a great commercial town, and have had an extensive naval force, without a large population, and above all many slaves. Its naval dominion, and its powerful resist- ance against Athens are incompatible with a small popula- tion. Why then may we not suppose that 470,000 slaves © slaves employed in the silver mines and in country labour were more than 150,000. 149 Athen. VI. p. 272. B. D. Schol. Pind. Olymp. VIII. 30. • The size of Ægina which is supposed in the text, was estimated according to the deceitful representation which is given of it in the common maps of Greece. In the mean time a learned pupil of the author, who is at present occupied about a history of that island, has more accurately determined the area from Gell's map of Argolis at nearly two square miles (forty-two square miles English), whence the possibility of a large population is increased, and the number of slaves is less. striking; especially if we assume, as is probable, that Ægina had possessions in early times upon the coast of Argolis. The person alluded to in this note, which is given from the Addenda, is the celebrated C. O. Müller, who published his Æginetica in 1817, from which work the following words are extracted (p. 5. note). "Sed major fides deberi videtur de- scriptioni Gellii Angli Argol. Ib. 28. ubi ambitus xweis rou xarα- xoλica: ducentorum et decem stadiorum est, spatium vero, quod complectitur, exacte computatum, stadiorum quadratorum 3164.” See also pp. 128, 129. 56 +. lived upon this small district, being only a German square mile; there still remained sufficient space, as slaves never occupied much room. Ægina received supplies from the countries upon the Black Sea, as well as the Peloponnese 150, and particularly from Corinth. In the mean time it is hardly necessary to remark that this large population of Corinth and Ægina must only be understood of the early times, before Athens had obtained possession of the com- merce of Greece and the sovereignty of the sea. In what manner this population of 500,000 souls in Attica was distributed, cannot be accurately determined. Athens itself contained above 10,000 houses. In general only one family lived in a house, and fourteen free in- habitants were at that time a large number for one house or for one family 151. Lodging houses (σvvoixías) were how- ever inhabited by several families, and manufactories con- tained many hundreds of slaves. The district of the mines must also have been very thickly peopled. The circumference of the city together with the sea-ports was equal to 200 stadii. The mines were in a space 60 stadii in width: the other dimension is not known. If 180,000 persons are reckoned for the city and harbours, and 20,000 for the mines, and the space for both taken at 32 square miles English, the number assumed would not be too high. There then remain 300,000 souls for the other 608 square miles, which gives something less than 493 to a square mile, which with the number of small towns or market-places, villages, and farms that were in Attica, is not to be wondered at. Now this population necessarily required a large supply of provisions. It should : 150 Herod. VII. 147. and thence Polyænus in the Strategics. 151 Xenoph. Soc. Mem. II. 7. 2. 57 however be borne in mind, that slaves were badly fed, and above all, that corn alone was requisite for their sustenance. How large a quantity of corn was required, and how the necessary supplies could be procured, I shall endeavour to determine presently. (8.) All commodities which are necessary for the pur- poses of life, are procured either by the domestic produc- tion and manufacture of the raw material, or by foreign commerce. Attica was not so unsuited for agriculture as is often supposed. The soil was indeed stony and uneven in many places; a great part was bare rock, where nothing could be sown; the less fertile soil however produced bar- ley 152 and wheat, the latter indeed with greater difficulty; and the mildness of the climate allowed all the more valuable products of the earth to ripen the earliest, and to go out of season the latest 153. Every sort of plant and animal thrived in spite of the poverty of the soil 154. Art also undoubtedly performed its share; for the ancients in all concerns of common life were possessed of sound principles founded on experience; and at so early a period as the time of Socrates, writings were extant upon agriculture 155. Agriculture was in as great estimation among the Athe- nians as with the Romans, if we may judge from the high encomiums of Xenophon and Aristotle 156. The latter 152 Thucyd. I. 2. where the commentators quote other passages upon the sterility of the soil. See more particularly the Intro- duction to Xenophon's Treatise on the Revenues. 153 Xenoph. ibid. 154 Plat. Crit. p. 110. E. 155 See my Preface to the Dialogues of Simon the Socratic Philosopher, p. XIX. 156 Xenoph. Econ. 4 sqq. Aristot. Polit. VI. 4. and the first book of the Economics attributed to Aristotle, which at least contains the principles of that philosopher. 58 . calls an agricultural people the most just; agriculture is represented as that species of industry, which is most just and conformable to nature; the most just because it does not gain from men, either according to their wills, as in paid labour and commerce, or against their wills, as in war; the most agreeable to nature, because every thing receives nourishment from its mother, and the earth is the mother of men. The ancients also esteemed agriculture, because it made their bodies and minds strong and active, and trained them for service in the field, whereas most kinds of manufactures and commerce weakened and ener- vated both. The opulent, however, only occupied themselves with the superintendence; and most of the manual labour fell upon the slaves, who were servants, and frequently also stewards, and who unquestionably lessened the expences of cultivation, whatever the moderns may advance against the cheapness of slave labour. Thus the cultivator derived sufficient support from his own farm, and in dear times the agriculturists even grew unduly rich 157. The most con- siderable produce was of wine, olives, figs, and honey; wine was probably better in other places; but the oil and honey were particularly excellent 158, the latter especially in the district of the mines 159, and upon mount Hymettus. The figs likewise were very much esteemed. Even now the keeping of the bees is carried on to a considerable ex- tent in Attica. The olive-trees make regular woods, and the wine is considered wholesome 160. For the protection of this branch of industry, laws were enacted that these pro- 157 Orat. in Phænipp. p. 1045. 12. 158 Pseud-Eschin. Epist. 5. 159 Strab. IX. p. 275. 160 See Wheler, Chandler, and other travellers. Concerning comp. Meursius Fort. Att. chap. X. oil ì 59 ducts should not be diminished, and that one person should not be injured by another in raising them; hence the ordi- nances of Solon with regard to the keeping of bees 161; hence no olive-tree could be rooted up, excepting that each proprietor was allowed to destroy two in each year for pub- lic festivals, or for his own use in the case of a death 162. Many of these products of the soil were exported, although, according to Plutarch 163, Solon prohibited all export of pro- visions, as might be seen from the first Table of the Laws of Solon; but fortunately this writer afterwards contradicts himself, when in another place he mentions the famous prohibition to export figs as no more than probable 164. The exportation of oil alone is said to have been permitted by Solon, as Plutarch also remarks, and in this point his testimony is confirmed by examples 165. As to the pro- hibition of the export of figs, I am entirely convinced that it did not exist in the times of which we have any certain knowledge. All that occurs in ancient writers upon this subject, only serves to explain the meaning of the term sycophant. Plutarch himself ventures to adopt it at the most for the very early times. If however the ancients had possessed any account of such a law, that could be at all depended upon, they would not speak in so vague and indefinite a manner concerning the origin of this appella- 161 Petit Leg. Att. V. 1. 6. 162 Demosth. in Macart. p. 1074. 163 Solon. 24. 164 De Curiositate, ad fin. 165 Plutarch Solon. 2. where Plato is said to carry on a trade in oil; and although it refers to later times, the law of Solon may still have been in force in reference to such cases. Petit Leg. Att. V. 5. 1. absurdly limits the permission to export oil to the cruise filled with oil given to the victors in the Panathenaic games. 60 tion. If a prohibition ever did exist, it certainly was not caused by the reason which is jocularly mentioned by Hume 166, that the Athenians thought their figs too ex- pensive for foreign palates, although Athenæus 167 nearly uses the same expression; but the object of the measure must have been to increase the quantity of figs in the country, while they were as yet very scarce in the most ancient times. This view of the case may be formed from the scholiast upon Plato 168, who dates the origin of the name of sycophant at a period when this fruit was first discovered in Attica, and did not grow in any other country. But the account is far more probable which states that the sacred fig-trees were robbed of their fruit during a famine, and that the wrath of the gods being felt in con- sequence of this sacrilege, accusations were brought against the suspected 169. In the same manner persons who in- jured the sacred olive-trees might be subjected to heavy penalties, of which Lysias in his defence concerning the sacred olive-trees affords a remarkable instance. Here then it would be impossible to understand a prohibition of exportation, which can only exist with regard to articles necessary for the consumption of the community, such for example as corn. The keeping of cattle unquestionably existed to a considerable extent: sheep and goats were the most numerous. From the latter animal one of the four 166 Ut sup. p. 81. p. 167 III. 74. E. where see Casaubon. The same writer treats of the Sycophants ad Theophrast. Char. 23. cf. Ast ad Plat. de Repub. p. 361. ed. 2. Petit Leg. Att. V. 5. 2. does not give any clear account of this point. To the passages quoted by earlier writers Lex. Seg. p. 304. may also be added. 168 P. 147. Ruhnk. cf. Schol. Aristoph. Plut. 874. 169 Schol. Aristoph. Plut. 31. 61 ancient tribes, Ægicoreis, took its name; which from the time of Cleisthenes remained only a borough; of the former there were many different breeds, and particularly of the finest kinds 170. In order to encourage the keeping of sheep, it was forbidden in a law of extreme antiquity, to kill them before they had lambed or been shorn 171: but this and similar regulations had been long abolished in the time of Solon. Pigs were also kept, and of larger cattle, asses and mules in tolerable quantities. Horses and horned cattle were evidently scarce in early times. Philochorus 172 mentions a very ancient law which prohibited the killing of horned cattle; and the scarcity of horses is manifest from the early insignificance of the Athenian cavalry, which, after the establishment of the Naucrarias, only amounted to 96 or 100 men, and was not even in existence at the time of the battle of Marathon. Subsequently horses and oxen were kept in sufficient quantities, for which the pastures of Euboea afforded great facilities. The woodlands for the most part only supplied firewood; the ship-building was carried on with imported timber. The fisheries were productive; the mines, in addition to silver, yielded lead, metallic colours, coloured earths, perhaps also copper; and the products of the Athe- nian foundaries were particularly esteemed. The quarries of Pentelus and Hymettus furnished the most beautiful 170 Demosth. in Euerg. et Mnesib. p. 1155. 3. or whoever is the author of this speech, which is called in question by the ancients (see Harpocrat. in v. névny), Athen. XII. p. 540. D. 171 Androt. ap. Athen. IX. p. 375. C. Philochorus ibid. I. p. 9. C. Other ancient laws to the same effect have been col- lected by Petit V. 3. 172 Ap. Athen. IX. p. 375. C. W 62 kinds of marble, which were much exported to foreign parts 173. Commercial occupations were never in great esteem among the ancient Greeks. No person of ancient nobility ever condescended to them, although conversely a manufacturer might raise himself to the head of public affairs, such as Cleon, Hyperbolus, and others. The early statesmen however encouraged industry, especially Solon, Themistocles, and Pericles, partly with the intention of improving the condition of the lower classes, and partly of increasing the population of the city; as well as of advanc- ing the cause of commerce, and of manning the numerous fleets, by which, after the time of Themistocles, the Athenians held the mastery of the sea 174. And it was this circumstance that rendered the resident aliens indis- pensable for Athens 175, who carried on manufactures and * 173 Cf. Xenoph. de Vectig. 1. 174 Proofs of this occur every where. Diodorus (XI. 43.) in particular expresses himself very clearly with regard to Themis- tocles. 175 Xenophon de Rep. Ath. I. 12. The genuineness of this Essay stands and falls with the other Treatise on the State of the Lacedæmonians, which Demetrius the Magnesian (ap. Diog. Laërt. II. 57.) abjudged from Xenophon. But the Essay upon the Revenues of Athens is so similar to those two in style, that it must be included in their condemnation; and it is cer- tainly possible to raise doubts against the latter writing, which however I consider as futile. The predilection for Sparta which predominates in the two first writings, is very like Xenophon, who even in his history is the constant eulogist of the Spartans, and frequently allows his predilections to give a colour to real facts. A certain irony in the tone, which occurs in the Pamphlet upon the State of Athens, is not very much in Xenophon's manner, but it might have been easily produced by particular circumstances and by the nature of his subject. It should be ob- • 63 commerce to a great extent, and were bound to serve in the fleet. It even appears that the useful arts were encouraged by honorary rewards 176; though even by these means they could not gain in the public estimation. There were prizes for the common people, for which the higher ranks did not compete with them. At the same time the respectable citizens, who had none of the high aristocratical notions, like Pericles, Alcibiades, or Callias the son of Hipponicus, whose pride yielded in nothing to the haughtiness of the modern nobility, were not ashamed of superintending extensive manufactories worked at their own expence. The inferior citizens were as much reduced to the necessity of manual labour as the poor aliens and slaves. It was not until after the balance had been turned served, that contradictions may be discovered between this writ- ing and the other upon the Revenues; thus in Rep. Ath. 1. 10. the freedom of the aliens is found fault with, whereas in the Treatise on the Revenues (chap. 2.) he recommends favouring them, and lightening their burdens, together with other dis- crepancies of the same kind: but the difference of the times, ob- jects, and circumstances must be taken into consideration, from which these contradictions are easily accounted for, if Xenophon wrote on the State of Athens during his exile, and on the Revenues after his recal, a short time, as it is asserted, before his death took place at Corinth. The arguments also learnedly brought forward by Schneider concerning the date of his writing, which tend to prove it not to be the production of Xenophon, are not entirely tenable, as I have shewn in book III. 5. At the same time I am willing to allow that the genuineness of this and other short writings of Xenophon is not sufficiently established, and that the Essay on the State of Athens may easily have been written by another author. All I wish to assert is, that the arguments which have as yet been brought against their authenticity, are not sufficient, and that a farther investigation is necessary. 176 Schol. Aristoph. Ran. 775. ? • 64 in favour of the aristocracy, that measures of severity were brought forward; as for example, Diophantus proposed that all the manual labourers should be made public slaves 177. There was again another reason why no restriction should have been imposed upon the freedom of industry, viz. the little importance that was attached to it; an alien was allowed to carry on any trade, although he was pro- hibited from holding any property in land; with regard indeed to the sale in the market, strangers were on a less advantageous footing than natives, as they were obliged to pay a duty for permission to expose their goods there. The law of Solon that men should not deal in oint- ments 178 was only founded on principles of education, in order to withdraw men from womanish labours; subse- quently however it became a dead letter, for Æschines the philosopher had a manufactory of ointments. With this entire freedom of industry, with the numbers of aliens and slaves, and the possibility of an extensive market by means of foreign commerce, and with the magnitude of the internal demand, which was increased by the resident foreigners, all branches of industry flourished, and Athens contained a large number of manufactories, which employed a corresponding quantity of labourers. Athenian arms and other metallic fabrics, implements and materials for dress and furniture, were in great request; tanners, arm-smiths, lamp-makers, cloth-weavers, even millers and bakers, who understood their art well, lived in abundance 179. With regard to the prices of commodities, it would be natural to 177 Petit V. 6. 1. 178 Petit V. 6. 3. 179 Only to quote one passage, see Xenoph. Mem. Socr. II. 7. 3-6. With regard to the exportation of manufactured goods, see Wolf ad Leptin. p. 252. 65 suppose that they must have been proportionally low, as all the labourers, and part even of the overseers were slaves; as the rate of wages was moderate, and there existed a complete freedom of industry; but to counterbalance these causes there was the extensive exportation, which together with the high rate of interest, and the proportion- ally high profits, that the manufacturers and merchants took, operated to force up the prices of commodities. At the same time many articles, such as bread and clothing, were prepared in most families at home, and not purchased from tradespeople. (9.) The commodities which Attica did not produce within her own territory, were obtained by foreign com- merce, and unless the importation was prevented by some extraordinary obstacle, such for example as war, there could be no danger of a scarcity, even in the case of a failure of the crops, because it consumed the surplus produce of other countries 180. Although not an island, yet it pos- sessed all the advantages of insular position, that is, excel- lent harbours conveniently situated, in which it received supplies during all winds; in addition to which it had suf- ficient facilities for inland traffic: the intercourse with other countries was promoted by the purity of the coin, as the merchant, not being obliged to take a return freight, had the option of carrying out bullion, although Athens abounded in commodities which would meet with a ready sale 181. For prohibitions to export money were unknown in ancient times, and are only compatible with the use of bills of ex- change. If a stagnation in trade was not produced by war or piracy, all the products of foreign countries came to 180 Cf. Xenoph. de Repub. Ath. 2. 6. 181 Xenoph. de Vectig. 1. 7. 3, 2. VOL. I. F 66 Athens; and articles which in other places could hardly be obtained singly, were collected together at the Piraeus 182. Besides the corn, the costly wines, iron, brass, and other objects of commerce which came from all the regions of the Mediterranean, they imported from the coasts of the Black Sea, slaves, timber for ship building, salt-fish, honey, wax, tar, wool, rigging, leather, goat-skins, &c.; from Byzantium, Thrace, and Macedonia, timber, slaves, and salt-fish; also slaves from Thessaly, whither they came from the interior; and carpets and fine wool from Phrygia and Miletus 183 "All the finest products," says Xenophon 184," of Sicily, of Italy, Cyprus, Lydia, the Pontus, and the Peloponnese, Athens, by her empire of the sea, is able to collect into one spot:" to this far extended intercourse the same author attributes the mixture of all dialects which pre- vailed at Athens, and the admission of barbarous words into the language of common life. On the other hand, Athens conveyed to different regions the products of her own soil and labour; in addition to which the Athenian merchants trafficked in commodities which they collected in other countries. Thus they took up wine from the islands and shores of the Ægæan Sea, at Peparethos, Cos, Thasos, Mende, Scione, and elsewhere, and transported it to the Pontus 185. The trade in books appears alone to have made but small advances in Greece, a branch of industry which was more widely extended in the Roman empire after the reign of Augustus. There was, it is true, 182 Thucyd. II. 38. Isocrat. Paneg. p. 34. ed. Hall. 183 Upon most of these points see Barthélemy Anachars. tom. IV. chap. 55. Wolf ad Leptin. p. 252. 184 De Rep. Ath. 2. 7. 185 Demosth. in Lacrit. p. 935, 6. 67 a book market (rà ßißλa) 186 at Athens, and books were exported to the Pontus and to Thrace 187; but there can be no doubt that the books meant were merely blank volumes. The trade in manuscripts was in the time of Plato so little common, that Hermodorus, who sold the books of this writer in Sicily, gave occasion to a proverb, "Hermodorus carries on trade with writings 188." at a subsequent period, while Zeno the Stoic was still a youth, dealers in manuscripts are mentioned as having been at Athens 189. The merchant-vessels appear to have been of considerable size; not to quote an extraordinary in- stance, we find in Demosthenes 190 a vessel of this kind, which besides the cargo, the slaves, and the ship's-crew, carried 300 free inhabitants. Athens had many regulations for the protection of trade, and for the maintenance of the commercial police. Among the officers belonging to this branch of the public service we may mention the Overseers of the Harbour (μλyτai Tоũ μπogíov), ten men annually appointed by lot 191; the Agoranomi, five in the city and as many in the Piraeus 192; the Metronomi, who had the inspection of the measures, ten in the city and five in the Piraeus 193; and the Pro- 186 Poll. IX. 47. and the commentators. 187 Xenoph. Cyr. Exped. VII. 5. 14. and the commentators. 188 Cicer. Epist. ad Attic. XIII. 21. Zenob. and Suid. in v. λόγοισιν Ἑρμόδωρος ἐμπορεύεται. 189 Diog. Laërt. in Vit. Zenonis. 190 In Phorm. p. 910. 12. 191 Demosth. in Lacrit. p. 941. 15. Orat. in Theocrin. p. 1324. 10. Dinarch. in Aristog. p. 81, 82. Lex. Seg. p. 255. and what Sigonius IV. 3. has upon the Constitution of Athens. 192 Aristot. ap. Harpocrat. in v. ȧyogaróμo, &c. 193 The passage in Harpocration is as follows: oav dè ròv ἀριθμὸν πεντεκαίδεκα, εἰς μὲν τὸν Πειραῖα δέκα, πέντε δ' εἰς ἄστυ. I read 68 metretæ, probably subordinate to the latter officers, who measured corn and other grain for hire 194. Upon the whole there was sufficient attention paid to weights and measures; as may in part be seen from a valuable frag- ment of a decree upon this subject, which has fortunately come down to our days 195. Credit was at a low ebb in Greece, although we find that there were large firms in all the different Grecian states, which were possessed of ex- tensive credit, and were able to raise money on the single security of their name 196. Merchants belonging to par- ticular cities, as the Phaselitans for example, were in bad repute on account of their want of honesty. The absence - it the contrary way, εἰς μὲν τὸν Πειραῖα πέντε, δέκα δ᾽ εἰς ἄστυ. The same correction should be made in Suidas in v. pergovóμos and in Photius. For what Meursius and Küster say upon the passage in Suidas is highly absurd. There were therefore ten Sitophylaces in the city and five in the Piraeus: see below chap. 15. Both divisions must necessarily have been closely connected, and for this reason the similarity of the number is also probable. In addition to this, the merchants were obliged to bring two thirds of the corn from the harbour into the city, which fact agrees com- pletely with my emendation. The Lex.. Seg. p. 278. certainly has in v. μετρονόμοι, δέκα τὸν ἀριθμὸν, ὧν πέντε μὲν ἦσαν ἐν τῷ Πειραιεῖ, Tévre d'iv äotel, together with Photius in the first article. But although it might appear more natural that their number should agree with that of the Agoranomi, and seem singular that there should have been ten in the city and five in the Piraeus, this very circumstance makes it more credible that my hypothesis is true, and that the statement in the Lex. Seg. is the arbitrary alteration of a grammarian according to what appeared to him the most natural. A different account is given by Kühn ad Poll. IV. 167. 194 Harpocrat. in v. goμerental, Lex. Seg. p. 290. &c. 195 See Inscript. 123. tom. I. p. 164. ed. Boeckh. 196 Demosth. in Polycl. p. 1224. 3. pang 69 of credit was supplied by security or bail 197; which, ac- cording to the laws of Athens, was in force for one year 198. The severity of the laws relating to debtors contributed materially to the support of credit, for the Athenians knew well how important these laws were to commerce and industry 199. "In the Athenian laws," says Demosthenes, "there are many excellent protections for the creditor; for commerce proceeds not from the borrower but from the lender; without whose assistance no vessel, no captain, no passenger can stir." Even a citizen, who in the capacity of a merchant, withdrew from a creditor a pledge for a sum vested in bottomry, could be punished with loss of life 200. No less severe were the regulations against false accusers of merchants and captains of vessels 201. Their disputes were heard before the com- mercial court of the Nautodica, where the Thesmothetæ introduced the causes 202; in law-suits between citizens of different nations, by virtue of a particular agreement there existed an appeal from one state to the other 203. As early as in the time of Lysias, the Nautodicæ, having been appointed to their office by lot, assembled in the month 197 Demosth. in Lacrit. init. 198 Demosth. in Apatur. p. 901. 7. 199 Demosth. pro Phorm. p. 958. 200 Demosth. in Phorm. p. 922. Dilatory debtors were also liable to imprisonment, only however in commercial cases. Hudtwalker von den Diäteten, p. 152 sq. See 201 Orat. in Theocrin. p. 1324, 1325. cf. inf. III. 10. 202 For the sake of brevity I refer to Sigonius R. A. IV. 3. Petit V. 5.9. Matthiä Misc. Philol. vol. I. p. 247. The Lex. Seg. also has an article upon this subject, as well as Photius p. 212. It is worthy of remark that the yeapǹ Ževías could also be brought before this court. 203 These are the δίκαι ἀπὸ συμβόλων. 70 Gamelion, in order to sit during the winter, when naviga- tion ceased 204, that the merchants and captains of vessels might not be impeded in the pursuit of their business. Advantageous as this regulation was, it did not obviate all the inconveniences to which traders were liable; for if the cause was not decided in the course of the winter, either the parties were obliged to prosecute it in summer to the prejudice of their business, or the case stood over till the following winter, and was heard before other judges. For this reason Xenophon proposed to establish a prize for the officer of the harbour who should pronounce the most rapid and just decisions of commercial causes 205; and in fact soon afterwards in the time of Philip 206 this evil was checked by the introduction of the monthly suits (μunvor díxai), to which all causes concerning trade, Eranus, dowries, and mines belonged 207. These were heard in the six winter months, so that the merchants might quickly obtain their rights and set sail 208; and a cause could not, as some have supposed, be protracted through this whole time, but it was necessary that it should be decided within the term of a month 209. Lastly, the Greeks tolerated a species of consul in the person of the Proxenus of each state, who was considered as the representative of his 204 Lysias περὶ δημοσ. ἀδικ. p. 593. 205 De Vectig. 3. 206 Vid. Orat. de Haloneso. p. 79. 18. sqq. 207 Poll. VIII. 63, 101. Suidas in v. éµpenvoi díxa from Har- pocr. in the same word, Lex. Seg. p. 237. That this is true of causes relating to mines. I have shewn in my Essay upon the silver mines of Laurion. 208 Demosth. in Apatur. p. 900. 3. cf. p. 966. 17. Petit V. 5. 9. 209 Vid. Orat. de Haloneso, Lex. Seg. and Petit. ut sup. Salmas. de M. U. XVI. p. 691. 71 L country, and was bound to receive the citizens who traded at the place. If for example an inhabitant of Heraclea died at any place, the Proxenus of Heraclea was by virtue of his office obliged to give information concerning the property which he left behind him 210. If an inhabitant of Heraclea died at Argos, the Proxenus of Heraclea received his property211. Among the many proposals for the advancement of commerce which Xenophon makes in his Treatise upon the Revenues, there is no where an exhortation to restore the freedom of trade: either this was not one of the points which lay within the knowledge of antiquity; or it must have existed without any limit. The latter supposition is nearly maintained by Heeren 212: "they were ignorant," says he, "of a balance of trade, and thus all the violent measures that flow from it naturally remained unknown. They had custom-duties as well as ourselves; but their only object was to increase the revenues of the state, and not as with modern nations, by prohibiting this or that article to give a particular direction to the course of industry. You will find no prohibition to export raw produce, no encouragement of manufactures at the cost of the agricultural classes. In this sense then there was a complete freedom of industry, of commerce, and of inter- course. And this was not the result of accident, but was founded upon principle. At the same time, where every thing was determined according to circumstances, not according to theory, persons may find individual excep- tions, perhaps discover particular cases in which the 210 Demosth. in Callipp. p. 1237. 16. 211 Ibid. p. 1238. 27. 212 Ideen über die Politik, den Verkehr und den Handel der Alten Welt, vol. III. p. 283. 72 state may for a time have assumed to itself a monopoly. But yet what a wide difference is there between this and our mercantile and compulsory system." I am ready to acknowledge that there is a great deal of truth in these remarks; but the other side of the question must also be considered. According to the principles of the ancients, which were not merely scientific, but were recognised by the whole of the people, and deeply rooted in the nature of the Greeks, the state embraced and governed all dealings between man and man. Not in Crete and Lacedæmon alone, two states completely closed up and from their position unsusceptible of free trade, but gene- rally throughout the whole of Greece, and even under the free and republican government of Athens, the poorest as well as the richest citizen was convinced that the state had the right of claiming the whole property of every indi- vidual any restriction in the transfer of this property, regulated according to circumstances, was looked upon as just; nor could it properly be considered an infringement of justice, before the security of persons and property was held to be the sole object of government; a light under which it never was viewed by any of the ancients. On the contrary, all intercourse and commerce were considered as being under the direction of the community, inasmuch as they originally owed their existence to the establishment of a regular political union: and upon the same basis was founded the right of the state to regulate trade, or even to participate in the profits of it. Any person who dissented from these principles was not a member of the state, and would by the bare avowal be considered as detaching himself from it. It was upon the same principle that the national monopolies were founded, which do not appear to have been unfrequent in Greece, although of short : 73 duration; their productiveness had been tried in the cases of private individuals who had obtained them by engrossing particular articles 213. It can however be safely asserted, that no republic ever demanded of its citizens that they should furnish commodities to the state in specified quantities and at prices arbitrarily fixed at a low rate, with a view to secure to itself a monopoly; such a demand could only have been enforced in countries under the government of a tyrant. The monopoly of lead, which Pythocles proposed to the Athenians, injured no proprietor of mines, provided it was exported: the producers were to receive the same price from the state, at which they had before sold it 214. Equally innocent was the banking monopoly which the Byzantians in a pecuniary embarrass- ment sold to a private individual 215. The proceeding of the Selymbriani in a similar difficulty was probably less defensible, who seized the whole stock of corn at a fixed price, with the exception of a quantity sufficient for the yearly consumption of each individual, and then sold it at a higher price with permission to export, which before had not been granted 216. Yet after all how many kinds of monopolies may there have been in Greece! Probably it was then a principle in politics, that states should avail themselves of these aids when under the pressure of pecuniary distresses 217. In addition to this there are abundant proofs that the exportation and importation were regulated according to the exigencies and interests of 213 Cf. Arist. Pol. I. 7. 214 See above, chap. 6. 215 See the second book of the Economics attributed to Aris- totle. 216 Ibid. 217 Cf. Arist. Pol. I. 11. 1 74 the state; which is by no means consistent with perfect freedom of trade. Aristotle 218 lays down five principles of policy as the most important, viz. finance, peace and war, the safeguard of the country, importation and export- ation, and legislation; mentioning at the same time that "with regard to importation and exportation, it is neces- sary to know how large a supply of provisions the state requires, and what proportion of them can be produced in the country and what imported, and what imports and exports are necessary for the state, in order that com- mercial treaties and agreements may be concluded with those of whom the state must make use for this purpose." Trade was thus an object of national policy; whence various restrictions or preferences must necessarily have arisen. Solon is related by Plutarch to have laid the exportation of all products of the soil except oil, under a malediction, which the Archon was obliged to pronounce or to pay a fine of a hundred drachmas 219: although the law was not in my opinion so general as here stated 220 , yet the main fact is unquestionable; and, considering the liberal disposition of Solon, is the more remarkable. The export of corn was always prohibited in Attica 221. Similar laws doubtless existed in other states; for example the Selymbriani prohibited the exportation of corn, if not always, at least in time of scarcity 222. There were also at Athens many commodities of which the exportation was prohibited (άπóggnτa), such as timber, tar, wax, rigging, 218 Rhetor. I. 4. 219 Plutarch. Sol. 24. 220 See above, chap. 8. 221 Ulpian. ad Demosth. in Timocr. p. 822. 22 Pseud-Aristot. Econ. II. 17. ** 97 75 < and leathern bottles, articles which were particularly im- portant for the building and equipment of the fleet 223. It may indeed be supposed that this prohibition only existed against the Peloponnesians during the continuance of war 224; but how often did Greece enjoy the blessings of peace? and even in the time of Theophrastus, the ex- portation of timber, i. e. of timber for ship-building, was still prohibited, being only allowed to particular individuals free of duty 225. It is obvious that war was necessarily attended with certain restrictions and limitations; for ex- ample the manufactories of arms at Athens supplied the consumption of many nations; it was natural therefore that laws should be directed against those who provided the enemy with arms; thus Timarchus decreed, that who- ever furnished Philip either with arms or tackle for ships should be punished with death 226. But in addition to these restrictions, even the importation of some commodities was occasionally prohibited in time of war; as for example of Boeotian lamp-wicks, of which the real reason is not, as Casaubon concluded from the jokes of Aristophanes 227, that the Athenians were afraid of these lamp-wicks causing a conflagration, but that all commodities imported from ! 223 Upon this point see Aristoph. Ran. 365. 367. and the Scholiast, Spanheim upon this passage, and Casaubon ad Theo- phrast. Char. 23. Concerning the leathern bottles (¿oxáμara) comp. besides the Scholiast of Aristophanes, the Etymologist, Suidas, and Thomas Magister in v. úλaxos. 224 Which one should also be led to suppose from Aristophanes and his Scholiast ut sup. and from Aristoph. Eq. 278. 225 Theophrast. Char. 23. 226 Demosth. de fals. Leg. p. 433. 4. See the note to Petit's Leg. Att. p. 517. ed. Wessel. 227 Aristoph. Acharn. 916. and the Scholiast, Casaubon ut sup. 76 Boeotia were excluded, for the purpose of harassing this country by a stoppage of all intercourse, as indeed may be seen from another passage in the play just alluded to 228. In like manner Pericles, according to the Acharnenses of the same poet 229, and the testimonies of many other writers, had excluded the Megarians from all intercourse with Attica, in order to oppress them. Upon the whole, war was as much carried on by impeding commerce as by force of arms, and by her dominion of the sea Athens ob- tained the means of exercising a continual despotism over trade."No state," observes Xenophon, "can ever export any thing, if it is not submissive to the masters of the sea; upon them depends all the exportation of the surplus pro- duce of other nations 230." They laid an embargo upon all vessels, seized, and detained or captured merchant-vessels, even such as the State had no right to interfere with; and to recover by a decree of the court of captures the goods which had been unlawfully lost, was a matter of extreme " 228 Acharn. 860 sqq. 229 See more particularly the argument to this Play, Thucyd. I. 139. Plutarch. Pericl. 30. Diod. XII. 39 sqq. ' Ħ 230 Xenoph. de Rep. Ath. II. 3. 11, 12. The words πρὸς δὲ τούτοις ἄλλοσε ἄγειν οὐκ ἐάσουσιν, οἵτινες ἀντίπαλοι ἡμῖν εἰσὶν, ἢ οὐ χρήσονται τῇ θαλάττῃ, are extremely difficult to understand, and certainly have not been understood by the commentators; but yet they do not appear corrupt. The sense is, "The States, from which we receive imports, will not permit our adversaries to export for their own use the materials necessary for ship build- ing, or they will lose by that means the use of the sea." The subject to ξάσουσιν and χρήσονται is ἐκεῖνοι, which refers to the pre- ceding παρὰ μὲν τοῦ, παρὰ δὲ τοῦ. The words οἵτινες ἀντίπαλοι ἡμῖν siriv are to be taken instead of the accusative to ayaw, just as if it stood πρὸς δὲ τούτοις ἐκεῖνοι οὐκ ἐάσουσιν ἄλλοσε ἄγειν τοὺς ἡμῖν ἀντι- πάλους, ἢ οὐ χρήσονται τῇ θαλάττῃ. รา ५ 77 difficulty. That these measures of the Athenians produced the greatest hatred against them, cannot excite surprize. Even the Spartans made a protest against the Megarian decree; its non-repeal was the immediate pretext of the Peloponnesian war. These examples, although not ap- plicable to a state of peace, prove at least, that the Athenians did not avoid any restriction of commerce, so long as it appeared profitable to them; and from this it may be fairly concluded that at times when there was a cessation from war, they provided for their real or supposed interests by various regulations which were inconsistent with freedom of trade. Their object was to frame compulsory laws for the purpose of forcing the supply of those commodities which were necessary for the consump- tion of the country; or which should be brought to the market in the port of Athens, in order to be there sold, that by these means Athens might become a general emporium. Some of these regulations are extraordinarily No inhabitant was allowed to carry corn any where but to the harbour of Athens; those who violated this law were subject to a Phasis or an Eisangelia 231. In the same manner it was fixed what portion of the corn of each cargo which had arrived in harbour, should be retained in the city of Athens, as will be presently shewn. There was also an exceedingly oppressive regulation, that no Athenian or alien resident in Attica should lend money upon a vessel which did not return to Athens with a cargo of corn or other commodities 232. If indeed we listen to Salma- severe. 231 See chap. 15. 232 Demosth. in Lacrit. p. 941. 9-20. from the Law, 'Agrigion δὲ μὴ ἐξεῖναι ἐκδοῦναι ᾿Αθηναίων καὶ τῶν μετοίκων τῶν ᾿Αθήνησι μετοικούντων μηδενὶ, μηδὲ ὧν οὗτοι κύριοί εἰσιν, εἰς ναῦν ἥτις ἂν μὴ μέλλῃ ἄξειν σῖτον 78 sius 233, this law refers only to the corn trade, and means no more than that it was not permitted to lend money for the purpose of buying corn in other countries, except upon the condition that the corn should be imported into Athens: this supposition is however manifestly devoid of foundation. The meaning of the law is, that money could not be lent upon any ship which did not return to Athens with corn; but if these were all the provisions of the law, no money could have been vested in bottomry at all, ex- cept upon vessels employed in the corn trade. Since then this supposition leads to an absurdity, it is manifest that we do not possess the law in a complete state. And this in fact is sufficiently pointed out in the speech of Demo- sthenes against Lacritus; and corn, as being the most important article, was only first and expressly named. In several places it is distinctly stated, that it was not lawful to lend money which was to be sent to any foreign port, without corn being particularly specified 234. In the agreement of bottomry given in the speech of Demosthenes against Lacritus (to which case the law exactly applies), it is not fixed that either corn or any thing else should be ᾿Αθήναζε, καὶ τἄλλα τὰ γεγραμμένα περὶ ἑκάστου αὐτῶν. The last words shew that many other specific provisions followed which the Orator omits, and in these no doubt the other com- modities were either individually or generally stated. 233 De M. U. V. p. 193 sqq. 10 R 934 In Lacrit. ut sup. καὶ δίκη αὐτῷ μὴ ἔστω περὶ τοῦ ἀργυρίου, ö àv indậ äλaoré ny 'Abúvale. Demosth. in Dionysodor. p. 1284. 15. » ὅτι οὐκ ἂν δανείσαιμεν εἰς ἕτερον ἐμπόριον οὐδὲν ἀλλ᾽ ἢ εἰς ᾿Αθήνας. The passage in the speech against Lacritus p. 941. 15. iàv de tig indậ παρὰ ταῦτ᾽, εἶναι τὴν φάσιν καὶ τὴν ἀπογραφὴν τοῦ ἀργυρίου πρὸς τοὺς ἐπιμελητὰς, καθὰ περὶ τῆς νεὼς καὶ τοῦ σίτου εἴρηται, κατὰ ταῦτα, proves nothing against my assertion for many reasons. 79 taken as a return-cargo; and the debtor himself affirmed that he had intended to return to Athens with a cargo of salt meat and Coan wine 235; nor in any similar document is the species of the commodities ever fixed which are to be taken as a return-cargo, but the only stipulations we find are with regard to the security, and that the return- cargo should be of equal value with the original freight: Lastly, how could it have been possible to specify the goods, which were to be taken up as a return-cargo, since the merchant would necessarily be guided in his selection by the state of the market, and no certain calculation could be made beforehand? We must therefore allow, that, in general, money could not be lent at Athens upon any ship or upon its cargo, except on the condition of its return- ing to that city, in order that no Athenian property might be employed to the profit of a foreign trading-town. This is not inconsistent with the permission to lend money only for the time requisite for the voyage to a particular place, without including the return (éregónλous). If the master of a vessel had borrowed money for the time of his voyage from Athens to Rhodes, and instead of not paying the money till he returned to Athens, if he was obliged to repay it immediately upon his arrival at Rhodes, it does not follow from this that he was not compelled to return; by law he was bound to do so, just as much as if the money had been lent him until his return to Athens. The sole difference is, that in the former case the creditor was only exposed to the risk of the passage outwards, in the latter of the passage inwards as well236. Money too could only 235 P. 933. 15. 236 To this view of the subject the passage in Demosth. in Dionysod. p. 1284. 8-20. cannot be opposed, for if rightly 80 1 be lent for the time of the passage outwards, upon the condition of the vessel returning to Athens: it was only absolutely prohibited, when the ship was not to return. It should also be remembered, that heavy punishments were laid upon the violation of this law. As to the laws re- lating to money lent out on other kinds of security, no com- plaint could be made. Those who failed to pay could be prosecuted by a Phasis 237; and the borrower, if he did not return, could be punished with loss of life 238. If the Athe- nians imposed such restrictions upon trade, it may be con- ceived how the laws of other states were constituted. In Ægina and Argos Athenian manufactures appear to have been in early times prohibited, although upon a pretended religious motive, and on the immediate occasion for sacred purposes 239. In the inland traffic too there was not by any means unrestricted freedom; nor indeed could it exist under the established principles of the ancients, among whom the police mixed itself with every thing, although the mode understood it completely agrees with it. Dionysodorus and Par- meniscus wish to borrow money for the voyage from Athens to Egypt, and from thence to Rhodes; it is therefore a irigóλous without any obligation to return, to which the lenders naturally would not consent. Compare also upon the questions relating to this subject book I. chap. 23. The space does not permit me to be more explicit upon this question, nor will persons ac- quainted with such subjects desire more: but to satisfy a certain class of readers, who expect every thing to be related ab ovo, and to be supported with passages explained at full length, is no easy matter, as we must not suppose that they have any previous knowledge of the question. 237 Demosth. in Lacrit. ut sup. 238 Demosth. in Dionysod. p. 1295. 8 sqq. as the context shews. 259 Herod. V. 88. 81 of its interference differed from that which now prevails in modern States. Assize-regulations were not unknown. In the time of Aristophanes the government of Athens on one occasion reduced the price of salt to a fixed rate; which however was not long retained, probably because it caused a deficiency in the supply of that article 240. In corn we certainly find a great freedom of prices. Yet the ruinous operation of engrossing was restrained within certain limits. Retail-dealing in the market was originally interdicted to foreigners according to the rigour of the law; instances however occur of its being permitted upon the payment of a duty, which is different from the protection-money of the resident aliens 241. What is here said must not however be referred to the wholesale trade in the harbour; this in a great measure owed its existence to foreigners, who exposed samples of their goods at a particular place called Deigma 242, for the convenience of the buyers who came there from all regions to purchase commodities. The prices of commodities could not however have been much enhanced by these restrictions, especially as the custom-duties were very moderate; but they were raised by the great profit which the merchants took. That the rate of profits was high, is sufficiently proved by the high rate of interest on money lent upon bottomry (fenus 240 Aristoph. Eccl. 809. and the Scholiast. 241 Demosth. in Eubulid. p. 1308. 9. p. 1309. 5. where this is called and reλetv. 242 Lysias Fragm. p. 31. Aristoph. Eq. 975. and Schol. De- mosth. in Lacrit. p. 932. 20. in Polycl. p. 1214. 18. Harpoc. in v. duyμa, Poll. IX. 34. and there Jungermann. cf. Casaub. ad Theoph. Char. 23. also Lex. Seg. p. 237. The Deigma at Rhodes is mentioned by Polybius V. 69. The specimens them- selves were also called Deigma, Plutarch. Demosth. 23. VOL. I. G 82 nauticum), in which 30 per cent for one summer was not unfrequently paid. Hume's remark 243, that a high rate of interest and profit is an infallible sign, that industry and trade are still in their infancy, applies with the greatest force to the ancient times of the Grecian nations, and in some measure to that of Pericles, and the period immediately succeeding. A Samian ship, which, as Hero- dotus 244 relates, had by accident made its way from Egypt to Tartessus in Iberia, at a time when no Grecians, not even the Phocæans, traded there, gained upon one cargo 60 talents; since the tithe to the goddess Juno amounted to six talents: probably it had received silver at a low rate in exchange for the goods carried out 245. Greek merchants had never made a greater profit, with the exception only of Sostratus of Ægina, with whom no one could in this respect enter into comparison. With regard however to the value of the cargo of the Samian ship, it is clear that it cannot now be ascertained, as the quantity of goods on board different vessels was very various; we find instances of cargoes which did not exceed two talents in value; but larger sums are met with, as for example, a ship of Naucratis mentioned in Demosthenes was valued at nine and a half talents 246. In the time of Lysias also, an Athenian vessel is said to have paid so large an interest upon a sum of two talents, that it doubled the principal 247. It is of course evident that the retail-traders (xάπηλ01) obtained likewise a very large profit on the goods which 243 Essays, p. 222. 244 Herod. IV. 152. 245 Compare what Diodorus V. 35. says of the Phoenicians. 246 Demosth. in Timocr. p. 696. and passim. 247 Lysias in Diogit. p. 908. 83 they sold, if we take into consideration the high rate of interest. (10.) If allowance is made for accidental variation in different places, it may be stated that in the ancient world the necessaries of life were upon the whole cheaper than at the present time, but in individual cases examples enough of the contrary occur. The chief reasons of the former phenomenon are the smaller quantity of money in circula- tion, the unusual fruitfulness of the southern regions in which the Greeks either dwelt or traded-regions, which although now neglected, were at that period in a state of the highest cultivation-and the impossibility of export- ation to distant lands, which had little or no intercourse with the countries upon the Mediterranean. The latter is in particular the cause of the great cheapness of wine. The abundant quantity of this article which was produced in almost all the southern regions, was not distributed over so large a space of the earth as is the case at present. It is to be observed however, that in considering the general scale of prices in ancient States, the difference of time and place must be well weighed. In Rome and in Athens, at the most flourishing periods of these States, commodities were not so cheap as in upper Italy and Lusitania. In upper Italy, even in the time of Polybius 248, the Sicilian medimnus of wheat, which was the same as the Attic, being somewhat less than 1 English bushels, frequently sold for only four oboli (eight asses), i. e. about sixpence, the medimnus of barley for half this sum, the metretes of 248 Polyb. I. 15. Polybius has changed the asses into oboli, reckoning two asses to an obolus, and the denarius equal to the drachma. He thus takes the Roman coins a small fraction too high. |? 84 wine, about ten wine-gallons, for the same price as the barley! Travellers used not, as in other places, to agree with the innkeepers for the price of each article, but only stipulated how much they should give in the gross for the whole consumption of an individual, and the sum demanded was generally a half as or quarter obolus, and seldom exceeded this rate. In Lusitania, according to the same historian 249, the Sicilian medimnus of barley cost a drachma, of wheat nine Alexandrian oboli, which appear to have been something less than the Attic 250; the metretes of wine the same as the barley; a kid of mode- rate size an obolus, a hare the same, a lamb three and four oboli, a fat pig, weighing a hundred minas, five oboli, a sheep two, a draught ox ten, a calf five drachmas, a talent of figs, about 56lbs, three oboli; game had hardly any value, but was included gratis in other bargains. Such low prices as these do not apply to Athens after the Persian war. In the time of Solon, indeed, an ox cost only five drachmas, a sheep one drachma, and a medimnus of corn the same sum: but prices gradually rose to five times, in many things to as much as ten or twenty times, their former amount, which after the examples of more recent times does not seem surprising. The quantity of money in use was not only increased, but through a rising population and an extended intercourse its circulation was accelerated. Thus Athens, as early as in the age of So- crates, was considered an expensive place of residence 251. Upon the whole, the cheapness of commodities in ancient 249 XXXIV. 8. 7. Concerning the reading see Schweighæuser in the Lexicon Polyb. p. 555. 250 See above, chap. 4. 251 Plutarch. de Anim. Tranquill. 10. 85 times has been exaggerated by some writers, who thought that the nearest approach would be made to the truth by assuming that prices were on an average ten times lower than in the eighteenth century 252; whereas the prices of corn, by which many other prices are necessarily regulated, prove the contrary. But that a more determinate judg ment may be passed upon this subject, I will explicitly treat of each in their order of the prices of immoveables; of slaves, of cattle, corn, bread, wine, oil, and other necessaries of life, and also of wood, clothing, and the different sorts of implements and furniture, as far as I have been able to find information upon these points. (11.) The value of the cultivated land in Attica was naturally very different according to its situation and goodness. The estates in the vicinity of the city bore a much higher price than those at a distance 253; the wooded land (yй TεQUTEUμévn) must have been dearer than the bare or unplanted land (yñ λǹ) as it was called, the rich and good than the poor soils. Among the many passages upon the value of land one alone contains an approximate statement of the area, and this without any particulars as to situation and quality. Aristophanes, according to the account of Lysias 254, had bought a house for five minas and 300 plethra of land, both together cost him more than five talents. If we assume that it cost him five talents and twenty minas, and subtract from this sum the value of the house, there remain for the land 27,000 drachmas, which 252 Gillies ut sup. p. 19. Wolf makes the same supposition with regard to a charitable institution of Trajan, p. 6. 255 Xenoph. de Vectig. 4. 254 Orat. pro Aristoph. bonis p. 633. and p. 642. where for οὐσίαν read with Markland οἰκίαν. 86 gives 90 drachmas for one plethron. Now the plethron was equal to 10,000 feet of Greek square measure, 9620 Rheinland, or 9900 English feet, according to Ideler's researches. The English acre of 43,560 square feet would thus have cost 396 drachmas; which does not by any means agree with the exaggerated notion above alluded to, that prices were ten times lower in ancient than in modern times. It is however by no means improbable that much land bore a lower value; but 50 drachmas may be fairly assumed as the average price of the plethron, without taking into consideration accidental circumstances by which the value of the land might be lowered. It should also be mentioned that in Attica the land was probably divided into portions of no very great extent. Alcibiades' paternal inheritance did not amount to more than the estate pur- chased by Aristophanes, although his was one of the most distinguished families. It was not until the time of Demosthenes that individuals purchased much landed property. The most extensive possessions were those which commonly went by the name of boundary-estates (xariai), which were situated at a distance either upon the seashore or at the foot of the mountains 255. Thus the boundary-estate of Timarchus in Sphettus is stated to have been extensive, but it had run wild through his neglect 256. The estate belonging to Phænippus in Cy- 255 Harpoc. in v. irxarıd. Schol. ad Eschin. in Timarch. p. 736, 737. ed. Reisk. Lex. Seg. p. 256. and the Commentators upon Æschines and Demosthenes in the passages to be quoted. Herodotus also (VI. 127.) calls distant estates irxarial. The supposition that the estates on the boundaries of the boroughs were so called is undoubtedly false, not to mention that many boroughs were bounded by the sea and by mountains. 256 Æschin. in Timarch. p. 117, 119. F 87 theron contained more than 40 stadii or 1440 plethra 257. Of other estates I have noted down the following prices. An estate situated in Sphettus is mentioned in Lysias as being worth five minas; another occurs in Isæus worth above ten minas, and in the former orator an estate in Cicynna is estimated by the creditor at ten minas 258. In like manner in Terence 259, an estate is stated to be mort- gaged for the latter sum. Timarchus sold an estate in Alo- pecæ, distant eleven or twelve stadii from the walls, under its value for 20 minas 260, Again, an estate is mentioned in Prospalta, which was hardly worth 30 minas 261, and one in Enoë for 50 minas 262. An estate of Ciron's was, according to the expression of Isæus, well worth a talent: whence we may conclude that an estate no larger than this was thought a considerable possession; an estate of the same value occurs in Demosthenes, which appears to have contained vineyards 263. The following sums are still more considerable, viz. 70 minas, and 75 minas for an estate in Athmonon, two talents for a property in Eleusis, and two and half talents for the same in Thria 264. Con- cerning other kinds of landed property I have been unable to obtain any information, except that mine-shares were 257 Orat. in Phænipp. p. 1040. 15. 258 Lysias Tegì dnpoo. ådíx. p. 594. cf. p. 593, 595. Isæus de Menecl. Hered. p. 221. ed. Orell. 259 Phorm. IV. 3. 56. 260 Esch. in Timarch. p. 119. 261 Isæus de Hagn. Hered. p. 298. 262 Is. ut sup. p. 294. 263 Is. de Ciron. Hered. p. 218. Demosth. in Onet. I. p. 872. ad fin. II. p. 876. 10. cf. I. p. 871.22. 264 Isæus de Menecl. Hered. p. 220, 221. ed. Orell. de Phi- loctem. Hered. p. 140. de Hagn. Hered. p. 292 sqq. 88 sold for a talent and 90 minas, although their price was at times enhanced by particular circumstances 265. (C (12.) With regard to houses, we know that Athens contained above 10,000 266; which probably does not include the public edifices and the buildings without the walls; the city and the harbour being nearly 200 stadii in circumference, there were many places within so large an area upon which no buildings were erected 267. The houses were for the most part small and mean in appear- ance, the streets crooked and narrow; a stranger," says Dicæarchus," might doubt upon a sudden view whether this were really the city of Athens ;" the Piraeus alone had been laid out according to rule, in the time of Themistocles, by the architect Hippodamus 268. The upper stories often projected over the streets; staircases, balustrades, and doors opening outwards, obstructed and narrowed the way. Themistocles and Aristides, with the entire co- operation of the Areopagus, gained nothing more by their endeavours than that a stop was put to any farther narrowing of the streets by building, a measure which was adhered to in later times 269. The plan of Hippias and Iphicrates for breaking down every thing that projected into the public streets 270 was not carried into execution, because their object was not the embellishment of the city, but to obtain money by fraudulent means. With the ex- 265 See my Essay upon the Silver-mines of Laurion. 266 Xenoph. Mem. Socrat. III. 6. 14. To this Xenoph. Econ. 8. 22. is also referred; but not with any certainty. 267 Xenoph. de Vectig. 2. 268 Dicæarchus p. 8. and Aristot. Polit. VI. 2. VII. 11. and the Commentators. 269 Heraclid. Pont. and Xenoph. de Rep. Ath. 3. 270 See Meursius F. A. p. 20. 89 ception of the magnificent public edifices, they did not begin to build good houses until the time of Demosthenes. "Formerly," says this orator 271, "no individual raised himself above the multitude. If any one of us could now see the houses of Themistocles, Aristides, Miltiades, Cimon, or the famous men of those days, he would perceive that they were not more magnificent than the houses of ordinary persons; while the buildings of the State are of such number and magnitude that they cannot be sur- passed:" and afterwards he complains that the statesmen of his time constructed houses which exceeded the public buildings in magnificence. Meidias built a house in Eleusis larger than any in that place 272. The greater number of houses were however even at this time badly built, as Photion's 273, for example; and, like those of Pompeii and Herculaneum, they occupied only a limited space, for which reason their price could not have been high. Labour was cheap, there was stone in plenty, and wood could be easily brought to the place of building; and another circumstance which diminished the price of houses was, that they were for the most part either built with a frame-work, or of unburnt bricks dried in the open air, which latter mode of building, as being more durable than with soft stones, was sometimes employed in splendid and costly edifices 274. An advantageous situation and the 271 Demosth. in Aristocrat. p. 689. 11-24. Olynth. III. p. 35. 14–24. p. 36. 20. from both of which the passage in the Oration Tigi cuvτážews p. 174-5. is composed. For the whole speech has been correctly abjudged from Demosthenes. 272 Demosth. in Mid. p. 565. 24. 275 Plut. Phoc. 18. 27 That the private buildings of the Athenians were con- structed of bricks of unburnt clay is in part proved by Demo- 90 customary high rate of house-rent, might however raise the value of houses. It was also of course possible for large sums of money to be expended by foolish and extravagant speculations upon an useless house 275. It should be ob- served that the Attic language distinguishes between dwelling-houses (oixía), and lodging-houses (σuvoixíai); accidentally indeed a dwelling-house might be let out for lodgings, and a lodging-house have been inhabited by the proprietor himself; which will explain how learned writers could fall into the error of supposing that the latter word (ouvoixía), frequently means a house in general without any addition of the idea of letting; whereas the derivation of the word plainly shews that it expresses a dwelling to- gether of several families, of whom either some or all are lodgers. The prices of houses, which are mentioned in the ancient writers, vary from three minas to 120, according to their size, situation, and condition. The data are as follows; a small house estimated by Isæus at less than three minas, though he probably depreciates its value; a house at Eleusis worth five minas, mentioned by the same orator276; a very small house near the temple of Hermes Psithyristes at Athens, sold for seven minas, according to another orator 277; another house which was pledged for ten minas, according to Demosthenes, a possession belonging to poor people, as is evident from their inconsiderable sthenes ap. Plutarch. in Vit. Demosth. 11. Hirt Baukunst der Alten p. 143. 275 Xenoph. Econ. 3. 1. 276 Isæus de Menecl. Hered. p. 221. ed. Orell. de Hagn. Hered. For the rest see p. 293. 277 Orat. in Neær. p. 1358. 6–9. 91 dowry of 40 minas, and from other circumstances 278; to these may be added a house noticed in Terence which is mortgaged for the same sum, a poet who generally repre- sents the usages and customs of Athens 279; a dwelling- house in the city, worth 20 minas, mentioned by Isæus 280; a lodging-house in the country mortgaged for sixteen minas, in Demosthenes 281; a house in the city that had been let, worth 20 minas, in Isæus 282, and several houses of the same value in Demosthenes and Æschines 283, one of them behind the Acropolis; a house sold for thirty minas, and another of the same value in Isæus and Demosthenes 284, the former in Melite; a lodging-house in the Cerameicus, worth 40 minas, given as a dowry, in Isæus; another in the city transferred for the sum of 44 minas, in the same orator 285; likewise one for 50 minas in Isæus and Lysias 286; a lodging-house belonging to the rich merchant Pasion, valued at a hundred minas 287; and, lastly, in Plautus a house purchased for two talents, having two wooden columns connected with it, valued, exclusively 278 Demosth. in Spud. p. 1029. 20. cf. p. 1032. 21. p. 26. 1033. 279 Phorm. IV. 3. 58. 280 De Ciron. Hered. p. 219. 281 In Nicostrat. p. 1250. 18. 282 Ut sup. 283 Demosth. in Onetor. II. p. 876. 9. and passim. Esch. in Timarch. p 119. 284 Isæus de Hagn. Hered. p. 293. Demosth. in Aphob. I. p. 816. 21. 285 De Dicæog. Hered. p. 104. de Philoctem. Hered. p. 140. 286 Is. de Dicæog. Hered. p. 105. Lys. pro Aristoph. bonis p. 633. 287 Demosth. in Stephan. 1. p. 1110. 8. 92 of the cost of the carriage, at three minas 288. To these may be added 30 minas, the value of a bathing house at Serangium in the Piraeus 289; and another of which the value may be fairly estimated at 40 minas, as the person, who was cast in a law-suit on the occasion, was compelled to pay that sum for it 290. (13.) The market-price of slaves, exclusively of the variations caused by the greater or less demand and supply 291, was very different according to their age, health, strength, beauty, natural abilities, mechanical ingenuity, and moral qualities. Some slaves, says Xe- nophon 292, are well worth two minas, others hardly half a mina; many sold for five or ten minas, and Nicias the son of Niceratus is stated to have given no less than a talent for an overseer in the mines. The slaves employed in the mills and mines were undoubtedly the lowest. Lucian, in the ludicrous valuation of the philoso- phers 293, estimates Socrates at two talents, a Peripatetic at twenty, Chrysippus at twelve, a Pythagorean at ten, and Dion of Syracuse at two minas, and, to omit the value of Diogenes, reckons Philon the Sceptic at a mina, remarking at the same time that he was destined for the 288 Mostell. III. 1. 113 sqq. III. 2. 138. I omit other passages which do not refer to Athens, such as that in the spurious Epistle of Æschines, 9. 289 Is. de Philoct. Sorte, p. 140. Compare also Harpocration in v. Σηράγγιον. 290 Isæus de Dicæog. Hered. p. 101. 291 Such for example, as those paid for the Carthaginian sol- diers, according to Liv. XXI. 41. 292 Mem. Socrat. II. 3. 2. 295 Βίων πρᾶσις 27. 93 mill; the latter therefore is evidently the price of a slave employed in the mills. "Assuming," observes Xenophon, "that the Athenian State 294 purchases 1200 slaves, and lets them out on hire into the mines for a daily payment of one obolus a head, and that the whole revenue accruing from this source is annually applied to the purchase of fresh slaves, who should again be let out at a like profit, which receipts should be applied as before, and so on for ever, the State would by means of these successive returns have 6000 slaves in five or six years." If, as I believe, the original 1200 are comprehended in this number, the price is here taken at from 125 to 150 drachmas; if they are not comprised in the estimate, which appears to me improbable, a slave in the mines would be only reckoned at from 100 to 125 drachmas. According to the account of Demosthenes 295, 105 minas were lent upon the security of a mine, and 30 slaves employed in working it; this was arranged by a fictitious purchase made by two creditors, one of whom, Nicobulus, gave 40 minas, the other, Euergus, a talent; the latter held the mine, the former the slaves as a pledge, which they were to cede as soon as the contract of purchase ceased to be in force 296; consequently each slave was in this case estimated at 150 drachmas: nor could a slave of this description in general have been worth more, although the antagonists of Demosthenes' client main- tain that the mines and slaves together were worth a much larger sum 297. The statement of Barthélemy 298, who 294 De Vectig. 4. 23. 295 In Pantænet. p. 967. 296 See p. 967. 18. and p. 972. 21. 297 For the sake of brevity I refer the reader to my Essay on the Silver-mines of Laurion. 299 Anachars. tom. V. p. 35. 2 94 supposes that the value of the mine-slaves varied from 300 to 600 drachmas, rests upon an erroneous assumption. Ordinary house-slaves, both male and female, could not have been worth much more than those just mentioned 299. The valuation of two slaves, each at two and a half minas, is considered in the works of Demosthenes 300 as high; in the same author we read of a slave who was sold for two minas 301. Demosthenes' father was possessed of workers of iron or sword-cutlers, some of whom were worth five, some six, and the lowest more than three minas, and twenty chair-makers, together worth 40 minas. The chair-makers with the 32 or 33 sword-makers, including a capital of a talent, are stated at four talents 50 minas 302, But when in another place the same orator reckons 14 sword-cutlers (although they might have been of advanced age), together with 30 minas, at only 70 minas 303, and con- sequently each at 71 drachmas, he is manifestly guilty of an intentional falsehood. How great an influence a knowledge of any art had upon the value of the slave is shewn by this I 299 Upon this point compare the unsatisfactory statements in Aristoph. Plut. 147. Isæus de Ciron. Hered. p. 218–220. 300 In Nicost. p. 1246. 7. The author afterwards states in the Addenda, that "he had considered the estimate of two slaves at 24 minas as high, because from the words rò μsysbos rũs åño- reapus he assumed a high valuation; and that therefore the words of the Orator must be interpreted as if each of the two slaves was estimated at that sum; but that since myelos might also be understood of a less amount, and as the context, although very obscure, seems to require this meaning, it might be pre- ferable to suppose that the two slaves were together valued at 2 minas." 301 In Spud. p. 1030. 8. 302 Demosth. in Aphob. I. p. 816. 5. 303 Cf. Demosth. in Aphob. p. 815. p. 817. 23. and p. 821, 95 example of the sword-cutlers; for the higher profit they afforded the greater was their value. While a slave in the mines only yielded a profit of an obolus a day, a worker in leather produced two, and the master of the workshop three oboli 304; from whence it can be judged how large may have been the profit which the manufacturers of fine ornamental goods, such as head-nets (σaxxupávтai) or of stuffs of Amorgus and variegated clothes (Total), yielded to their possessors 305. Five minas, which we found above to have been given for slaves skilled in some art, appear moreover not to have been at all uncommon 306, as is shewn by an account in Diogenes 307. The Roman sol- diers whom Hannibal had sold in Achaia, were ransomed 304 Eschin. in Timarch. p. 118. 305 Concerning the caxxvpávraι see Demosth. in Olympiod. p. 1170. 27. Pollux X. 192. The interpretation given in Lex. Seg. p. 302. is incorrect. For the other points cf. Æsch. ut sup. Concerning the ποικιλτὴς, afterwards called πλουμάριος (plumarius, see Muratori Inscript. vol. II. p. DCCCCVI. 13. and again p. DCCCCXXIV. 11. together with his Dissertation de Textrina in the Ant. Ital.), Poll. VII. 34, 35. and the Commentators, Schol. Esch. p. 730. ed. Reiske, and Lex. Seg. p. 295. 306 It might also be supposed that the price of five minas for slaves at the oars (xwπs) was mentioned in Andocides de suo Reditu p. 81. if in that passage we write vs μvv for æévre deax- pewv: for what Reiske (Ind. Andoc. Orat. Att. tom. VIII. p. 503.) infers from this passage, Remigis erat ingens pretium quinque drachmæ, will not mislead any reader. Kwaùs however does not mean a rower, but a piece of wood for an oar, as may be easily seen by a comparison of the passages, where it was supposed to mean Of these is the passage in Andocides, where the con- text clearly shews, that pieces of wood for oars, and not slaves for the oars, are intended: and a piece of wood of this description was probably well paid for at five drachmas. a rower. 307 Vol. II. in the Life of Aristippus. 96 at a compensation of five minas each, the price having been fixed by the Achæans themselves, and the State paid it to their respective possessors 308. These statements agree for the most part with the prices which were paid for some slaves sold to the Delphian Apollo, upon the condi- tion that the individuals who thus became sacred property should in all other respects be free, and ever after be exempt from serving any person as slaves. In instruments of sale belonging to this kind of transfer we find four minas paid for a male, from three to five for a female309; yet in a sale which took place at Amphissa to the temple of Apollo not less than 1000 drachmas are given for a male slave. Plautus appears, as is frequently the case with the comic poets, to make a high estimate, when he values a strong useful slave at twenty minas, and supposes a child to be sold for six minas 310. The father of Theocrines was condemned to pay to the State a fine of 500 drachmas for having attempted to emancipate a female slave of Cephiso- dorus. The sum paid to the State for an offence of this nature was, according to law, the half of the complete fine, 308 1200 cost the State a hundred talents according to Po- lybius, Liv. XXXIV, 50. This was in Olymp. 146. 1. in the year of the city 558. 309 Chandler Inscript. II. 154. cf. Muratori p. DXCIII, also Chandler II. 150, 151, 152, 153, 155. and Chandler Marm. Oxon. II. XXIX. 2. The sacred slaves, igédouλo, were of this description, as e. g. the Venerii at Eryx in Sicily, the female servants of Venus at Corinth, the Hieroduli of Comana upon the Pontus, which the priests could no more sell to another person, than the Thessalian could sell their bondsmen the Penestæ, or the Spartans their Helots out of the country. Cf. Strab. XII. p. 384. 310 Captiv. II. 2, 103. V. 2, 21. 4, 15. T 97 the other half went to the injured master; and it is probable that this was a simple compensation for the loss sustained, so that the female slave appears to have been valued at five minas 311. For women who prostituted their persons, and female players on the cithara, 20 or 30 minas occur as common prices 12. Neæra was sold for 30 minas 313. A negro-woman and an old eunuch are sold in a play of Terence for 20 minas 314. Even these prices were still farther enhanced by luxury; and although at Athens an excellent slave could be bought for ten minas, the price at Rome in the time of Columella exceeded even this amount 15, in the same manner that the value of negro-slaves has at the present day considerably increased: as early as in the age of the first Ptolemies, an Alexandrian talent was the price given for the males and females who attended at court 316. The ransom-money for captives was only in part regulated by the price of slaves. This may be seen from the fact that the Chalcideans, who before the Persian war remained prisoners in Athens, were ransomed at two minas a head 317; at which sum subsequently the indigent 311 Orat. in Theocrin. p. 1327. 1328. see book III. 12. 312 Terent. Adelph. II. 1. 37. 2. 15. IV. 7. 24. and elsewhere, Plaut. Mostellar. in several places, Curcul. I. 1. 63. II. 3, 65. and passim, Terent. Phorm III. 3. 24. Isocrat. megi avridórews p. 124. ed. Orell. 313 Orat. in Neær. p. 1354. 16. 314 Terent. Eunuch. I. 2. 89. In V. 5. 13. he inaccurately says that the eunuch cost the same sum. The negress appears to have been worth but little, cf. III. 2. 18. 315 Hamberger de pretiis rerum, p. 32. Cf. Jugler de Nundin. Serv. 7. p. 85 sqq. 516 Joseph. Antiq. Jud. XII. 4. 317 Herod. V. 77. VOL. I. H 98 citizens of Potidæa were valued, and paid taxes for it as for property of the same amount. Again, Dionysius the elder, after he had conquered the Rhegini, first compelled them to make good the expences of the war, and then demanded for each man a ransom of three minas, or, according to Diodorus, one mina 318; Hannibal also agreed to ransom the Roman prisoners at three minas a head; and finally, in the time of Philip, when there were many Athenian prisoners in Macedonia, the customary ransom varied from three to five minas 319. But since it frequently happened that not only the respectability and character of a man, but also his wealth and importance, were taken into considera- tion, a higher rate of ransom was in such cases arbitrarily fixed. Nicostratus, as appears in a speech attributed to Demosthenes 320, was forced to ransom himself for 26 minas; Plato was freed from captivity by Anniceris for 20 or 30 minas; with which sum, the friends of the Philoso- pher having raised the money for the ransom and given it to Anniceris, the latter purchased him a garden adjoining the Academy 321. Philip affirms in his Epistle to the Athenians 322 that the Attic general Diopeithes had refused to ransom Amphilochus, a man of consideration, who was employed upon embassies, for less than fifteen talents. 318 The former according to the second book of the Economics attributed to Aristotle, from which the account of Diodorus XIV. 111. disagrees in several points. The date of this occur- rence is Olymp. 98. 2. 319 Polyb. VI. 56. Demosth. de fals. Leg. p. 394. 13. 320 In Nicostrat. p. 1248. 23. 321 Diog. Laert. III. 21. Plutarch. de Exilio 10. Seneca Epist. 74. Macrob. Sat. 1. 11. The account of Diodorus XV. 7. is, as usual, confused. 522 Demosth. p. 159, 15. 99 Hence in order to prevent any arbitrary proceedings, Demetrius Poliorcetes concluded an agreement with the Rhodians that the free inhabitants should be ransomed for ten and the slaves for five minas 323. The rights of pos- session with regard to slaves in no way differed from any other property; they could be given or taken as pledges 324, They laboured either on their master's account or their own, in consideration of a certain sum to be paid to the master, or they were let out on hire either for the mines, or any other kinds of labour, and even for other persons' workshops, or as hired servants for wages (anopogá) 325: a similar payment was also exacted by the masters from their slaves serving in the fleet. The profits derived from the slaves must necessarily have been very great; for the possessor must have replaced his outlay of capital and ensured the usual high rate of interest, exactly in the same manner as if it had been vested in cattle, since the value of slaves was destroyed by age, and at their death the money vested in them was lost. To this must be added the great danger of their elopement, espe- cially when there was war in the country, and they were with the armies 326; it then became necessary to pursue them, and offer rewards publicly for their recapture (σã- 323 Diod. XX. 84. 324 Demosth. in Pantænet. p. 967. in Aphob. p. 821. 12. p. 822. in Onetor. I. p. 871. 11. 325 Demosth. in Nicostrat. p. 1253. 1, 11. in Aphob. I. p. 819. 26. Xenoph. de Rep. Ath. 1. in several places, particularly in chap. 11. which passage (as corrected by Heindorf) appears chiefly to refer to the pay of the sailors; Theoph. Char. 22. Andoc. de Myst. p. 19. 326 Thucyd. VII. 27. and VII. 13. 100 Orga) 327. The idea of an institution for the insurance of slaves first occurred to a Macedonian grandee, Anti- genes of Rhodes, who undertook for a yearly contribu- tion of eight drachmas for each slave that was in the army, to make good his price, as estimated by the owner at the time of elopement; which he was easily able to do, by compelling the governors either to return the slaves who had fled into their provinces, or to pay for them 328. It cannot however be determined with any accuracy how high was the rate of profit which a slave returned. The thirty-two or thirty-three iron-workers or sword-cutlers belonging to Demosthenes, annually produced a net profit of 30, and the twenty chair-makers of 12 minas; the value of the former being 190, of the latter 40 minas 329, the latter produced 30, the former only 1515 per cent, a disparity sufficiently remarkable. It is however to be mentioned, that the master furnished the raw materials for manufac- turing, and perhaps we ought to consider what he gained upon the raw materials as constituting a part of the whole profit. The leather-workers of Timarchus produced to their master two, the overseer three oboli a day, but probably this return is not to be considered as arising only from the capital vested in the slaves, as it must have also included the profit which the master derived from the supply of the raw materials. Hence it may be concluded that when mine-slaves let out to a tenant yielded to their master a profit of an obolus a day, which, reckoning 350 working days and an average value of 140 drachmas, 327 Plat. Protag. init. Xenoph. Mem. Socr. II. 10. 2. 328 See Pseud-Arist. ŒEcon. II. 2. 34. Antigenes for Antimenes is a correction of Niebuhr. 329 Demosth. in Aphob. I. p. 816. 101 gives 474 per cent, the rent thus paid extended not only to the slaves, but also to the mines let out with them; an inference which I have supported with other arguments elsewhere 330, (14.) Among domestic animals, horses were in Attica sold for comparatively high prices, not only on account of their utility and the difficulty of keeping them, but from the disposition of the Athenians to extravagance and dis- play: while the knights kept expensive horses for military service and processions at the festivals, and while men of ambition and high rank trained them for the games and races, there arose, particularly among the young men, an excessive passion for horses; of which Aristophanes gives an example in the Clouds, and which is recorded by several ancient writers 331; so that many were impoverished by keeping horses, although it is true that others were enriched by the same means 332. In early times also technical principles had been laid down concerning the management of horses, and rules of this kind had been published before the time of Xenophon by Simon a cele- brated rider 333. The price of a common horse, such as a countryman used, was three minas. "By keeping horses," says the client of Isæus 334, "you have not squandered your property, for never were you in possession of a horse which was worth more than three minas." But a good saddle-horse, or a horse for running in chariot-races, ac- 350 Essay on the Mines of Laurion. 331 Cf. Xenoph. de re Equestri, I. 12. Terent. Andr. I. 1. Bach ad Xenoph. Econ. 2. 6. &c. 352 Xenoph. Econ. 3. 8. Many ancient writers speak of καθιπποτροφεῖν. 333 Xenoph. de re Equestri, and see Schneider's note. 331 De Dicæog. Hered. p. 116. 102 cording to Aristophanes, cost twelve minas; and since this sum is lent upon a horse in pawn, it must have been a common price 335. But fashion or fancy for horses raised their price beyond all limits. Thus thirteen talents were given for Bucephalus 336. A yoke of mules, probably two animals, and not particularly good ones, but only destined for the ordinary purposes of country work, were sold for five and a half and also for eight minas 337. Asses were probably much cheaper in proportion; yet besides the ludicrous story of Lucian 338 that the ass Lucius, when no purchaser could be found for him, was at last disposed of to an itinerary priest of the Syrian goddess for the sum of 30 drachmas, I have been unable to meet with any thing upon this point in reference to Greece, and even this passage proves nothing with respect to the usual price in ancient times, and particularly in Attica. With regard to the prices of cattle, I am at a loss to guess whence an English writer could have derived the statement that an ox in the time of Socrates cost eight shillings; an assertion which is contradicted by the concurrent testimony of all writers who mention the subject. If indeed two drachmas were paid for an ox at the Delian Theoria 339, I will not deny that in the most ancient times this price may have existed; but of later times it is inconceivable, and the most that can be allowed is, that in the distribution of the prizes, which were merely a matter of honour, this primitive standard may have been retained. In Athens, Aristoph. Nub. 20, 1226. Lysias xaτny. xaxoλ. p. 306 sq. 336 Chares ap. Gell. Noct. Att. V. 2. 337 Isæus de Philoct. Hered. p. 140. 338 Asin. 35. 339 Pollux IX. 61. where the Commentators question the fact. 103 at the time of Solon, an ox, probably one selected as a victim, was sold for five drachmas, five times as much as a sheep 340; in Lusitania, according to Polybius, for ten drachmas, and a sheep in like manner a fifth of this sum; in Rome the price of an ox was ten times that of a sheep 341. If therefore in the flourishing times of Athens a sheep, as will be presently shewn, cost from ten to twenty drachmas, according to its age, breed, and the variation in the market price, an ox may be reckoned at from 50 to 100 drachmas. In Olymp. 92. 3. 5114 drachmas were paid for a hecatomb, and if we suppose that nearly 100 oxen were purchased for it, the price of an ox amounted to about 51 drachmas. But in Olymp. 101. 3. a hecatomb of 109 oxen cost 8419 drachmas, that is 77 drachmas a head; in both cases oxen selected for victims are meant 342. Pro- bably also in other countries except Athens, prices were not much lower at this period; in Sicily, which abounded with cattle, in the time of Epicharmus the price was the same as at Athens in the days of Solon. For a fine calf, according to that comic poet, was sold for ten nummi 343, or two drachmas 43 oboli of Attic money 344; and since it may be inferred from the analogy of the prices in Lusitania, that the value of a full-grown ox was double, it is probable that at that time in Sicily, an ox of similar 340 Plutarch. Solon. 23, from Demetrius Phalereus. 341 Hamberger in the Treatise above quoted, Taylor ad Marm. Sandw. p. 37. 342 See the second Prytaneia of the Choiseuil Inscription, and Barthélemy in the Mém. de l'Acad. des Inscriptions, vol. XLVIII. p. 355. also Inscript. 158. tom. I. p. 252. ed. Boeckh. cf. Taylor. ad Marm. Sandw. p. 36. Ap. Poll. IX. 80. 344 According to the assumption in chap. 4. 343 104 quality might have sold for twenty nummi, or five drach- mas 3 oboli of Attic money. A sucking pig was sold at Athens in the Peloponnesian war for three drachmas 345. A small sheep for a sacrifice, picked out for the use of the temple, is estimated in Menander at ten drachmas 346. In the time of Lysias the prices cannot have been at all lower, otherwise the dishonest guardian mentioned in this orator could not have set down sixteen drachmas for a lamb at the Dionysia, whatever might have been his eagerness to overrate the charges in his accounts 347. A remarkable but rather indeterminate statement is supplied by the oration against Euergus and Mnesibulus. The person for whom this speech was written had been robbed by Theo- phemus of fifty fine sheep together with the shepherd, and also a slave with a valuable water-pitcher and some shep- herd's implements 348. But the injured party was indebted to Theophemus for a fine, which together with Epobelia and Prytaneia amounted to 1313 drachmas and two oboli 349; and he maintains that the stolen sheep together with the shepherd were worth more than the fine 350. If we reckon the shepherd at a very high rate, viz. at more than three minas, it results that fifty sheep were worth 1000 drachmas; according to this the price of a fine full- grown sheep was at the least twenty drachmas. Concerning the value of goats, which were very plentiful in Attica, I have been able to obtain no information, except that in 345 Aristoph. Pac, 373. 346 Ap. Athen. IV. p. 146. E. VIII. p. 364. D. 347 Lysias in Diogit. p. 906. 348 See p. 1155. These sheep are called rgóßara paλará. 349 See p. 1158. 24. p. 1162.20. p. 1164. 10. 550 P. 1156. 15, 23. cf. p. 1164. 5. 105 Isæus 351, a hundred goats, together with sixty sheep, a horse, and some implements, are valued at thirty minas. As an example of luxury it may be worth mentioning, that Alcibiades gave seventy minas for a dog, which he shortly afterwards deprived of its chief beauty 352. (15.) On the subject of corn it will be necessary to enter into a more detailed examination. The consumption of Attica required a very considerable supply of corn. "No state," asserts Demosthenes, "consumes so large a quantity 353." The Athenian ambassadors in Livy 354 boast of having supplied 100,000 measures, although their state was obliged even to import corn for the use of the countrymen. But the main points to which we must direct our attention are, in the first place, what quantity of corn did Attica require? secondly, how much of this was it able to produce at home? and, thirdly, what quantity was it compelled to procure by importation? To answer these questions, the knowledge of which the Athenians considered necessary in a statesman 355, is far more difficult for us moderns, and yet is indispensable for an accurate insight into the political and statistical relations of Attica. I now undertake the solution of these problems, without presuming to maintain that I may not fall into error. According to the investiga- tion in a former part of this book, Attica may be assumed to have contained a population of 135,000 free inhabitants and 365,000 slaves. An adult slave received, according to 351 De Hagn. Hered. p. 293. The passage in the Speech de Philoct. Hered. p. 140. is still more indefinite. 352 Plutarch. Alc. 9. Poll. V. 44. 353 Demosth. de Corona p. 254. 21. and in Leptin. ut inf. 354 XLIII. 6. 355 Xenoph. Mem. Socrat. III. 6. 13. cf. Aristot. Rhet. I. 4. 106 accounts which can be fully depended upon, a chonix or the 48th part of an Attic medimnus per diem, and consequently consumed in a common year of 354 days 79 medimni. The Roman soldiers, according to Polybius, received about the same quantity, that is to say, at the most of a medimnus of wheat per month. If we assume that among the slaves there were 25,000 children, the 340,000 adults would then consume 2,507,500 medimni a year. And if four medimni a year are reckoned for a slave child, the total slave popula- tion would have consumed 2,607,500 medimni. Among the free inhabitants one half must be reckoned as children; but the adults also, as they were better fed than the slaves, probably did not consume so much corn. It will be enough to reckon two medimni for a child and four for an adult, altogether 450,000 medimni for 135,000 souls. cording to this the whole consumption of a common year would amount to 3,012,500 medimni, or since an exact calculation is impossible, in round numbers three millions, exclusively of the seed corn, which is more difficult to determine. If again it should be alleged that a larger quantity than this must have been required for the supply of the foreigners serving in the navy and the army, it should be remembered that the absence of a large number of soldiers and sailors from Athens would rather have had the effect of lessening the consumption, as the army was mostly supplied from abroad. On the other hand it can certainly be conceded that the necessity of supplying their country with imported provisions, increased the difficulty to the Athenians of employing many mercenaries, who were also to be provided with corn 356. Now that Attica did not produce these three million medimni, we know for certain; 356 Xenoph. Hellen. VI. 1. 4. 1 107 and corn was brought from all quarters into the market of the Piraeus, from the Pontus, Thrace, Syria, Egypt, Libya, and Sicily 357. It is well known that the imports of corn from the Pontus were very considerable, which was the cause that Byzantium was of so great importance to the Athe- nians, and partly for that very reason Philip of Macedon endeavoured to obtain possession of this town 358. In the time of Lysias private individuals imported corn from the Thracian Chersonese, probably from the Athenian Cleruchiæ 359. Some corn was brought from other countries by the Athenian merchants, and part was supplied by Cyprus and Rhodes through the medium of a carrying trade. From the former island there came to Athens in the time of Andocides corn-vessels in considerable numbers; of the latter, which was itself obliged to import corn, and according to Polybius subsequently obtained it from Sicily, we find an account in Lycurgus 360. In addition to this, Euboea, which was colonized with Cleruchi in the time of Pericles and Alcibiades, supplied corn and other products, which, before the occupation of Decelea by the Spartans, were imported over Oropus, but it subsequently became necessary to carry them in ships round Cape Sunium, which was fortified on this account 361. A very large quantity of corn must consequently have been imported, although it was not all for the internal consumption of the country, but some 357 Theophrast. de Plantis VIII. 4. see Anachars. tom. IV. chap. 55. Wolf ad Lept. p. 253. Meursius F. A. chap. IV. and many scattered passages in the Orators. 358 Demosth. de Corona ut sup. 359 Cf. Lys. in Diogit. p. 902. 360 Andocid. de suo reditu p. 85, 86. Lycurg. in Leocr. p. 149. Polyb. XXVIII. 2. 361 Thucyd. VII. 28. ef. VIII. 4. 108 ; to be sold in the Piraeus to foreigners. This makes the statement of Demosthenes appear the more unintelligible 362, that the imports from the Pontus, which did not amount to more than 400,000 medimni, might be taken as nearly equal to the whole importation from other countries; so that the total of the imports would have been little more than 800,000 medimni, exclusively of that which was never unshipped, but was transferred in the port of the Piraeus to other countries. Demosthenes appeals to the books of the Sitophylaces; but must we suppose that they agreed exactly with his words? All the Athenian orators, and even the noblest among them, Demosthenes, distorted the truth without the least hesitation, whenever it suited their own purposes. The total of the imports may be fairly taken upon an average in round numbers at a million medimni: but in particularly bad years, when even the fertile Boeotia (at least after two successive years of deficient harvests) required imported supplies 363, a much larger quantity was doubtless necessary for the consumption of Attica. If we compare this sum with the average number before assumed, it follows that Attica must have produced two million medimni, which in my opinion was not impos- sible. The country, it is true, is mountainous; but the height of the mountains is not so considerable as to have made them necessarily barren; the naked rock, which was not indeed uncommon in Attica, composed but a small 362 In Lept. 466, 467. The words πgòs roívvv äπavta tòv ix tãv ἄλλων ἐμπορίων ἀφικνούμενον ὁ ἐκ τοῦ Πόντου σῖτος εἰσπλέων ἐστὶν, do not signify an equality, but only an approximation in the quantity of the corn from the Pontus to the supplies received from other places, of which there is an evident proof in Herod. VIII, 44. cf. 48. 365 Xenoph. Hellen. V. 4. 54. 109 portion of the area, and where the stony bottom was mixed with a little earth, barley could be cultivated: and art performed its share. What portion of the area of Attica (amounting to 64,000 stadii or 2,304,000 plethra) was corn-land, it is impossible for me to ascertain; but that it was possible for as much land to be under the plough as was sufficient to produce two million medimni, cannot easily be denied. In the territory of the Leontini in Sicily 364, the Roman jugerum, about 23 plethra, was sown with a medimnus of corn; that is, about a bushel and a half of seed was reckoned for an acre and a quarter, the jugerum being equal to 28,800 Roman or 25,532 Rheinland, i. e. 34,468 English, feet. The fertile land yielded in good years eightfold, in the best tenfold. If we assume, as may be fairly done, the same measure of seed-corn for Attica, and the increase on account of the inferior pro- ductiveness of the soil as only sixfold (and even at the present day, when agriculture has undoubtedly fallen off, the multiplication of grain in Attica, according to Hob- house 365, is five and six for one and never more than ten), a plethron of land in Attica produced 24 medimni, and to produce two million medimni 888,890 plethra of land were requisite, and again for replacing the seed-corn 66,000 plethra besides. According to these suppositions the land in corn must have amounted to 955,500 plethra; the rest remained for fallow, plantations, vines (which were how- ever frequently cultivated together with barley, the branches of the vines being attached to the trees), leguminous plants, gardens, pasture-grounds, bog, water, waste-land, roads, ** 364 Cic. Verr. II. 3. 47. 365 A Journey through Albania and other Provinces of Turkey in Europe and Asia, to Constantinople, during the years 1809 and 1810. By J. C. Hobhouse, London, 1813. vol. I. p. 411. 110 and dwellings. How little exaggerated this supposition is; appears also to be proved from the fact, that the property of Phænippus containing 1440 plethra of land, although it was a boundary-estate with woods, produced yearly more than 1000 medimni of corn, and more than 800 metretæ of wine 366. To general principles of political arithmetic I have intentionally paid no regard, because, when applied to ancient times, they usually yield doubtful and uncertain conclusions; and still less will I institute a comparison with the produce of Lacedæmon, since the estimate which has been attempted to be made from Plutarch 367 is founded upon false assumptions. With an importation equal to a third part of the con- sumption, and in times of failure of the crops even this being insufficient, a great scarcity must necessarily have arisen 368, if judicious arrangements had not been devised in order to prevent the occurrence of such an event. The arrangements for the supply of corn were therefore con- ducted upon a large scale; Sunium was fortified, as has been remarked, in order to secure the sailing of the corn vessels round the promontory, armed ships convoyed the fleets laden with corn, as for example that from the Pontus 369; when Pollis the Spartan remained near Ceos, 366 Orat. in Phænipp. p. 1045. 5. 367 Lycurg. 8. There were in Laconia altogether 39,000 estates, of which 9000 were Spartan: one of these estates brought the proprietor a return of 82 medimni of barley, from which the whole produce has been calculated. It was not how- ever perceived that these 82 medimni were only the tribute or rent of the Helots; nor is it certain whether the passage is to be understood of the Spartan estates alone, or of the Lacedæmonian also. 368 Cf. e. g. Demosth. in Phorm. p. 918. 8. in Leptin. p. 467. 369 Demosth. de Corona p. 250, 251. in Polycl. p. 1211. 25. 111 Ægina, and Andros with sixty ships, Chabrias offered him battle, in order that the corn from Geræstus in Euboea might reach the Piraeus 370. The exportation of all grain was unconditionally prohibited: of the corn which arrived from foreign parts in the harbour of Athens the law re- quired that two-thirds should be brought into the city, and compliance with this regulation was enforced by the Overseers of the Harbour 371; that is to say, only one third could be carried away to other countries from the port of the Piraeus. In order to prevent as much as possible the accumulation and keeping back of corn 372, engrossing was very much restricted; it was not permitted to buy at one time more than fifty such loads as a man could carry (pogμol) 373. The violation of this law was punished with death. The corn-dealers or the engrossers of corn were 370 Xenoph. Hellen. V. 4. 61. Diod. XV. 34. 371 Harpocr. in v. queλnths quoglou, from Aristotle, and Lex. Seg. p. 255. where 'ATTIòv should be written instead of dorixov, and the rest of the article restored from Harpocration. 372 Cf. Plutarch. de Curiosit. ad fin. 373 Doguòs, from Pigw, generally means a platted basket, in which corn was probably carried. Taylor upon Lysias compares with it the cumeras or cumera of the Romans, of which there were two kinds, a greater and a less; the latter contained five or six modii, i. e. about an Attic medimnus. See Acron ad Horat. Serm. I. 1. 53. Probably at Athens the phormus was not very different from the medimnus: a medimnus of wheat weighed from about eighty to ninety pounds, and may therefore be fairly taken for a man's load: thus the army of Lucullus, according to Plutarch, was followed by 30,000 Galatæ, who carried 30,000 medimni of corn. The explanations of the grammarians afford no information as to the size, but the notion of Petit that Pogròs is the same as xóQwvos ( of the Attic medimnus) is absurd. Vid. Leg. Att. V. 5. 7. 112 also compelled to sell the medimnus for only one obolus more than the price they themselves had given. Notwith- standing which regulations, these men, who were for the most part aliens, raised the price of corn by competition in bad times, and often sold it upon the same day a drachma higher 374. Lysias cannot say enough of the villany of these usurers, who were then just as much detested as they are in modern times. They bought up corn under the pretence of providing for the interest of the people, or of having an order from the proper authorities; but if a war-tax was imposed, their momentary public spirit had altogether vanished. The public loss was their gain; and so much did they rejoice at the occurrence of any national calamity, that they never failed to have the first intelligence of it; or else they fabricated some disastrous news, such as that the ships in the Pontus had been taken or destroyed, that the trading-places were closed up, or the treaties were in danger of being broken off: even when external enemies were at rest, they annoyed the citizens by buying up the corn, and refusing to sell when it was most wanted, in order that people might not contend with them about the price, but be content to take it on their terms 375. Nor did even the merchants make any profit by it, a circumstance upon which much stress is laid by the modern teachers of political economy in favour of engrossing: on the con- trary they suffered severe injury from the combinations of the corn-dealers and their continual persecution 376. "If they were not menaced with the punishment of death,” · 374 See the Speech of Lysias against the Corndealers, more particularly p. 715, 718, 720. 375 Ibid. pp. 720, 721 sqq. 37 Ibid. pp. 726, 727. 113 says Lysias 377, "they would be scarcely endurable." Whilst therefore the sale of all other commodities was under the inspection of the Agoranomi, the State, in order to control the engrossing of corn, had set over this one branch of trade the separate office of the Sitophylaces 378, which originally consisted of three persons, afterwards of ten in the city and five in the Piraeus, probably because their duties had increased. These officers kept accounts of the imported corn, and it was also a part of their duties to inspect the meal and bread, and to take care that it was sold at the legal weight and price 379. But even the Sito- phylaces could not at times control the importunate competition on the part of the engrossers, who were 377 P. 725. 378 Ibid. p. 722. 379 Lysias ut sup. p. 717. mentions three Sitophylaces. The other statement rests upon the authority of Aristotle's State of Athens ap. Harpocrat. in v. roQuλaxis, where Valesius correctly reads ἦσαν δὲ τὸν ἀριθμὸν πεντεκαίδεκα· δέκα μὲν ἐν ἄστει, &c. Si- gonius R. A. IV. 3. silently follows the first account; Petit V. 5. 7. perceived the truth, but his emendation is false with regard to the position of the words, and dexa is only to be re- peated. Photius (in whose article for giro read gro) has the same error; he moreover states that in later times there were thirty (x') in the city and five in the Piraeus. All this is with- out doubt to be attributed solely to confusion, errors of the transcriber, and the false emendation of previously existing mistakes. The original passage, from which the different ac- counts were derived, was probably as follows: ἦσαν δὲ τὸν ἀριθμὸν πάλαι μὲν τρεῖς, ὕστερον δὲ πεντεκαίδεκα, δέκα μὲν ἐν ἄστει, πέντε δὲ ἐν Пga. Their duties may be seen from Demosth. in Lept. ubi Πειραιεῖ. sup. Harpocrat. and Lex. Seg. p. 300. The inspection of bread and prepared corn, particularly of barley meal (λqitα), occurs as early as in the age of Pericles. See the ancient comic poet ap. Plutarch. Præc. Polit. 15. VOL. I. I 114 Nokia punished with the greatest severity, and at times condemned to death 380; where we are as much astonished at the ir- regularity of the corn-police, as at the formidable adminis- tration of justice. A still greater loss to the state was caused by the speculations of the merchants, who, as Xenophon remarks 381, carried corn about to different parts, and did not sell it at the first place they arrived at, but where they had ascertained the price to be highest. Andocides 382 gives an account of a plot for turning the corn-fleet from Cyprus, which was bound for Athens, in another direction; but he compelled the contrivers to relinquish their plans. No one with regard to corn did Athens and the other Grecian states so much injury as Cleomenes of Alexandria, Alexander's Satrap in Egypt, who accumulated large stores of corn, fixed the prices arbitrarily, and on account of the number of servants whom he had engaged in the corn-trade, was enabled every where to ascertain the state of the market with accuracy. He employed three descriptions of persons, some who de- spatched the corn, the attendants of the latter, and others, who received it and unshipped on the spot: accordingly he did not allow his corn-vessels to touch at any com- mercial town before his assistants in that place had given information with regard to the state of the prices; if they were high, the corn was landed and sold, and if not, the vessel proceeded to some other place. By these means Lysias ut sup. pp. 718, 723, 725. extr. 726. init, Perhaps Demosth. in Timocrat. p. 743. 4. also refers to this subject, according to whom persons who acted fraudulently in dealings relating to corn were sentenced to imprisonment. 381 Econ. 20, 27. 382 De suo reditu pp. 85, 86. It is almost unnecessary to mention that Andocides was a merchant. 115 the corn at Athens rose considerably, until the importation from Sicily produced a relief 383. Of the contrivances of this obnoxious corn-dealer the author of the second book of the Economics attributed to Aristotle gives some other examples. At a dear time when the medimnus sold for ten drachmas, he convened the sellers for the purpose of ascertaining from them at what price they would transfer their corn to him: upon their agreeing to sell it to him cheaper than to the retail-dealers, he gave them the same price, but afterwards fixed the medimnus at 32 drachmas ! Upon the occasion of a great scarcity in foreign countries, and even in Egypt to a certain degree, he prohibited that any corn should be exported; upon the representation of the Nomarchs, that the taxes could not be paid if the ex- portation was not made free, he permitted it, but at so high a duty, that the exports were very limited, which the Nomarchs were deprived of their pretext for not paying the taxes, and moreover a large sum was raised from the export duty. The Athenians endeavoured by various measures to ensure or to increase the importation of corn. Of these was the general law that no money should be lent upon any vessel which did not bring to Athens a return-cargo of goods, among which corn was expressly specified 384 ; and also the more important law, which provided that no person dwelling in Attica, should import corn to any other place than into the port of Athens; the transgressor was subject to a Phasis, and also to an Eisangelia according to Lycurgus, and consequently to the punishment of death 385. 383 Demosth. in Dionysod. p. 1285. 384 See above chap. 9. 385 Demosth. in Phorm. p. 918. 5. in Lacrit. p. 941. 4, Lycurg. 116 Theophilus 386 asserts, that the corn-dealers at Athens had enjoyed a freedom from taxes; which evidently cannot be understood of the times of its independence, unless it was a transitory indulgence, or to a very limited extent. For the term Ateleia has several significations; it is either a general immunity (átéλeα áñávтwv), or a particular exemption from the liturgies, or from certain custom-duties and other taxes 387. For example, the Athenians gave the universal exemption from taxes to the Byzantian and Thracian re- fugees, who were resident at Athens in the time of Thrasy- bulus 388; and to Leucon the ruler of the Bosporus, who, together with his sons, had an exemption from custom-duties, as is particularly remarked 389. In this in Leocr. p. 156. and the speech against Theocrines. That the Phasis might be instituted in such a case is certain from the last- mentioned oration, from which (p. 1325. 28.) it is to be parti- cularly remarked that the informer received half the forfeited commodities. Concerning the Phasis against this offence see also the Commentators of Pollux VIII. 47. and Lex. Seg. p. 313. in v. φαίνειν, where the words ἢ ἔμπορον ἀλλαχόθι ἐργαζόμενον can only be referred to this practice. Concerning the Eisangelia against this offence see Matthiä Miscell. Philog. tom. I. p. 231. 386 Theophil. I. 2. according to the emendation of Salmasius de M. U. V. p. 195. upon the authority of MSS. 357 See Wolf ad Lept. p. LXXI sqq. 388 Demosth. in Lept. pp. 474, 475. 389 Demosth. in Lept. pp. 466–468. That he was free from custom-duties is evident from the comparison of the Ateleia given to him and to his sons with that granted by him to all the Athenians, p. 466. 29. This complete exemption appears to have been once given to the Thebans and Olynthians (Harpocrat. in v. 'Iσoreλns), unless it only means an exemption from pro- tection-money and liturgies, in case they should come as denizens to Athens, in the same manner that the Byzantians, in addition ✡ 117 general Ateleia was comprised the exemption from custom- duties, and from the liturgies (with the exception of the trierarchy, which was only disallowed under certain con- ditions regulated by law), and for aliens from the protection- money, and in particular cases from property-taxes; per- haps also the exemption from providing sacrifices (άtéλeia ieguv"), concerning which very little is known. That the corn-merchants could not have enjoyed this universal im- munity is alone evident from the fact of their not having possessed several of the individual exemptions. For, to say nothing of the general immunity, they must in the first place have had an exemption from the import-duties upon corn; now in Athens, the corn-duty was let out in farm 390, and it must therefore have entirely disappeared, if all corn-merchants had been allowed by law to import corn free of duty; the assertion in question does not therefore require any refutation. It is still less conceivable that they should have had permission to import or export other goods free of duty, although individuals were allowed this privilege for all or certain articles 391. Were they however to the rights of citizenship, gave an exemption of liturgies to all Athenians going to Byzantium. See the decree ap. Demosth. de Corona p. 256. and compare the decree of the Arcadians in Crete in Chishull's Ant. Asiat. p. 119. Mox vectigalia sacris faciundis a Plothensibus pendenda memorantur: a quibus ut immunitatem habeant, ex publico solvuntur ea vectigalia. Hinc vides quæ sit áréλα iɛgãv, quam memorat Demosth. adv. Lept. §. 105. ed. F. A. Wolfii, in qua jure hæsit editor Proleg. p. LXXI." Boeckh. ad Inscript. 82. tom. I. p. 122. 590 See the Speech against Neæra, p. 1353. 23. 391 An instance of free exportation, particularly of wood, which is undoubtedly to be referred to Athens, is given by Theophrastus Char. 23. 118 exempted from the regular liturgies? Unquestionably not; since, according to Demosthenes, so small a number either of the citizens or resident aliens were exempted from them 392. Moreover this orator would not have omitted to point out the prejudicial effects which the abolition of the immunity of the corn-merchants would have had upon the importation of corn, if any thing of the kind had existed; for in the speech against Leptines he searches for every argument against this abolition, and particularly in speaking of Leucon's Ateleia, he mentions the dangerous effect which the abolition of this exemption might have upon the free exportation from the Bosporus. Hence it may be concluded either that the immunity of the corn- merchants had no real existence, or that at any rate it amounted to a very trifling exemption. At the most it might be possible that the resident aliens who imported corn, were exempted from certain degrading liturgies, such as the Scaphephoria and the like, or from the pro- tection-money 393. Nor moreover is the least credit due to the absurd assertion of the scholiast to Aristophanes 394, that in Athens, the merchants had an immunity from all property-taxes. They were not even excepted from the liturgies, an exemption, which, it may be observed, would have been extremely unfair; Andocides, notwithstanding that he was a merchant, performed liturgies, though he was not appointed upon his own offer 395. The statement of the Scholiast is either an erroneous inference from the words of the poet, or a misconception of the account of 392 See book III. 21. 395 Concerning the latter see book III. 7. 394 Plut. 905. cf. Eccles. 1019. 395 Andocid. de Myst. p. 65. cf. Inscript. ap. Chandler II. 6. p. 48. Vit. X. Orat. p. 229. 119 Euphronius, upon whose authority he relies. The truth is, that those who traded by sea had an exemption from serving in war, although this privilege was probably cir- cumscribed within narrow limits 396. Now since the exemption from military service is also called Ateleia 397, it seems to me most probable, that when Theophilus speaks. of the immunity of the corn-merchants, he means nothing more than this exemption, which was granted alike to all merchants. It may be also observed, that Athens had public warehouses for corn in the Odeum, the Pompeum, the long Porch, and at the naval storehouse near the sea, where corn, bread, &c. were sold to the people 398. It is not however quite clear, whether this magazine was used exclusively for corn which belonged to the State, or whether grain was there measured out which was the property of private merchants. There are some grounds for considering the latter notion as the more probable 399. It is however certain that considerable stores were brought to Athens at the expence of the State, which must have been kept in this warehouse. This corn was in part purchased with the public money, and partly by voluntary contributions: a 396 This is stated by the Scholiast and Suidas in v. ἔμπορός εἰμι σκηπτόμενος. 397 Vid. Orat. in Neær. ubi sup. Whether however the im- munity from military service was comprised under the άriλua άæávтæv, may be fairly doubted, although military service was included among the rλn; at least I do not venture to assume it without express testimony to the point. 398 Demosth. in Phorm. p. 918. Concerning the public sale of corn see also Schol. Aristoph. Eq. 103. concerning the Odeum see Lex. Seg. p. 318. and upon the magazines of corn Poll. IX. 45, with the Commentators. 399 From Demosth, ut sup. p. 918. 24—26. 120 merchant named Chrysippus boasted of having given a talent for that purpose; Demosthenes also presented an equal sum 400. Certain persons named Sitonæ were ap- pointed to superintend the sale, whose office was not con- sidered unimportant, as it implied the entire confidence of the people; there were also Apodectæ, whose duty it was to receive the corn and to measure it out. The former situation was once filled by Demosthenes; and it was perhaps at that time that he gave the voluntary contribu- tion already mentioned 401. It was doubtless sold to the people at a very low price, as otherwise these donations of money would have been unnecessary; perhaps too the corn brought to Athens was at times distributed gratis. The want however of adequate information renders it impossible to form any certain conclusion; for even when the reader hopes that he has at length met with a statement which may be depended upon, the ambiguity of the expression and the difficulty of interpretation oppose insuperable difficulties in his way. Thus De- mosthenes, in the speech against Leptines, relates that two years before, during a scarcity of corn, Leucon had sent so large a quantity and at so cheap a rate, that fifteen talents, of which Callisthenes had the management, remained as an overplus. It may however be doubted whether a clear surplus actually remained, in the sense in which the commentators understand it, viz. that these fifteen talents formed a portion of the money set apart for the purchase of corn, which had not been entirely con- 400 Demosth. in Phorm. p. 918. 27. Attic Decree at the end of the Lives of the Ten Orators in Plutarch I. Theophrast. Char. 23. does not appear to refer to this point. 401 Poll. VIII. 114. Demosth. de Corona p. 310. 1. 121 sumed; or whether we are not rather to understand that as the corn had been bought up at so low a price, this sum remained as a net surplus profit to the State, after the corn had been sold to the people 402. To this donation of corn an account of Strabo has been with much apparent probability referred 403; for the context shews that he must allude to some particular distribution of corn, inas- much as he states expressly that Leucon had sent 2,100,000 medimni to the Athenians from Theudosia; and it is possible that this took place within the space of one year. For since Attica consumed 3,000,000 medimni, of which in the regular course of things it was required to produce 2,000,000, a failure of the crops might easily for once have caused the produce of the country to fall off to half the usual amount; and while the other countries, which also felt the effects of the general scarcity, were unable to furnish any supplies, Leucon alone made up the deficiency. On particular occasions free distributions of corn took place at Athens (σirodoσía), such as were very frequent in 402 The passage is as follows (p. 467. 14—17.): 'Aarà œgo- πέρυσι σιτοδείας παρὰ πᾶσιν ἀνθρώποις γενομένης οὐ μόνον ὑμῖν ἱκανὸν σῖτον ἀπέστειλεν, ἀλλὰ τοσοῦτον ὥστε πεντεκαίδεκα ἀργυρίου τάλαντα, ἃ Καλλισθένης διώκησε, προσπεριγενέσθαι. Τοσούτου should evi- dently be written with Hier. Wolf, and compare the note of F. A. Wolf ad Lept. pp. 257, 258. The date of the occurrence is about Olymp. 105. 4. The chief ambiguity lies in the word προσπεριγενέσθαι. It might be said that if Demosthenes had only wished to signify the residue of the money appointed for purchas- ing corn, he would have said περιγένεσθαι; and that προσπεριγένεσθαι shews that the excess was gained, viz. by the sale of corn to the citizens; but I do not venture to found any arguments upon this supposition. It must not on any account be supposed that the corn was sold abroad. 403 VII. p. 215. 122 Rome; the object of them being in both places to pacify the people 404. The presents in particular, which were at times made to the people from foreign parts, were dis- tributed gratis. Thus Demetrius Poliorcetes, in Olymp. 118. 2. promised to the Athenians 150,000 medimni of corn as a present from his father. Thus Spartocus, the son of Eumelus, king in the Bosporus, who reigned twenty years from Olymp. 119. 1., sent 10,000 medimni to the people of Athens 405. So again in Olymp. 83. 4. in the Archonship of Lysimachides, the Athenians during a scarcity of corn received from an Egyptian of the name of Psammetichus, who was not known to them, 40,000 me- dimni of wheat, which were distributed among the genuine citizens 406. With this distribution the Scholiast to Aris- tophanes 407 confounds another, in which each citizen 404 Aristoph. Vesp. 714. The word arodoria occurs in Pollux VIII. 103. who observes from Andocides that checking-clerks (avriygaQuis) were employed for some purposes connected with it. 405 Plutarch. Demetr. 10. Diod. XX. 46. Attic Decree in Chandler Inscript. II. 12. Concerning the time of Spartocus, or, as Diodorus incorrectly calls him, Spartacus, see Diod. XX. 100. The same person occurs in two inscriptions found at Pha- nagoria. Another more ancient Spartocus occurs in Diod. XII. 31, 36. (where see the Commentators), also king of the Cim- merian Bosporus, another in XIV. 93. and again another as king in the Pontus in Diod. XVI. 52. who was succeeded by his brother Pairisades. A Spartocus, father of Pairisades, perhaps the same with the son of Eumelus, is mentioned in an inscription. More however of these well known princes elsewhere. It may be observed that by Bosporus and Pontus the same kingdom is signified. 406 Philochorus ap. Schol. Aristoph. Vesp. 716. where μv- giadas should be written from Plutarch. Pericl. 37. Concerning the number of the citizens comp. above chap. 7. 107 Ubi sup. 123 received five medimni of barley, although he himself perceives that from 40,000 medimni 14,240 citizens could not have each received five medimni. The donation of which Aristophanes speaks, took place in Olymp. 89. 1. one year before the Wasps of the same poet, when, in the Archonship of Isarchus, an expedition was undertaken against Euboea. At that time it was probably expected that large supplies would be derived from this island, and fifteen medimni of corn had therefore been promised to each citizen, a new scrutiny being also instituted into the genuineness of their births; after all however they only received five medimni 408. The division of the lands in Euboea, which Aristophanes expressly distinguishes from this donation of corn, was perhaps promised at the same time. The donation of corn made by Atticus to the people, at the time of their severe distress, is also a well- known circumstance 409, Before I attempt to ascertain the prices of corn, some- thing must be said upon the measures by which it was sold. The Attic corn-medimnus (uédiuvos σingos) contained, ac- cording to the division commonly used in trade, six sextarii (EXTEïç) or forty-eight chonices, or 192 cotylas (xoTÚλαI): this last occurs both as dry and liquid measure 410. 409 Aristophanes in the text, where the words evias Qúywv allude to the examinations into the legal claims of the citizens, which were made with great strictness upon these occasions. Con- cerning the Archon, under whom the expedition was undertaken, see Palmer Exercit. in Auct. Græc. p. 738. Compare also the Fragments of Philochorus in the edition of Lenz and Siebelis pp. 51, 52. 409 Nepos Att. 2. 410 Pollux X. 113. IV. 168. VII. 195. cf. Athen. XI. p. 479. F. 124 Pollux in the fourth book reckons three cotylas instead of four to a choenix, which belongs to some other mode of computing than that in use among the Athenians. A choenix was the common daily allowance of food (nμegnola Tgoon) 411, particularly for slaves, from which circumstance the Corinthians, who had a great number of slaves, are said to have been called choenix-measurers by the Pythian priestess 412. An athlete indeed was able, according to Theophrastus, to consume two and half Attic chonices a day; and if Aglais required for one meal twelve minas of meat and a chus of wine, it is natural that she should eat four chonices of maize-bread. This woman was a player on the trumpet of great celebrity; Herodorus of Megara, also a famous trumpeter, consumed six chonices of maize- bread each day, eight minas of meat, or according to another authority twenty minas, and drank twice as much as the former person 413; not to mention many other gluttons, whose names may be found in Athenæus. The Spartans also, who lived upon little food, appear to have eaten much bread; each person was therefore bound to furnish monthly a medimnus of barley-meal to the public entertainment, together with a scanty portion of other provi- sions. The Athenian prisoners in the quarries of Syracuse only received half a chœnix, i. e. two cotylas of barley and one 411 Cf. Herod. VII. 187. from which it might indeed be in- ferred that a choenix was but a small quantity; but it must be remembered that he is speaking of soldiers, who would naturally consume a large quantity, and that there were also many persons of distinction. Suidas in v. Πυθαγόρα τὰ σύμβολος ἦν τάδε, Athen. p. 98. E. III. 412 Athen. VI. p. 272. B. 413 Elian. Hist. Var. I. 26. Poll. IV. 89. Athen. X. p. 415. F. λίτρα in Athenæus is the same as μνᾶ. 125 cotyla of water, which allowance was continued for eight months 414. That with this scanty food many of them perished in the first sixty days from hunger and thirst is not to be wondered at, particularly as barley contains but little nourishment 415. The size of these several measures immediately follows from the determination of the me- dimnus. Without paying any regard to the false state- ments of Eisenschmid and Romé de l'Isle, or to the ambiguous calculation of Rambach, I follow the account given by Ideler, which can alone be depended upon. The Athenian medimnus then, like the Sicilian, contained six Roman modii 416; but the modius, according to a decree of the people preserved in Festus, contained 16, the amphora 48 sextarii; consequently the Athenian medimnus con- tained about two amphora, which is also shewn by the testimony of Rhemnius Fannius 417, But the amphora or quadrantal was the Roman cubic foot, which as the Roman foot of long measure is nearly equal to 131 Paris 414 Concerning the Spartans see Plutarch. Lycurg. 12. Of the prisoners in Syracuse, Thuc. VII. 87. Plutarch. Nic. 29. cf. Eustath. ad Il. x. p. 1282. 15. Diod. XIII. 33. asserts that the proposal of Diocles was accepted, that the captive Athenians, Sicilians, and Italians should work in prison, and receive two choenices a day (XIII. 19.); but although he here speaks of a different period, viz. when they were brought out of the stone- quarries, and separated from the other prisoners, Diodorus does not deserve the least credit, and he has probably confounded two cotylas with two chonices. It is unnecessary to adduce any proof of the assertion that Diodorus is a wretched historian. 415 Athen. III. p. 115. 416 Nepos Att. 2. Cic. Verr. Frument. 46, 49. Suidas in v. pédievov, from which passage correct Zonaras in the same word. 417 Hujus (amphora) dimidium fert urna, ut et ipsa medimni amphora, terque capit modium. 126 lines, contained 1301 Paris cubic inches. The medimnus was therefore about equal to 2602 French or 3150.059 English cubic inches (for it can hardly be supposed that the ratio of the modius to the medimnus was precisely as 6 to 1); and the English pint of dry measure containing 33.6 cubic inches, the medimnus of 3150 cubic inches is equal to 93.75 pints, or 1 bushel 3 gallons 5.75 pints, i. e. nearly a bushel and a half. Of other corn measures, con- sistently with my plan, I shall only touch upon the artabe and the Boeotian cophinus. The former was a Persian measure, and contained, according to Herodotus 418, an Attic medimnus and three chonices. Others fix it at an approximate valuation as equal to the Attic medimnus 419. It was also in use in Egypt, where there was besides a smaller artabe, which only contained 33 Roman modii or 263 Athenian chonices 420. If the capacity of this measure is doubled, it gives 533 Athenian choenices, which differs so little from the value of the greater artabe in Herodotus (51 chœnices), that, as it appears, we may fairly assume the smaller artabe to have been exactly half the greater, and either that the statement of Herodotus is too low, or that the valuation of the smaller artabe at 3 Roman modii is somewhat too high, or, lastly, that the ratio of the Athenian medimnus to the Roman modius has been estimated a fraction too low. The Boeotian cophinus, which was used both as a wet and dry measure, contained two 421 choëis, i. e. a quarter metretes, or 36 cotylas, since the metretes contained 144 cotylas, which is equivalent to nine chœnices, or medimnus of Athenian measure. 16 418 I. 192. 419 Suidas, Hesychius, Polyæn. IV. 3.32. Epiphanius Ponder. 24. 420 Wesseling ad Diod. XX. 96. 421 Poll. IV. 169. Hesych. in xópios. 127 The prices of different kinds of corn were, as may be supposed, very different. In Sicily and upper Italy the price of barley was only half that of maize, in Athens probably, as in Lusitania, it amounted to two thirds of the price of the latter 422; but where the price of corn is men- tioned, the particular description of grain is not always specified. It may be seen from examples, that the prices from the time of Solon to that of Demosthenes were con- tinually rising; yet again there frequently existed at the same period a great fluctuation, according to the greater or less productiveness of the years, the increase or diminu- tion in the imports, the prejudicial effects of the engrossers both in and out of Attica, or the imposition of high custom-duties in foreign parts, or the accidental remittance of them to the Athenians; thus for example Leucon and Pairisades, kings of the Bosporus, the former of whom used to levy a duty of a thirtieth upon all exported corn, granted to the Athenian people an exemption from this tax 423. Prices at Athens were never again so low as in the time of Solon, when the medimnus was sold for a drachma 424. Barley-mcal (λpira) was sold in the age of Socrates at two drachmas the medimnus, and at an obolus for four chonices 425; by which however we are not to understand meal prepared after the modern way. Diogenes the Cynic reckons, that in his age the choenix of barley- 422 Concerning Upper Italy and Lusitania see above chap. 10. I will presently speak of Sicily and Athens. 423 Demosth. in Lept. p. 467. in Phorm. p. 917. 25. 424 Plutarch. Solon. 23. Petit. Leg. Att. I. 1. 3. wishes to read ten drachmas for one, which really almost borders on madness. 425 Plutarch. de Animi Tranquillitate 10. Stob. Serm. XCV. p. 521. Comp. Barthél. in the Mém. de l'Acad. des Inscriptions, tom. XLVIII. p. 394. concerning the price of corn. 128 meal sold at two chalcûs, and consequently the medimnus at two drachmas 426: but this can only refer to the cheapest years, for at a former period the common price at Athens had been much higher. In a play of Aristo- phanes 427 a man declares that he has lost a hecteus of maize, by not having gone to the assembly, and conse- quently not receiving his three oboli, whence it may be concluded that about the 96th and 97th Olympiads, the medimnus of maize sold for three drachmas, which agrees very well with the price of barley just quoted. But in the time of Demosthenes, and even after Alexander's ex- pedition against Thebes, five drachmas were a moderate price, at which during a scarcity some of the more liberal corn-dealers sold their maize: thus Chrysippus sold 10,000 medimni at this price 428. According to the speech against Phænippus 429, even barley must have been at six drachmas for a long time, as eighteen drachmas are stated to be three times the former price. The prices in other Grecian States were not very different. In the second book of the Economics attributed to Aristotle, it is stated that the price of barley-meal at Lampsacus was four drachmas, but that the State once fixed it upon a particular occasion at six drachmas, in order to obtain a profit of the difference. When Sicily came under the Roman dominion, the latter people fixed for supplies the Frumentum Decumanum Alterum at three sesterces for each modius, the Imperatum and Estimatum of maize at four and of barley at two sesterces the modius; a price which must at that time have been moderate, as the Romans would doubtless have 426 Diog. Laert. VI. in Vit. Diog. 127 Eccles. 543. 428 Demosth. in Phorm. p. 918. 429 P. 1048. 24. ! 129 fixed a low rate, although according to the statement of Cicero, it was not insupportable to the cultivators. Con- sequently the medimnus of the Decumanum Alterum cost at that time four drachmas the medimnus, of the Impe- ratum and Estimatum of barley four drachmas four oboli, and of maize five drachmas two oboli of Attic money. If the lowness of these prices should seem start- ling, we must remember how dense was the population of this country and how large the exportation. In earlier times however corn, as may be inferred from the price of cattle 430, must have been much cheaper in Sicily; and subsequently, as for example in the time of Verres, prices did not attain even this height, on account of the decreasing population of the cities; the medimnus of maize was commonly sold at that time for twelve sesterces, or two drachmas four oboli, and never rose to more than fifteen sesterces, or three drachmas four oboli 431. It is also to be observed that in the prices of the supplies of Sicilian corn, as the Romans had fixed them, the cost of transport to each separate place of destination was likewise included. Such prices as the following are extraordinary, viz. when corn rose at Athens to sixteen and barley to eighteen drach- mas; also at Rome in the year of the city 544, the Sicilian medimnus of corn was sold, according to Polybius, at fifteen drachmas, or rather denarii; and in Dollabella's army, from which the supplies by way of Laodicea were cut off, the medimnus of maize was sold for twelve drachmas 432. From a very corrupt passage of Strattis 430 See above chap. 14. 451 Cic. Verr. Frument. 74, 75, 81, 84. 132 Demosth. in Phorm. p. 918. Orat. in Phænipp. p. 1045. 4. Polyb. IX. 44. Cic. ad Fam. XII. 13. VOL. I. K 130 preserved in Pollux 433, so much at least may be gathered, that a slave, to the great astonishment of his master, pre- tends to have bought a Boeotian cophinus of barley-meal for about four drachmas, which gives for the medimnus 21 drachmas two oboli; and it may be inferred from the same grammarian that another writer spoke of maize being sold for 32 drachmas, without doubt referring to the usurious practices of Cleomenes, which I have already noticed 434; not to mention that at Athens during the siege of Sulla, the medimnus of maize rose to a thousand drachmas, the inhabitants being reduced to feed even on shoes and leathern bottles; and in like manner at Casili- num, where the Prænestini were besieged by Hannibal, the same measure was sold for 200 drachmas 435. 433 Pollux IV. 169. Petit ut sup. reckons from this passage the medimnus at 128 drachmas. 434 Pollux IV. 165. where there stood formerly the word τριος xovτadideαxμíπvgyo, an uncouth form, which Petitus alone re- tained, and proposed to change to τριακονταδιδραχμόπυργοι. The reading of Voss's manuscript, τριακονταδίδραχμοι πυροὶ, is evidently the right one, and consequently the price of maize is meant; manifestly that which was fixed by Cleomenes. The present reading in the text, dideaxua, is entirely without foundation, as well as Kühn's conjecture, τριακαιδεκάδραχμοι: τρικοντάδραχμοι, the correction of Jungermann, has indeed some probability; however I consider the reading of Voss's manuscript to be correct for this reason, that the use of the singular compound relaxovra- δίδραχμοι instead of δυσκαιτριακοντάδραχμοι appears to be the very reason why Pollux quotes the word. 435 See Plutarch. Sulla 13. and Strabo V. p. 164. where in the account of Casilinum the medimnus is mentioned alone, without the thing measured, which ought never to have appeared surprising to so excellent a scholar as Casaubon, as it so frequently occurs. Pliny, Frontinus, and Valerius Maximus substitute indeed a mouse in the place of this measure, but Strabo had too 1 131 The varieties of bread were extremely numerous in Greece, and particularly at Athens, and the invention of the Athenians was directed with great success to this department of the culinary art 436. Athenæus and Pollux will supply the amateur of the arts of cookery and baking with sufficient materials for enquiries, which we neither feel disposed nor entitled to enter upon. The most com- mon distinction is between maize-bread (agros) and barley- bread (µága): λpra sometimes means barley-meal itself, and sometimes a bread made of barley-meal, of a very fine quality, and adapted for cookery 437. I have not however been able to meet with any clear statement in reference to the price of bread, but it was probably high in proportion to that of corn; for, if we may judge from the rate of interest, a great profit must have been obtained upon the capital employed in the preparation of bread. At Athens four large and eight small loaves used to be baked out of a choenix of corn; consequently one large or two small loaves out of a cotyla 438; in dear times, when for example corn was at sixteen drachmas, a loaf of maize-bread of this kind, probably a large one of a cotyla, might have sold for an obolus: to which may be referred the fact, that at the very same time maize-bread was sold in the much judgment to say, as the Commentators impute to him, that two hundred drachmas were given for a mouse, and that the sellers died, but that the buyers saved their lives. We must indeed, if this story be true, suppose that great events spring from little causes. 436 Athen. III. p. 112. C. &c. 437 Omitting other passages, I only refer to Xenoph. Econ. 8. 9. Plat. Rep. II. p. 372. B. Poll. VI. 78. Concerning the word μa see below chap. 23. 438 Schol. Aristoph. Vesp. 438. Lysistrat. 1208. 132 Piraeus in loaves of an obolus 439. At Alexandria the ἄρτος ὀβελίας or ὀβελίτης was sold for an obolus 440, and probably the same was the case at Athens 441, which how- ever gives no information with regard to the price, as the size is unknown; and this Alexandrian bread was not of the ordinary kind, but something more costly, which is opposed to the common maize-bread 442. There were also loaves of a much larger size, for instance of three chonices 443; and at the Dionysia they carried around in honour of the divine inventor, loaves of from one to three medimni, which were likewise called ἄρτοι ὀβελίαι 444. (16.) The common measure for liquids was the metretes, which contained twelve choeis or 144 cotylas, and to which the common vessel (ἀμφορεὺς, κάδος, κεράμιον) was adapted. The Roman amphora, or the solid foot, was according to 439 Demosth. in Phorm. p. 918. 440 Concerning which bread and its price see Pollux I. 248. and in other places, Athen. III. p. 111. B. who has been tran- scribed by Eustath. ad II. N. p. 930. ad Odyss. A. p. 39. 38. "1 441 If the interpretation of ßoxías grovs in Aristophanes given in Lex. Seg. p. 111. is correct. 442 Pherecrates ap. Athen. ubi sup. and Nicochares the comic poet ibid. XIV. p. 645. C. It may be observed that the supposition, which is mentioned in Athenæus, and thence in Eustathius, and which occurred to Seber ad Poll. I. 248. that this bread received its name from the price, is extremely improbable, although åßeλòs and ¿ßoλòs are the same word, and originally meant a fork or spit, and afterwards the coin so called. Cf. Plutarch. Lysand. 17. Poll. IX. 77. and the Commentators, Etymol. in ßenixos, also the Commentators upon Athenæus ubi sup. and Taylor ad Marm. Sandw. p. 49. It was no doubt so called from the forks or long pieces of wood upon which it was baked in the ashes. See Athen. III. ubi sup. and the Commentators, Photius p. 229. 443 Xenoph. Anab. VII. 3. 23. 414 Poll. VI. 75. cf. Eustath. 133 4 3 the testimony of Rhemnius Fannius 3 of the Attic metretes: but the Attic medimnus is the double of the amphora; consequently the metretes was of the Attic medimnus, which is also evident from its being equal to 144 cotylas. The contents of the medimnus were in a former place ascertained to have been 2602 Paris inches, and therefore the metretes is equal to 2362.5 English cubic inches, or 81.818 pints, i. e. 10 gallons 1 pints of wine measure. Who then is not astonished at the extraordinary cheapness of wine in ancient times, upon reading of such prices, as have been already quoted with regard to Lusitania, at which more than ten gallons of unmixed wine sold for 3d.? And since the ancients allowed one part of wine to two of water, without intending to dilute it much, ten gallons of such liquor were sold for a penny. The common wine must therefore have been looked upon as the cheapest of all necessaries, the causes of which phenomenon have been already stated. In Lusitania the metretes of wine appears to have been equal in price to the medimnus of barley, but at Athens it seems to have been even cheaper than barley; for according to the speech against Phænippus, when prices were three times higher than usual, barley was sold at eighteen and the native Athenian wine at twelve drach- mas 445. Therefore, according to the usual price, the metretes of wine was sold for four drachmas: even this rate however, as well as six drachmas for a medimnus of barley, must have been considered dear; there would be no danger of exaggeration, if the half of this price were assumed as an average for cheaper times. In an agreement in Demosthenes 446 300 casks (xepάuia) of Mendæan wine are estimated at 600 drachmas, that is, the cask or the metretes 445 Orat. in Phænipp. p. 1048. 24. 446 In Lacrit. p. 928. extr. 134 came to two drachmas, although Mendæan wine was used even at the most sumptuous entertainments of the 'Macedo- nians 447. It is mentioned by Polybius 448 that the Rhodians bought from the Sinopians, when the latter were invaded by Mithridates in Olymp. 179. 4., for the sum of 140,000 drachmas 10,000 casks of wine, 300 talents of prepared hair, a hundred talents of prepared strings, a thousand complete suits of armour, four catapults with darts and attendants, and 3000 gold coins. Whence it is easy to perceive that this could only have been possible in case the price of wine did not exceed that which has been above mentioned. According to the grammarians a tricotylus of wine, i. e. three cotylas, was sold at an obolus 449; which gives for the metretes eight drachmas. This therefore was either of a superior sort, or it only appears dearer because the retail-dealers (xáяnλ) who sold it by the obolus, added considerably to the price. On the other hand there were also very costly wines; for example the Chian wine, as early as in the time of Socrates, sold for a mina the metretes 450. Oil, although it was produced in large quantities in Attica, Asia Minor, and the islands, appears to have maintained a higher price on account of the great demand for it in ancient times, for the purposes 447 Athen. IV. p. 129. D. to omit other passages concerning the goodness of this wine. 448 1V. 56. τρι 449 Schol. Aristoph. Thesmoph. 750. and Hesych. in v. τęɩ- xérvλos. J. Capellus de Mensur. II. 43. finds a still higher price in Pollux IV. 169. according to which three choeis cost four drachmas, and consequently the metretes sixteen drachmas; but his supposition rests upon an alteration in the text, which cannot be assumed. 450 Plutarch. de Anim. Tranquil. 10. 135 of light, for dressing meat, and for the gymnasia; yet as regards the Greeks I have only been able to find a single statement of its price, and this is given in the second book of the Economics attributed to Aristotle 451, where it is stated that the chus of oil was sold at Lampsacus for three drachmas, and afterwards that a duty was laid upon it equal to half its price, which raised it to four and half drachmas; consequently the metretes without the duty was at 36 drachmas; which indeed as compared with modern prices is a low rate. Salt, which was measured by phormi, or by medimni and chœnices 452, was easily imported into Athens on account of her dominion of the sea; and as long as Nisæa in Megaris was in the hands of the Athenians, it was brought over from thence with the greatest facility 453. Besides this there were salt springs in Attica itself, opposite Gephyra on the other side of the Cephisus, and salt-works upon the seashore 454; I have not however found any thing with regard to the price of salt, 451 II. 2.7. The duty was laid upon wine, corn, and other commodities at half their price; but in the part where the duty upon oil should be stated there is an hiatus in the text. It is evident that the chus of oil, after the addition of the duty, was sold for 4 drachmas: but that the duty upon the chus was only three oboli, as Camerarius gives it in his translation, is an arbitrary assumption. The whole context confirms the supposi- tion, that a duty equal to half the former price was also laid upon oil. I therefore restore καὶ τοῦ ἐλαίου, τὸν χοῦ ὄντα δραχμῶν τρίων πωλεῖν τεττάρων καὶ τριωβόλου, and the price in the text is given according to this hypothesis. 452 Poll. X. 169. from the Demioprata, Aristoph. Acharn. 814. (See also Aristot. H. A. VIII. 10. Eudem. Eth. VIII. 2.) 453 Aristoph. Acharn. 760. with the Scholiast and Commenta- tors. 454 See the Piræean Inscription in Chandler II. 110. 136 except that the Athenians once endeavoured to lower it by a decree of the people 455. As to the supply of wood, we may observe that the Athenians were forced to import large quantities of timber, particularly for the uses of shipbuilding, from distant countries, especially from Macedonia 456; even palisades and props for the mines were brought by sea 457; small wood for burning they had in plenty, particularly beech-wood, from which charcoal was made, a business in which the Acharnians were chiefly engaged 458. Charcoal, firewood, and faggots were brought into the city in baskets, carried either by men or on asses 459; thus Phænippus sent to Athens every day from his boundary-estate in Cytheron six asses laden with wood, which produced each day twelve drachmas 460, whence an ass's load may be estimated at two drachmas. (17.) The meals of the Athenians, which were called μingoτgánεlo, were for the most part scanty, and had little that was agreeable 461. But although the ordinary fare was not very expensive, the great banquets with ointments, female players upon the flute and cithara, Thasian wine, eels, cheese, honey, &c. were by no means cheap; "they cost at least," says Menander, "a small talent." In the Flatterers of Eupolis a repast of this kind is reckoned at 455 Aristoph. Eccles. 809. and Scholiast. 456 Thucyd. IV. 108. Xenoph. Hell. VI. 1. 4. Demosth. in Alexand. gì œuvênxãv p. 219. 4. cf. in Timoth. p. 1192, 1. p. 1195. 1. 457 Demosth. in Mid. p. 568. 458 Aristoph. Acharn. 459 Poll. VI. 111. VII. 109. 460 Orat. in Phænipp. p. 1041. 3. 461 See the comic poet Antiphanes ap. Athen, IV. p. 131. E. Lynceus ibid. F. Alexis ibid. p. 137. D. 137 a hundred drachmas, and the wine at the same sum 462; an expence sufficiently great for Athens, though little in comparison with the extravagance and debauchery of the kings. Alexander's table for sixty or seventy persons cost a hundred minas a day 463. Every thing eaten, with the exception of what was prepared from corn, was originally comprehended under the name of Opson (pov, óþúviov): Plato expressly comprises under it salt, olives, cheese, onions, cabbage, figs, myrtle-berries, walnuts, and pulse 464; and it is evident that roots such as radishes, turnips, &c. and all preparations of meat and fish, were also included; but by degrees the usage of this word was changed, so that at length it signified only fish, the favourite food of the Athenian epicures 465. The slave in Terence buys cabbage and little fish for an old man's meal at an obolus 466, but according to Theophrastus 467 a miser would have been disgraced by allowing his wife only three chalcûs for opson; three oboli appear to have been sufficient for a few moderate persons to buy the opson uncooked 468; hence Lysias 469 thinks that a guardian's charge of five oboli for the opson of two boys and a little girl was excessive. Three oboli were not sufficient to procure opson for so expensive a person as Aristippus 470, and ten drachmas 462 Poll. IX. 59. 463 Athen. IV. p. 146. C. 464 Athen. VII. p. 277. A. Plat. de Rep. II. p. 372. C. cf. Xenoph. Econ. 8. 9. 465 Athen. VII. p. 276. E. 466 And. II. 2. 32. 467 Char. 28. 468 Thugenides (not Thucydides) ap. Poll. VI. 88. 469 In Diogit. p. 905. 470 Diog. Laert. in Vit. Aristipp. 138 71 ! appear to the slave in Terence 471 to be very inadequate for a marriage-feast. The following are particular state- ments of prices, of which however some are inaccurate. Four small pieces of dressed meat cost an obolus ac- cording to Antiphanes; a piece of meat, as it was pre- pared for eating, probably of a tolerable size, half an obolus according to Aristophanes 472. In the Comic Poet Aris- tophon 473 a landlord appears to receive five chalcus for some small livers and an intestine, probably a sausage; perhaps the same sum from several persons who dined together. A partridge, for which any other person would have given an obolus, Aristippus is said to have bought for 50 drachmas 474; one extreme is as incredible as the other. A dish of Boeotian fieldfares for a festival is sold for a drachma in Aristophanes; seven maize-thiefs, birds which in places where they are abundant are usually very cheap, were not considered dear at an obolus 475; and I may also mention, that in the Athenian bird-market, a jackdaw was sold for one obolus and a crow for three 476. Of fish Athens had a superabundance, and the smaller varieties, which are nearly worthless in all countries that are copiously supplied with fish, bore, as may be sup- posed, a very low price. A species of small fish called membrades may be bought for four chalcus, but not eels or thunny-fish, says the comic poet Timocles 477 ; of aphuas (άpúα), which, according to Lucian, were ex- 471 Andr. II. 6. 20. 472 Antiphanes ap. Athen. IV. p. 431. E. Aristoph. Ran, 562. 473 Pollux IV. 70. 474 Diog. Laert. ubi sup. 475 Aristoph. Acharn. 960. Av. 1079. with the Scholiast. 476 Aristoph. Av. 18. 477 Ap. Athen. VI, p. 241. A. 139 ceedingly small and light, a large quantity could be bought for an obolus; their cheapness is particularly mentioned. The sausage-seller in Aristophanes promises to offer up a thousand goats to Artemis Agrotera (outbidding in jest the offering of thanks for the battle of Marathon), when- ever a hundred trichides, likewise a small kind of fish, are sold for an obolus 478, which was therefore an impossibility. Larger and better fish bore a higher price, and the fish- mongers were decried as a shameless and avaricious race; for a sea-polype they asked four oboli, for a cestra (pro- bably a kind of pike) eight oboli, for two cestreis (mugiles) ten oboli, for which eight were offered; for a sea-wolf (λáßgat) a fishmonger asked ten oboli, without fixing in what currency; but when it comes to paying, says Diphilus, he had meant Æginetan oboli 479. A dish of echini cost when dressed eight oboli, according to the comic poet Lynceus 480. Eels, particularly those that came from the lake Copais, were a favourite dish of the Athenians, and as well as poultry and birds, were brought from Boeotia 481. A Copaic eel cost three drachmas in the time of Aris- tophanes 482. Salted or pickled provisions (rágxos) par- ticularly fish, were brought from the Pontus, Phrygia, Egypt, Sardinia, and Cadiz 483, and were very abundant at Athens, in different degrees of goodness; the common sorts were considered as inferior to meat, and were the food of the lower classes and of the country people, according to 478 Lucian. Piscat. 48. Aristoph. Eq. 646, 660. 479 Athen. VI. p. 224. C. to p. 227. B. 480 Ap. Athen. IV. p. 132. B. 481 Aristoph. Pac. 1005. and the Scholiast; also Schol. Lysist 703. Poll. VI. 63. Aristophanes in the Acharnenses. 482 Aristoph. Acharn. 961. 483 Poll. VI. 48. 140 Demosthenes and Aristophanes-as the proverb says, the pickle often cost one obolus, but the sauce two 484. The comic poet Philippides 485 reckons a dish of pickles for one person at two or three oboli, and the capers for it in a separate vessel at three chalcus. It is hardly worth men- tioning that vegetables, such as cabbages, &c. were sold at a cheap rate; of leguminous plants the same may be concluded from an expression of Demosthenes 486, who, in order to point out the great increase of prices, says, "you know that even vetches were dear.” Beans, which were eaten out of the shells as a remedy against drunkenness, were, according to the statement of Timocles, who perhaps exaggerates in joke, so dear that eight pods were sold for an obolus, although they always used to be sold by the choenix 187. A choenix of olives in the time of Socrates sold for two chalcus, the cotyla of Attic, that is of the best honey, cost five drachmas 488. The warm beverage, which the ancients drank instead of tea, cost a chalcûs according to Philemon 489, 11 484 Οβολοῦ τάριχος, δι᾿ ὀβολῶν τἀρτύματα, Michael Apostol. XIV. 9. 485 Ap. Athen. VI. p. 230. A. At Rome in the time of Cato the elder, a hundred denarii, or, as Polybius usually says, drachmas, were given for a cask of pickles from the Pontus. See Polyb. XXXI. 24. 486 In Androt. p. 598. 4. 487 Timocles ap. Athen. VI. p. 240. E. Concerning their use see Alexis ap. Poll. VI. 45. and the Commentators; and for their measure see Inscript. 123. tom. I. p. 164. ed. Boeckh. 488 Plutarch. de Animi Tranquil. 10. The expression of Aris- tophanes (Pac. 253.) that the Attic honey was worth four oboli, must be understood proverbially to mean something expensive and costly. See Schol. and Suid. in v. τετρώβολον and τεττάρων ößoλav. Küster has misunderstood both passages. 489 Ap. Poll. IX. 67. who (cap. 70.) correctly infers from the 141 (18.) The clothing of the Athenians varied considerably in materials, colour, and make, according to the time of year as well as the age, family, rank, property, taste, and object of the wearers; and fashion, although not so all- powerful as in modern days, had also its influence at that time. Woollen garments were the most common; although linen ones were worn, especially by women, and were at a low price, with the exception of the finest kinds 190. The Amorgian stuffs were an expensive material, which were finer than Byssus and Carpasus, almost transparent, and sometimes dyed; they are said to have derived their name from the island Amorgus, where they were best manufac- tured; although others derive it from the dye or the plant (aμógyn), from which latter word the island itself probably received its name 491. Even woollen garments, if the material and wearing were of superior quality, as the Persian Caunace for example 192, were sold at a high price. The prices which I have met with are as follows: Socrates, as stated by Plutarch 493, considers an Exomis (a dress worn by the common people) to be cheap when sold at Athens for ten drachmas. This was a garment with one sleeve, the other arm being left bare. A Chlamys, the lowness of the price that water for drinking and not for bathing is meant. The words of Philemon are, χαλκοῦ θερμὸν ἦν, in the reckoning of a guest with his landlord. The preceding words in this corrupt passage, καὶ μάλα τριημιωβολιαῖ, ἐστὶ, refer to the other articles furnished to the guest. 490 Vid. Pseudo-Plat. Epist. XIII. p. 363. A. 491 They were called ἀμοργίδια, ἀμοργίδες, χιτῶνες ἀμόργινοι. See concerning these Aristoph. Lysistrat. 150. and Schol. Lysistrat. 736. Schol. Æschin. p. 737. Reiske, Eustath. ad Dionys. Perieg. Poll. VII. 57. 74. Harpocrat. Hesych. Suid. Etymol. 192 Aristoph. Vesp. 1132, 1140. 493 Ubi sup. 142 usual dress of the knights and young men, of Macedonian and Thessalian origin 194, is called rgiσráτngos in Pollux 495, by which doubtless the weight is not meant, but that its value amounted to three silver staters, or twelve drachmas. A citizen in the Ecclesiazusæ of Aristophanes 196, who appears without any upper garment, his wife having al- ready gone with it to the assembly, declares, that since the preservation of the State is to be the subject of debate, he himself is in want of a preservation of four staters (σωτηρίας τετραστατήρου); in this instance no one can doubt with Pollux 497 whether the coin or the weight is meant, as it is evident that sixteen drachmas, the price of the upper gar- ment, are alluded to. When the young man in the Plutus 498 requires twenty drachmas from his aged mistress for an upper garment, it is possible that he intended to make her pay for an expensive one. Socrates mentions that purple was sold for three minas, quoting it as an example of the increased dearness of articles of luxury at Athens 499; it may be doubted whether by this he means a garment or a certain measure of dyed cloth; in my opinion the former is the right supposition: it is well known that the gar- ments made of the Byssus which grew in Achaia were weighed against gold 500. In the article of shoes great luxury was displayed; Laconian, which were the dress 494 Poll. VII. 46. X. 124. and the note of Hemsterhusius, also X. 164. Ammonius in v. xhaµùs and Strabo ubi sup. Dorvill. ad Charit. p. 433. ed. Leips. 495 VI. 165. 496 Vs. 413. 497 IX. 58. 498 Vs. 883. 499 Ap. Plutarch. ubi sup. 500 Plin. Hist. Nat. XIX. 4. 143 shoes of men, Sicyonic, Persian, Tyrrhenian, Scythian, Argive, Rhodian, Amyclæan, Thessalian, and Thracian shoes, with several others, occur in the different provinces of Greece; and like our fashion of calling trifling things after celebrated names 501, so they had various kinds of shoes named after distinguished persons, such as Alcibiadean, Iphicratean, &c. 502 A pair of Sicyonic woman's shoes cost two drachmas according to Lucian 503; for a pair of man's shoes the above-mentioned youth in the Plutus of Aristo- phanes 504 requires eight drachmas, which is comparatively high, and either too high a price is supposed to be given, or it was for some very expensive and ornamented kind. Ointment is among the dearest articles of ancient times. A cotyla of fine ointment, probably from the East, cost at Athens, according to Hipparchus and Menander 505, 505 from five to ten minas. The interlocutor in the comic poet. Antiphanes is not satisfied with moist ointment at two minas the cotyla 506. It is manifest that the Athenians, although they were much addicted to the use of ointments, and every thing contributing to the refined enjoyments of life, could not have easily afforded to pay so high a price. It is therefore probable that for the most part they made use of inferior sorts; of such ointment perhaps as occurs 501 Aristophanes passim, and particularly Pollux VII. 85-89. 502 ᾿Αλκιβιάδεια or ᾿Αλκιβίαδες (ὑπόδημα), Ιφικρατίδες, Δεινιάδες, Σμινδυρίδεια, Μυνάκια. See Pollux ubi sup. with his Com- mentators, Athen. XII. p. 534. C. Schol. Lucian. Dial. Meretr. The Iphicratean were not however a mere variety of fashion, but an improved kind of shoes for the soldiers. 503 Dial. Meretr. 14. 504 Vs. 984. 505 506 Ap. Athen. XV. Ap. Athen. ibid. p. 691. C. 144 in Lucian, a small alabaster-box of which, brought from Phoenicia, was sold for two drachmas 507. (19.) A knowledge of the prices of different kinds of furniture, implements, arms, and ships, would not be unimportant for the determination of many questions. The ancient writers however afford but few data, and of those which we have some are too high, to be looked upon as the customary prices, although it is probable that, notwithstanding the low rate of wages and the existence of slavery, the manufacturers on account of the high rate of interest obtained a large profit, which raised the price of certain commodities. Passing over the works of art, the value of which was only determined by the taste of the purchaser, I adduce the following examples. A little cart for a child's plaything, cost an obolus according to Aristophanes, and a small oil-flask (λnxúbiov) the same sum, an earthen cask three drachmas 508; a sideboard (éyyubńxn) (ἐγγυθήκη) decorated with brazen figures of satyrs and heads of oxen 509, not particularly well executed, thirty drachmas; a small two-wheeled chariot for racing, probably with many ornaments of ivory, brass, silver, &c. in the same manner that the ancients used them upon beds and other kinds of furniture 510, together with the wheels, cost two minas 511. The price of a The price of a scythe or sickle (dgéπavov) in time of peace is evidently exaggerated in joke by Aris- tophanes 512, who supposes fifty drachmas to be given for 507 Ubi sup. 508 Aristoph. Nub. 861. Ran. 1267. Pac. 1201. 509 Lysias Fragm. p. 15. 510 Plutarch. de vitando ære alieno 2, 3. 511 Aristoph. Nub. 31. 512 Pac. 1200. 145 it. A private key together with the ring cost in the same age three oboli, a magic ring a drachma 513. A small book for an agreement (ygaµμatídiov), i. e. a small ordinary wooden diptychon with two wax tablets, Demosthenes values at two chalcus 514. It is well known that the assize price of a rope, even if a man used it for hanging himself, was an obolus 515. Arms and armour cannot have been cheap; in the time of war when the demand was con- siderable, ten minas were, according to Aristophanes (who probably mentions the highest rate), the price of a coat of mail of good workmanship and fastened with metal chains (dλvoidwrós); one mina, as it appears, for a helmet ; and sixty drachmas for a war-trumpet 516. For determining the expences of the marine it would be particularly de- sirable to know the prices of articles employed in ship- building, but very little definite information can be gathered from the passages of ancient writers. A piece of wood for making an oar (xweùs) cost, according to Andocides 517, five drachmas; Lucian, who both from the lateness of the period at which he lived and the bent of his writings cannot be sufficient evidence, supposes the fraudulent god Mercury in a reckoning with Charon to ask five drachmas for an anchor for Charon's boat, which to the covetous ferryman appears a large sum; for the thong with which the oar was fastened on (τgоng), two oboli; for a needle Aristoph. Thesm. 432. Plut. 885. 514 Demosth. in Dionysod. p. 1283. 4. cf. Salmas. de M. U. X. p. 403. 515 Lucian. Timon. 20. 516 Aristoph. Pac. 1223. and the Schol. 1250. and 1240. 517 De suo Reditu p. 81. Reiske (Ind. Andoc.) falsely under- stood xareus to mean a rower. The next passage is Lucian. Dial. Mort. 4. VOL. I. 513 L 146 to sew together the sail cloth, five oboli; for pitching-wax, nails, and cords for the sail-yard, altogether two drachmas. The cost of a whole ship as compared with its size it is not now possible to ascertain. In a bond of bottomry in Demosthenes 518, three thousand drachmas are lent upon a merchant-vessel, by which however we are not justified in assuming that the ship had not a greater value, as at Athens a double pledge was not unfrequently given in case of bottomry, and therefore its real value might have been as much as a talent. Nor could the cost of a trireme or the common ship of war, without its furniture, have been much greater, as labour could be procured at a low rate, and ships were easily built; for which reason they did not last long, but were frequently wrecked when out at sea, and were shattered to pieces in battle. A cal- culation has been made from accounts of the expences of the trierarchy, that it cost a talent to build the hull of a trireme, but it is founded upon an erroneous supposition; another means of determining the price might have been derived from the account of Themistocles having built 100 or 200 triremes from the annual proceeds of the mines; but neither can the annual returns of the mines nor the number of years be ascertained with certainty: the state- ment of Polyænus that a ship was built for every talent which was allowed, is after all the most probable 519; but it was perhaps only a contribution granted to the trierarchs, who according to the most ancient form of the trierarchy were obliged to supply all the furniture of the vessel, and 518 In Dionysod. p. 1283. 18. 519 See my Memoir upon the Mines of Laurion. According to Diodorus (see below II. 20.) there were perhaps twenty tri- remes built every year. ་ 3 147 were only indemnified for the building of the hull. Sub- sequently however, on account of the general rise of prices, a trireme may have stood a little higher: would that instead of the fictitious sale of the triremes for fifty drach- mas, at which the Corinthians once furnished some vessels to the Athenians 520, we had a statement of their real value! (20.) From the preceding particulars, it is possible very nearly to determine the sum which was requisite for the maintenance of a respectable person in the best times of Athens. The most moderate person required every day for opson one obolus, for a choenix of corn, according to the price of barley in the age of Socrates, a quarter obolus, making altogether in a year of 360 days, 75 drachmas ; and for clothes and shoes at least 15 drachmas; a family of four adults must therefore at the lowest have required 360 drachmas for the specified necessaries; which sum for the age of Demosthenes, when the price of corn was five drachmas, must be increased by about 224 drachmas - for each person, and for four persons by about 90: to this the expence of house-room is to be added, which, if we reckon the value of a house at the lowest at three minas, taking the ordinary rate of interest of twelve per cent, gives an outlay of thirty-six drachmas; so that the poorest family of four free adults spent upon an average from 390 to 400 drachmas a year, if they did not live upon bread and water. Socrates had two wives, not indeed at the same time, as has been fabulously reported, but one after the other; the first was Myrto, whom he married poor, and probably without a dowry; the second Xan- thippe; he had three children, of whom Lamprocles at 520 Herod. VI. 89. - 148 the death of his father had reached the age of manhood, while Sophroniscus and Menexenus were minors 521; for himself, after having sacrificed his youth to unceasing endeavours after knowledge, he followed no profession, and his teaching did not produce any pecuniary return. According to Xenophon 522, he lived upon his own pro- perty, which if it had found a good purchaser (wynτns), would together with the house, have readily produced five minas; and he only required a small contribution from his friends: whence it has been inferred that prices were most extraordinarily low at Athens. It is however evident that Socrates and his family could not have lived upon the proceeds of so small a property; for, however miserable his house may have been, it cannot be estimated at less than three minas, so that even if the furniture is not taken into consideration, the rest of his effects only amounted to two minas, and the income from them ac- cording to the ordinary rate of interest to only 24 drach- mas, from which he could not have provided barley for himself and his wife, not to mention the other necessaries of life and the maintenance of his children. Shall we then understand the expression "purchaser (wyrǹs)” of a lessee of his property, and five minas as the annual rent? This way of avoiding the difficulty would be the easiest; but the ancients, as far as I am aware, only use the word " to buy (wveïσbai)” instead of “to let," as applied to the public re- venues, the letting of which was a real sale of the dues be- longing to the State; for a lease of the lands or the whole 521 Plat. Apol. 23. and there Fischer. 522 Econ. 2. According to Meursius, who has been tran- scribed by later writers, he lived upon it very respectably (per- honeste)! See Fort. Att. IV. p. 30. " 149 property (oixos) of an individual to a tenant, the expression μobov is used; and, moreover, a lease of the whole property never occurs, as far as I am aware, except in the case of the estates of orphans. In addition to this, the fortune of Cri- tobulus is valued at more than 500 minas, in the same sense as that of Socrates is at five, with the remark that it came to the same thing, as he supplied great sacrifices, enter- tained guests, feasted and maintained many citizens, kept horses, performed public liturgies, and subjected himself to other expences besides the maintenance of his wife, things which, with an income of 8 talents, he would have been undoubtedly able to afford, but not with only a property of that amount. We must therefore believe that Xenophon stated the whole property of Socrates at only five minas, but we have equal right to reject as to receive this testi- mony; for the history of the ancient philosophers is so cor- rupted and mixed with fables, and the circumstances of their lives have been so differently represented even by con- temporary writers, that one seldom treads upon firm ground. Thus in the Apology of Plato, Socrates is represented as saying that he need not have given more than a mina of silver for his release; in which account Eubulides also agreed: according to others he estimated the whole cause at 25 drachmas; and in the Apology for Socrates attributed to Xenophon, it is related that he had neither valued his law- suit himself, nor would allow it to be valued by his friends 523! Thus the well-informed Demetrius of Phalerum maintained, in opposition to Xenophon, that Socrates had, besides his house, seventy minas lent out to Criton upon interest; and Libanius relates that he had lost eighty minas, which were left him by his father, through a friend who had 523 Plat. Apol. 28. Diog. Laert. II. 41. Xenoph. Apol. 23, A 150 failed in his business, whom we can by no means suppose with Schneider to have been the wealthy Crito 524. But assuming Xenophon's account to be entirely correct, it must be thought that the mother of the young sons main- tained herself and two children either by her labour or out of her dowry, while Lamprocles supported himself, and that the domestic economy for which Socrates was so celebrated, consisted in keeping his family at work. He may in that case, indeed, have lived upon his 24 drachmas, together with some additional contributions from his friends; for his necessary expences were exceedingly small. It is true that he is related to have often sacrificed at home and upon the public altars525, but doubtless only baked animals, according to the custom of the poor, together with loaves of bread, which were mostly consumed with the meat, and to which his family also contributed; he lived in the strictest sense upon bread and water, except when he was entertained by his friends; and therefore he may have been much rejoiced, as he is said to have been, at barley being sold at the low price of a quarter obolus the choenix 526: he wore no under-garment; and his upper-garment was slight, the same for summer and winter; he generally went bare- footed, and his dress-shoes which he sometimes wore, pro- bably lasted him his whole life. A walk before his house served him instead of opson for meals; in short no slave lived so poorly as he did 527. His greatest expence was 524 Demetrius ap. Plutarch. Aristid. I. where rèv oixíar should resume its place in the text for Reiske's yuv oixɛlav; Liban. Apol. vol. III. p. 7. Schneider ad Xenoph. ubi sup. 525 Xenoph. Mem. Socrat. init. 526 See Plutarch and Stobæus in the passages quoted in chap. 15. 527 Xenoph. ut sup. I. 5. 2. Plat. Conviv. p. 174. A. Athen. 151 unquestionably the drachma which he gave to Prodicus; and without disparaging the greatness of his intellectual powers, it may be boldly asserted, that as far as his miserable condition and a certain resemblance to the habits of the Cynic philosophers are concerned, the representa- tion of Aristophanes is not only not exaggerated, but is faithfully copied after the life. If in the time of Socrates four persons could live upon 440 drachmas, they must have passed a very wretched existence, and to live respectably it was necessary even then, and still more in the time of Demosthenes, to be pos- sessed of a larger income. According to the speech against Phænippus, the plaintiff and his brother inherited from their father 45 minas, upon which the orator says it was not easy to live 528, that is upon the interest, which according to the common rate, amounts to 540 drachmas. Isæus in his speech upon the estate of Hagnias 529 relates, that Stratocles and his brother had inherited an estate from their father, which was indeed too inconsiderable to oblige them to the performance of liturgies, but sufficient for their maintenance: now since the property of Stratocles amounted at his death to five and a half talents, besides IV. p. 157. E. Many persons used to go barefooted, even the wealthy and distinguished Lycurgus (see Lives of the Ten Orators). 528 P. 1045. 17. 529 P. 292. where read εἶναι μὲν ἱκανὰ, λειτουργεῖν δὲ μὴ ἄξια, as Reiske proposed, with the addition however of another unhappy conjecture. Ovx ixavà is manifestly corrupt, in the first place because it ought to be μ, and not oỷ, and in the second, because it would be absurd to remark, that his property was indeed not sufficient to live upon, but too inconsiderable for the performance of liturgies. 152 his wife's dowry of twenty minas, which cannot be reckoned into his legacy, and since out of this sum he had acquired either by subsequent inheritance or his own exertions the sum of four talents 44 minas, his patrimony amounted to 46 minas, which according to the ordinary rate of interest afforded an income of five minas 52 drachmas a year, and at the rate of eighteen per cent at which he lent it out, eight minas 28 drachmas, and with the interest of the dowry reckoned at twelve per cent, ten minas 68 drachmas, an income which was amply sufficient to maintain him. Mantitheus, in a speech of Demosthenes 530, asserts that he had been supported and educated from the interest of his mother's dowry, which amounted to a talent, conse- quently according to the customary rate of interest, from 720 drachmas. The expences of Demosthenes himself when a youth, of his young sister and of his mother, amounted to seven minas a year, exclusively of the cost of house-rent, as they lived in their own house: but the cost of Demosthenes' education was not paid out of this sum, as it remained owing by the guardians 531. After Lysias has finished speaking of the fraudulent account rendered by the guardian of Diodotus' children (who for example had charged more than a talent for clothes, shoes, and hair-cutting within eight years, and more than 4000 drach- mas for sacrifices and festivals, and at the termination of his office would only surrender three minas of silver and 30 Cyzicenic staters) 532, he remarks533, that "if he charges more than any person in the city ever did, for two boys and D. 530 In Boot. de Dote p. 1009. 28. p. 1023. 6. 531 Demosth. in Aphob. I. p. 824, 26 sqq. p. 825. 5. 532 In Diogit. p. 903. cf. p. 897. and p. 905. 533 Ibid. p. 910. 153 a girl, a nurse and female servant, he could not reckon more than 1000 drachmas a year;" which would give not much less than three drachmas a day. This is equal to about two shillings and three pence in our money, a sum which certainly must appear too large for three children and two female slaves in the time of Lysias. In the age of Solon an obolus must have gone very far, for that legislator prohibited any woman from carrying with her upon any procession or journey more than would buy thus much of food, together with a basket which was more than an ell long 534: and the Trozenians appear to have made a liberal donation, when, according to Plutarch 535, they decreed to allow two oboli to every one of the old-men, women, and children, who had fled from Athens at the time of the invasion of Xerxes. But in the flourishing times of the State, one person could live but moderately upon two or even three oboli a day 536; upon the whole how- ever the cheapness and facility of living were considerable. From the piety of the Greeks towards the dead, the death of a man, with his funeral and monument, often cost more than many years of his life, for we find that private in- dividuals frequently spent for that purpose as much as three, ten, fifteen, or even 120 minas 537. 534 Plutarch. Solon. 21. 535 Themistocl. 10. 536 Lucian (Epist. Saturn. 21.) says, that in order to satiate one's self with maize or barley bread, together with a few cresses, some thyme, or a few onions, four oboli were wanting; which is the very sum that a miserly father gives to his son who has reached his eighteenth year, for his daily sustenance, in another place in the same author (Dial. Mort. 7.). This however cannot be applied to Athens and to ancient times. 537 Lysias in Philon. p. 884. Pseudo-Plat. Epist. XIII. p. 361. 154 The national wealth of the Athenians, exclusive of the public property and the mines 538, I have estimated in a succeeding part of this work according to a probable calculation, at from 30 to 40 thousand talents; if of this only 20,000 talents are reckoned as property paying interest, each of the 20,000 citizens would have had the interest of a talent, or according to the ordinary rate of interest, an annual income of 720 drachmas, if property had been equally divided, which the ancient philosophers and statesmen always considered as the greatest good fortune of a State; and with the addition of the produce of their labour, they might have been all able to live comfortably. But a considerable number of the citizens were poor; while others were possessed of great riches, who from the lowness of prices and the high rate of interest were able not only to live luxuriously, but at the same time to accumulate additional wealth, as capital increased with extreme rapidity. This inequality de- stroyed the State and the morals of the inhabitants. The most natural consequence of it was the servility of the poor towards the rich, although they thought that they had the same pretensions as their superiors in wealth; and the wealthy citizens practised the same canvassing for popular favour, as was the custom at Rome, with different degrees of utility, or rather of hurtfulness. A citizen might perhaps adopt beneficial means for obtaining his end, as Cimon for example, the first man of his age, who, besides his great mental qualities, imitated Pisi- stratus in leaving his lands and gardens without any 1 E. Demosth. in Boot. de Dote p. 1023. 22. Lysias in Diogit. p. 905. Demosth. in Stephan. I. p. 1124. 15. 539 IV. 4. 155 keepers, and thus the produce of his farms and his house became almost the property of the public; he used also to provide cheap entertainments for the poor, to bury the indigent, to distribute small pieces of money when he went out, and to cause his attendants to change clothes with decayed citizens 539. Yet these were the very means by which the sovereign citizens were reduced to a miserable state of beggary and dependance. Even this however might have been tolerable; but as every statesman had not the means of making such large outlays from his private fortune, and liberality to the people being necessary to purchase their favour, the distribution of money at the festivals, the payment of the soldiers, the Ecclesiasts, Dicasts, and senators, the costly sacrifices, and the Cleru- chiæ, were introduced by the demagogues: the allies were compelled to try their causes at Athens, among other reasons for producing more fees to the Dicasts, and em- ployment for the other citizens 540: of every oppressive act committed against the allies, public crimes were the con- sequence, which the demagogues pretended that they were driven to by the poverty of the people 541. And when the necessary consequence and punishment of their tyranny arrived in the defection of the allies, the helpless condition of the State had increased; for the multitude had forgotten their former activity, and been gradually accustomed to ease and refinement; no course therefore remained but to struggle to regain their former ascendancy. Add to this the envy which the poor entertained against the rich, and 559 Theopomp. ap. Athen. XII. p. 533. A. Plutarch. Cimon. 10. partly from Aristotle, and Pericl. 9. 540 Xenoph. de Rep. Athen. 541 Xenoph. de Vectig. init. 156 the joy and readiness with which they divided their pos- sessions, upon which, after bribery had been tried in vain, the whole rage of the multitude vented itself. Xenophon, in his treatise upon the Revenues, understood perfectly that it was necessary to promote the welfare of individuals: but, leaving out of the question the insufficiency of his proposals, Athens, even if her power in foreign parts could have been restored, was lost beyond all hope of recovery, as the minds of her citizens could not be so easily recalled to a state consistent with her desired prosperity. (21.) From the extreme cheapness of the necessaries of life, the wages of labour must have been at a low rate in ancient times; and the number of competitors in the market for labour, among whom, besides the Thetes and the resident aliens, a large portion of slaves should be reckoned, must have contributed to produce a farther diminution 542. In addition to the effect of competition, the gangs of slaves maintained by the wealthy essentially injured the profits of the poorer classes of citizens. And it was with justice that the Phocians, who are said to have subsequently prohibited the keeping of slaves, upbraided Mnason, who possessed more than a thousand, with keeping an equal number of citizens out of employment 543. After the Peloponnesian war, even citizens who had been accus- tomed to live in a better condition of life-the struggle which it produced had been so great-maintained them- selves by working for daily wages at any manual labour, as they had lost their foreign estates, rents had fallen as well from the scarcity of money, as from the decrease of the population, and loans were not to be procured 544. I 542 Cf. Xenoph. de Vectig. 4. 543 Athen. VI. p. 264. C. cf. p. 272. B. 544 Xenoph. Mem. Socrat. II. 7, 8. 157 have been able to find but few exact statements of the amount of wages of labour: Lucian states that in the age of Timon (provided he does not refer to earlier what really belongs to later times) four oboli were the daily wages for garden or field-labour upon a distant estate 545; this same sum occurs as a porter's wages in Aristophanes, and of a common labourer who carried manure 546. When Ptolemy sent 100 masons and 350 labourers to the Rho- dians, in order to repair the damage caused by the earth- quake, he gave them fourteen talents a year for opson, that is, three oboli apiece 547; which, if they were slaves, was the expence of their maintenance, if free labourers, only a part of their wages, as a man required other things besides opson. The philosophers Menedemus and Asclepiades must have been powerful labourers in their youth, if they earned two drachmas a night for grinding in a corn-mill 548. Particular services, which require a certain degree of com- pliance on the part of the labourers, received a higher recompense at Athens, as in all other great cities. Bacchus, in the Frogs of Aristophanes 549, wishes to have his bundle carried by a porter, who asks two drachmas for his trouble; but when the god offers the departed shade nine oboli, he declares that "rather than do this he would re- turn to life again." If this dialogue in the region of shades is not a scene of real life, it has no point: a living porter at Athens was perhaps equally exorbitant in his de- mands, and if less was offered him, he might naturally answer that he would sooner die than do it. The fare 545 Lucian. Timon. 6. 12. 546 Aristoph. ap. Poll. VII. 133. and Eccles. 310. 547 Polyb. V. 88. 548 Phanodemus and Philochorus ap. Athen. IV. p. 168. A.- 549 Vs. 172 sqq. 158 paid for passages by sea was extremely moderate, parti- cularly for long voyages; it cost two oboli to go from Ægina to the Piraeus; that is, for more than twenty-one miles; the fare from Egypt or the Pontus to the same port, more than 600 miles, for a man with his family and baggage, was at most two drachmas in the age of Plato; a proof that commerce was very profitable, so that it was not found necessary to require much from passengers. In the time of Lucian the fare from Athens to Ægina was four oboli 550. The freight of timber appears to have been more considerable in a case mentioned by Demosthenes 551, in which 1750 drachmas were paid for a cargo from Macedonia to Athens: the immense corn vessel the Isis, which, in the time of the emperors, brought so much corn from Egypt to Italy, that it was asserted that one cargo would be sufficient for a year's consumption of all Attica, produced at the least twelve talents of freightage per annum 552. The fulling of an upper garment cost three oboli 553. Thirty drachmas were paid for engraving a decree of moderate size, if we may judge from the fragment that remains; 50 drachmas were assigned for engraving all the decrees of Lycurgus in the Archonship of Anaxicrates (Olymp. 118. 2.) 554, which can only be explained by sup- posing that the writing was for the most part very small. 550 Plat. Gorg. §. 143. ed. Heindorf. Lucian. vol. III. p. 258. ed. Reiz. 551 In Timoth. p. 1192. That only one cargo is meant is evident from the mention of only one captain, ibid. 1. 24. 552 Lucian. ut sup. p. 256. 555 Aristoph. Vesp. 1123. cf. 1122. 554 Marm. Oxon. XXIV. ed. Chandl. and in some unpublished inscriptions; third decree at the end of the Lives of the Ten Orators. 159 The great inscription which was first published by Bar- thelemy 555, is only 3′ 8″ 4″ Paris measure high, 6″ 6″″ thick, the upper part, which contains an image in high relief, is 1' 11", the lower part upon which the writing is engraved, 2′ 4″ 6″ wide. The whole inscription consists of only forty rows of letters, which are 34 lines high, with spaces between the rows of two lines in height; so that the whole height of the inscription itself is 1' 6" 4". In addi- tion to this we may notice the payments at the baths, which, according to Lucian, amounted to two oboli, although they cannot be considered solely as the wages of labour 556. For the labour of plucking out the hair with pitch, in order to make the skin resemble that of a woman, a person is represented in Philemon as paying four men six chalcûs apiece, as it appears from a passage in Pollux 557. It may be also observed the rich had private, and the people of Athens public baths 558, The pay of the soldiers was different according to times and circumstances, and varied between two oboli, and two drachmas, the latter including the provision- money for an Hoplites and his attendant; the cavalry received from two to four times, officers generally twice, and generals only four times that amount: the provision- money was usually equal to the pay. A soldier could maintain himself sufficiently well for two or three oboli, especially as in many places living was much cheaper than at Athens; out of his pay he was to provide clothes and arms, after which a certain overplus remained, which, with 555 The Choiseul inscription. 556 Lexiphanes 2. 557 IX. 66. and there Hemsterhuis. Xenoph. de Rep. Ath. 2. 10. see Barthél. Anach. tom. II. chap. 20. 160 the addition of plunder, might enable him to amass a decent fortune. This explains the meaning of the comic poet Theopompus 559, who says, that with a pay of two oboli a soldier could maintain a wife, and with four oboli his fortune was complete; where he means the pay alone with- out the provision. The pay of the Dicasts and Ecclesiasts amounted in its increased state to three oboli, and like the Theorica, only served as a contribution to the support of the citizens: the Heliast in the Wasps of Aristophanes 560 clearly shews the difficulty which there was in procuring bread, opson, and wood for three persons out of this allowance: clothes and house-room he does not reckon, as these he provided from his private property. The salaries of the senators and ambassadors were more considerable; the liberal arts and sciences were the most abundantly paid, although the rewards of those who administered to unlawful pleasure were scarcely inferior. The ancient states maintained physicians who were paid at the public cost 561; thus, for example, Hippocrates is said to have been public physician at Athens: these again had attend- ants, for the most part slaves, who exercised their calling among people of low condition 562. The celebrated phy- sician Democedes of Croto received about the sixtieth 559 Ap. Poll. IX. 64. where read with Kühn, καίτοι τίς οὐκ ἂν εἰκὸς εὖ πράττοι τετρωβολίζων, εἰ νῦν γε διώβολον φέρων ἀνὴς τρέφει γυναῖκα. S [Porson Præf. Hec. p. 43. διώβολον φέρει τρέφειν γυναῖκα. νῦν γ᾽ ἀνὴρ διώβολον φέρων τρέφει γυναῖκα.] 560 Vesp. 299. cf. 699. 561 Xenoph. Mem. Socrat. IV. 2. 5. Plat. Gorg. §. 23. Con- cerning the pay see Strab. IV. p. 125. Diod. XII. 13. 562 Plat. Leg. writes the last line, si vovy ave The correct reading probably is, εἰ P 161 Olympiad, notwithstanding the small quantity of money then in circulation, the large salary of thirty-six Æginetan minas or of one Attic talent of silver: being invited to Athens, he received a hundred minas, until Polycrates of Samos gave him two talents 563. It cannot be doubted that many artists of a different description were paid in a similar manner by the State, such as the head-architect at Rhodes and Cyzicus, and doubtless at every place of im- portance. The pay of musicians and actors was very considerable. Amoebeus, a singer in ancient Athens, re- ceived an Attic talent for each time that he appeared 564; it is well known that the flute-players were very highly paid. In a Corcyræan inscription 565 of no great antiquity, 50 Corinthian or 83 Attic minas, are fixed as the pay for three auletæ, three tragic, and three comic actors for a festivity, besides the large expences of their maintenance. Distinguished actors were not less highly paid, although they made considerable gains by travelling from place to place, when they were not employed at Athens 566; thus, for example, Polus or Aristodemus is said to have gained a talent in two days, or even in one 567. In like manner common strolling players, jugglers, conjurors, fortune- 563 Herod. III. 131. 561 Aristeas ap. Athen. XV. p. 623. D. 565 Inscript. 150. tom. I. p. 231. ed. Boeckh. 566 Cf. Demosth. de fals. Leg. and the second argument to this oration. 567 Vit. X. Orat. p. 268. ed. Tübing. Gell. XI. 9. 10. Con- cerning the pay of the common actors at Rome, see Lipsius Exc. N. ad Tacit. Annal. I. It is difficult to believe that Demo- sthenes gave 10,000 drachmas to the actor Neoptolemus for teaching him to speak with long breath, as is stated in the Lives of the Ten Orators, p. 260. VOL. I. M 162 tellers, &c. gained a competence by their callings, although the sum which one person paid was inconsiderable, for ex- ample, a chalcûs, an obolus, or sometimes a drachma 568; apprentices' fees for instruction in trades and arts, including even that of medicine, had been introduced in the time of Socrates 569. The tribes at Athens were bound to provide for a part of the instruction in music and gymnastic exercises, and they had their own teachers, by whom the youth of the whole tribe were instructed 570; in the other schools each person paid, but how much we are not in- formed 571: an exception was made to this rule by some enactments of Charondas, who is said to have appointed salaries for the grammarians, if the laws, from which Diodorus 572 took his account, are not fabrications. The teachers of philosophy and rhetoric, or the sophists, were not paid by the State till later times; at first however they obtained large sums from their scholars, the worthy suc- cessors of the mercenary lyric poets, whose inspiration was frequently the result of gold 573. Protagoras of Abdera is 568 Casaub. ad Theophrast. Char. 6. Lucian gives a good deal of information with regard to the fortune-tellers: the most remarkable instance of growing rich by this art occurs in Isocrat. Æginet. 569 Plat. Menon. p. 90. B. sqq. 570 Demosth. in Boot. de Nom. p. 1001. 19. 571 Demosth. in Aphob. I. p. 828. 572 Diod. XII. 13. Although their spuriousness has been proved, yet every thing that occurs in them cannot be rejected as forged: the latter law however gives strong grounds for suspect- ing that it is later than the Alexandrian age. 573 Many persons have treated of the pay of learned men. The most important particulars have been collected by Wolf (Ver- mischte Schriften p. 42 sqq.) without any parade of quotations. 163 said to have been the first who taught for money; and he received from his pupils a hundred minas for their com- plete education 574: Gorgias 575 required the same sum, notwithstanding which he only left at his death a thousand staters 576: together with Zeno of Elea 577, who was other- wise unlike the sophists. Instruction being obtained at so high a price, it is natural that competition should have arisen, and endeavours to agree for moderate terms; at which we who carry on the same trade with books, as they with their oral instruction, should be the last to be astonished. Hippias, while still a young man, together with Protagoras, earned in Sicily in a very short space of time a hundred and fifty minas, of which more than twenty minas came from one small town; and not as it appears by any long course of education 578. By degrees however the number of teachers brought about a reduction of the price: Euenus of Paros, as early as in the time of Socrates, exposed himself to the ridicule of the multitude by taking only ten minas 579, for which sum also Isocrates taught the whole art of rhetoric 580; 574 Quintil. Inst. Orat. III. 1. Gell. V. 10. Diog. IX. 52. and there Menage. 575 Suidas, and Diod. XII. 53. 576 Isocrat. de Antidosi p. 84. ed. Orell. 577 Plat. Alcib. I. p. 119. A. The Scholiast of Aristophanes (Nub. 873.) states that the teachers would not have readily taken less than a talent: if any reliance is to be placed on this account, which is hardly necessary, it must be referred to the time of Socrates alone. 578 Plat. Hipp. §. 5. For farther information concerning Hip- pias, see Suidas, Philostr. Vit. Soph. I. 1. 11. Apulej. Florid. p. 346. ed. Elm. 579 Plat. Apol. Socrat. p. 20. B. 580 Demosth. in Lacrit. p. 938. 17. Plutarch. in Vit. Demosth. and Vit. X. Orat. in Vit. Isocrat. 164 and this in the time of Lycurgus was considered as the common remuneration of a teacher of eloquence 581. At last even the followers of Socrates were content to teach for money, Aristippus having, as it is said, been the first to set the example 582. It may be also mentioned, that they used to receive money from each pupil for private lectures; thus Prodicus, for example, received from one, two, and four, to fifty drachmas 583. Antiphon was the first person who wrote speeches for money, and he was paid highly for them 584. I am almost ashamed to speak of the prices of intercourse with persons of both sexes, which, according to Suidas and Zonaras 585, were fixed by law: three chalcûs, one and two oboli, a drachma 586; a stater with women of middling condition 587, but the price of a Lais was 10,000 drachmas for a night 588. Other prices may be seen in Lysias 589, and the author of the epistles of Eschines 590, (22.) The rate of interest in Greece was expressed either by the number of oboli or drachmas which were 581 Vit. Dec. Orat. in Vit. Lycurg. 582 Diog. 11. 65. and there Menage, cf. 72, 74. He is said to have taken from 1500 to 100 drachmas, although others refer these accounts to Isocrates. 583 Plat. Cratyl. init. Aristot. Rhet. III. 14. Philost. ut sup. 12. Schol. Aristoph. Nub. 360. Suidas in v. Igodixov, Eudoc. Πρόδικον, p. 365. Ion. 584 Van Spaan (Ruhnken) de Antiph. p. 809. tom. VII. of Reiske's Orators. 585 In v. διάγραμμα. 586 Hesych. in v. Telavтoróg, Athen. VI. p. 241. E. Aristoph. Thesm. 1207. The diobolares are well known. 587 Theopompus the Comic poet ap. Poll. IX. 59. 588 Sotion ap. Gell. I. 8. 8. 589 In Simon. pp. 147, 148. 390 Pseud-Eschin. Epist. 7. 165 paid by the month for each mina that was borrowed, or by the part of the principal that was paid as interest either annually, or for the whole time of the loan. According to the first method of speaking, interest of ten per cent per annum, is called at five oboli (πì névte ỏßoroïs), of twelve per cent at a drachma (ì dgax), of sixteen per cent at eight oboli (π' ỏxtw ỏßoλoïs), of eighteen per cent at nine oboli (éπ' évvéa ¿ßoλoïs), and of 24 or 36 per cent at two or three drachmas (ἐπὶ δυσὶ, τρισὶ δραχμαῖς): according to the other method, the rates of the third, fifth, sixth, eighth, and tenth parts of the principal, either annually or for any specified term, are 33, 20, 163, 121, and ten per cent (τόκοι ἐπίτριτοι, ἐπίπεμτοι, ἔφεκτοι, ἐπόγδοοι, ἐπιδέκατοι) 591. Passages in the ancient writers leave no room for doubt that the expressions above-cited have the sense assigned to theaf; and in the first method of expression, the specified number of oboli and drachmas, was the amount of interest to be paid by the month, and in the other the portion of the principal was interest to be paid either annually, or in cases of bottomry for the time of the ship's passage spe- cified in the agreement: some earlier writers however, whom Salmasius has already refuted with too great minute- ness, have maintained the absurd notion, that the tenth, eighth, sixth, fifth, and third parts of the loan were interest to be paid monthly, or in agreements of bottomry even daily; nor can we feel otherwise than astonished to find Bar- 591 The words ixitgitos, iπITÉTagtos, &c. in the mathematical and musical writings of the ancients, signify 14, 14, &c. as the beginner may learn from my Memoir über die Bildung der Weltseele im Timäos des Platon, Studien 1817. part I. p. 50. that in the reckoning of interest they mean, &c. has been already remarked by Salmasius de M. U. I. cf. Schneider ad Xenoph. de Vectig. p. 183. 166 thélemy 592, in contradiction to Petit, considering sixteen per cent as monthly interest. The main source of this error lies in the supposition, that all interest was paid by the month, which without doubt was frequently the case 593: but not only is it impossible that in bonds of bottomry, the interest could have been paid monthly, as the borrower was neither able nor obliged to pay it until after his return; but even in debts of mortgage, the annual pay- ment of interest was not uncommon 594: nor if in ancient Greece, at all times, and in all places, interest had been paid by the month, would it follow from the names of the interest of the third, fifth, sixth, and eighth parts, that those portions of the principal were paid monthly, any more than at present, when it is paid quarterly or half yearly, it follows from the expression that a sum of money is lent at five per cent, that five per cent is to be paid every quarter or half year. We may also remark, omitting the agreements of bottomry, which did not exactly run a year, that the interest of the tenth part (τóxoi éπidéxaтo) is the same as the interest of five oboli, of the eighth part (124 per cent) nearly the same as the interest of one drachma (12 per cent), of the sixth part (163 per cent) nearly the same as the rate at eight oboli (16 per cent), of the fifth part (20 per cent) nearly the same as the rate at nine oboli 592 Anachars. tom. IV. p. 372. 593 Aristoph. Nub. init. and 751 sqq. 594 Demosth. in Polycl. p. 1225. 15. Inscript. ap. Montfaucon Diar. Ital. p. 412. Even when the rate of interest was fixed by the month, it might be paid by the year, as is evident from the above-quoted inscription. In the Orchomenian Inscription (Rose p. 263.) the rate of interest is also fixed by the month, but it did not necessarily follow that the money should therefore be paid every month. 167 (18 per cent), and of the third part (334) as the rate of three drachmas (36 per cent): but the examples which will be presently quoted prove that they are not therefore to be taken as identical; and each expression must be under- stood precisely in its strict meaning as it stands, since the lenders would never have made use of indefinite expres- sions. It was not until the age of Justinian that the Centesima, which is exactly equal to the interest at a drachma, was identified with the interest of the eighth part (τóxos éπóydoos) or 123 per cent, as Salmasius correctly remarks; although he himself, in speaking of more ancient times, does not always accurately distinguish between the rates of interest which I have mentioned as only slightly differing. From the preceding investigation into the method of expressing the rate of interest, it follows that in Greece interest was not so low as in modern States, and at Rome in the age of Cicero: the lowest rate at Athens appears. to have been ten per cent, the highest thirty-six per cent; the latter is not exceeded by any examples of interest received upon bottomry, although these were in fact higher than they appear, since the time of a ship's voyage for which the money was generally lent, was shorter than a year. I can find no authority for the statement of Casaubon 595, that they sometimes obtained an interest of four drachmas a month, although usurers took without reserve as much as they could extort. Interest equal to half the principal (μiódios tóxos), first occurs a considerable time after the Christian era in a case of a loan of products of the soil to be repaid in kind 596. The cause of the high rate of 595 Ad Theophrast. Char. 6. 596 Salmas. de M. U. VIII. 168 interest can only be that it was then more difficult than now to procure a loan of money, or what is equivalent, that there was a greater demand for money to be borrowed, and a smaller quantity to be lent. But that in general, this circumstance was not owing to the insufficient quantity of money in circulation, appears to be evident from this, that in the case of the metallic circulation being too contracted, the demand for money would necessarily be diminished, on account of the fall in the prices of other commodities, and also from the fact, that landed estates bore a rent equal to eight per cent of their value, and even more than twelve per cent for the lease of the whole property 597; so that the rate of interest does not appear to depend upon the quantity of money in circulation, but to have a com- mon origin with rent. The chief reasons therefore why money was not willingly lent out at a low interest, appear to be, that any person who wished to carry on business with it himself, might obtain a high profit by employing it in commerce or manufactures 598, in the same way that any one who managed his own property himself, on account of the smaller expence of slave-labour, would necessarily have made a greater net profit than at the present time under a different combination of circumstances. Add to this that credit was at a low ebb, which was occasioned by the want of moral principles, and the imperfection of the civil con- stitutions and jurisdiction of the different States, and especially by the difficulty of obtaining restitution for injuries in a foreign country. Even the legislation of Solon, by which the rights of individuals were more accurately defined, struck at the root of the security of the 597 See below chap. 24. 598 See above chap. 9. 169 creditor, by taking away his right over the body of the debtor; and it was shewn by the measure called the Seisach- theia, how little respect the State had for the security of property, whether by this ordinanve merely the value of the currency was depreciated, or the rate of interest also was diminished, or whether, in certain cases at least, a complete annihilation of all claims of debt was effected by it 599; nor was the severity of the laws upon debt sufficient to produce any great security in the lending of money, as the administration of them was entrusted to ill-regulated courts of justice, and the fraudulent debtor had at his command every species of subterfuge and dishonest con- trivance against the creditor. The business of the bank- ers 600 might lastly have contributed to raise the rate of interest, as these usurers took money at a moderate premium from persons who would not occupy themselves with the management of their own property 601, in order to lend it with profit to others, and thus to a certain de- gree obtained possession of a monopoly. Trading with borrowed money composed the chief part of the business of the bankers 602, although they sometimes employed capital of their own in that manner; the exchange of money at an agio 603 was by no means their exclusive employment. Although they were generally of a low mg 599 See Plut. Solon. 14. 600 Concerning which see particularly Salmasius de Fenore Trapezitico and de Usuris, and the acute Heraldus, Animadv. in Salmas. Obs. II. 24, 25. 601 Thus e. g. Demosthenes' father kept a part of his capital in the hands of bankers, Dem. in Aphob. I. p. 816. 602 Demosth. pro Phorm. p. 948. sup. 603 Isocrat. Trapez. 21. Demosth. de fals. Leg. p. 376. 2. in Polycl. p. 1216. 18. Poll. III. 84. VII. 170. 170 w origin, freedmen, aliens, or persons who had been admitted as citizens, they aimed less at connecting themselves with good families, than at pecuniary gain 604; but they became possessed of great credit, which existed among the prin- cipal houses through the whole of Greece, and were thus effectively supported in their business 605; they even maintained such a reputation, that not only were they considered as secure merely by virtue of their calling, but such confidence was placed in them, that business was transacted with them without witnesses 606, and as is now done in courts of justice, money and contracts of debt were deposited with them, and agreements were concluded or cancelled in their presence 607. The importance of their business is shewn by the great wealth of Pasion, whose bank annually produced a net profit of a hundred minas 608; there are however instances of their failing and losing every thing 609. It is scarcely necessary to shew that they took a high rate of interest; their loans on the de- posit of goods are without other testimony sufficient to prove it 610. The Athenian bankers obtained thirty-six per cent, a rate which hardly occurs among honest people, except in the case of bottomry. The common usurers (ToxoyλÚÇOI, toculliones, pegodaveirai), who made a profit of the neces- sities of the poor or the extravagance of the young, de- manded, according to the faithful description of Theo- 604 Demosth. pro Phorm. p. 953. 605 Cf. Demosth. pro Phorm. p. 958. sup. in Polycl. p. 1224. 3. 606 Isocrat. Trapezit. 2. 607 Demosth. in Callip. p. 1243. 8. in Dionysod. p. 1287. 20. 608 Demosth. pro Phorm. p. 946. 25. 609 Dem. pro Phorm. p. 959. in Stephan. J. p. 1120. 20 sqq. Ulpian ad Demosth. in Timocrat. 610 Demosth. in Nicostrat. p. 1249. 10. 171 phrastus 611, as much as an obolus and a half a day for each drachma; and the practice which was prevalent in the times of Plutarch, of immediately subtracting the interest from the sum borrowed, and again lending it out upon interest 612, had probably arisen in the flourishing times of Athens. On account of this high rate of interest, and the severity with which they enforced the payment of it, frequently seizing the houses and property of their debtors, and as lenity was foreign to their character or indeed any other consideration but that of their own gain, the bankers, and money-lenders, like the Jews in modern times, drew upon themselves the merited hatred of all, as being the most infamous of human beings 613. Money was lent without interest from motives of friend- ship or kindness, even without a written bond and any security or pledge, either with or without witnesses (χειρόδοτον, ἀσύγγραφον) 614; sometimes with an acknow- ledgment (xegóvgapov), which was usually written upon papyrus; or with a formal and solemn instrument (σvy- ygaon), which was written by a third person in a diptychon of waxen tablets, signed by witnesses, and given in charge to a banker 615. The security was either made over to the creditor or not; in the latter case it was security in a more 611 Char. 6. and there Casaubon; cf. Herald. Anim. in Salmas. Obs. ad I. A. et R. II. 21. 612 Plutarch. de vitando ære alieno 4. 613 Demosth. in Stephan. I. p. 1122. extr. and p. 1123. sup. in Pantæn. pp. 981, 982. Antiphanes the Comic poet in the Mironovngos ap. Athen. VI. p. 226. E. cf. Herald. ut sup. II. 24. 1, 2. 614 Demosth. in Timoth. p. 1185. 12. Salmas. de M. U. X, p. 381. 615 Salmas. ibid. 172 limited sense, in the former it was the pledge (véxugov) 616: the security in the more confined signification was generally of immoveable property, but sometimes of moveables, for in- stance, slaves, and especially in cases of bottomry, the goods, the ship, and the outstanding freightage-money; although the pledges were generally of moveable property, we sometimes find that immoveables, such as houses and lands, were given in pledge, and indeed, on account of their safety, were common for dowries and leases of orphans' property. To lend upon a person's own body (davelleiv éπì cúμari) was prohibited in Athens from the time of Solon 617, in imita- tion, as Diodorus supposes, of the Egyptian law; in other States this cruel and barbarous custom remained in force, although it was not allowed to take even agricultural imple- ments in pawn 618. Arms could neither be taken or given in pawn at Athens 619. There were also public books of debts in Greece, like the German registers of mortgages; but they are not mentioned as having existed at Athens. On the contrary, mortgaged lands were distinguished by stone tablets or pillars, upon which the debt and the creditor's name were inscribed (go) 620: a custom of extreme 616 Salmas. ut sup. XI. 617 Diog. Laërt. and Plutarch in the Life of Solon, also the latter in his Essay de vitando ære alieno 4. 618 Salmas. ut sup. XVII. p. 749. 619 Petit Leg. Att. VIII. 1. 6. • See Boeckh Inscript. T. I. p. 250. No. 157. 255 See the passages in my Preface to the Catalogue of the Lectures in the University of Berlin, Summer, 1816. p. 4. 256 Olynth. p. 37. 6. These were presents from the public coffers. Those referred to in the second Prytaneia of the Choiseul Inscription are quite different. 257 Book I. 14. 258 Lysias in Nicomach. p. 856-860. which passage has not been entirely understood by the Commentators. 259 Decret. ap. Demosth. de Coron. p. 266. 23. Lives of the 284 although it was for the most part well filled, it did not satisfy the people. Besides the sacrifices furnished by the State (dnμoteλn isga), there were many others provided by particular corporations and societies, such, for instance, as those furnished by the boroughs (onμorina iegà) and by the companies of the Orgeones (ogywvxa) 260; not to mention the feasting of the tribes, of which I will speak in a subsequent part of this work. The entertainments at the festivals were either musical or gymnastic, both being attended with considerable expence. The choruses, both in and out of the plays, their teaching, maintenance, and dresses, the cost of the musicians and actors, together with the decorations, machinery, and dresses, and in the gym- nastic games, the maintenance of the combatants of all Ten Orators p. 263. singular expression) 260 Lex. Seg. p. 240. Hesychius and Harpocration in v. dno- TEλй iɛgά. Some of these expressions occurred in the Laws of Solon, as e. g. the dnporεañ iɛgá. See Esch. in Timarch. p. 47. p. 176. in Ctesiph. p. 566. These words also occur in the speech against Neæra (p. 1374. 2. p. 1374. 4.) in the Formula εἰσιέναι εἰς τὰ δημοτελῆ ἱερὰ, which induced Reiske, in the Index to Demosthenes, and Buttmann ad Mid. p. 125. to think that the temple was meant: but sioivas is rà iɛgà evidently refers in particular to the admission to the sacrifices, although it also includes permission to enter the temples in which the sacrifices were held. To these passages all the interpretations of the grammarians refer, and perhaps to the words of the Dodonaan oracle excellently emended by Buttmann ad Demosth. in Mid. p. 531. 24. Buttmann also quotes from Pollux the dnμoreλes έogras, from which these sacrifices were bought. Thyatir. Inscript. in Spon's Travels vol. III. part 1. p. 110. ràs duoredeïs Ovolas nai ἑορτὰς ἀφθόνως καὶ ἀνυπερκρίτως ἐπιτελέσαντα. Thucydides (II. 15.) has logràv dnμortan, Dio Cassius (XLIII. 25.) and Herodotus (VI. 57.) θυσίην δημοτελῆ. where the words dzidane dè xai Dewgois (a vgías refer to this circumstance. 285 kinds, and the preparation of every thing which belonged to their exercises and contests, required a considerable outlay of money: and although this was in part provided by direct Liturgies, the Choregia and Gymnasiarchy, it all came at last from the same source; and it makes no essen- tial difference whether the State raised the money and gave entertainments for it, or whether private individuals pro- vided the games instead of paying the money in the shape of a tax. To these must be added the prizes awarded to the successful competitor, of which some had no great value, while others were costly, and were given either in money (in the άyæves ágyugîtai), crowns, or tripods, which either the State or whoever defrayed the costs of the festival provided, or the conqueror himself furnished at his own expence 261. There occurs in an inscription 262 a golden crown of victory weighing 85 drachmas, which must at the least have cost 1000 or 1200 drachmas of silver. At the games of Neptune in the Piraeus, the first Cyclic chorus that gained the victory, received, according to a regulation of Lycurgus, at the lowest a reward of ten minas, the second eight, and the third six 263; and, even before the time of Solon, it was customary to grant to the Athenians who gained the prize in foreign sacred games (i. e. in the four great contests) rewards of a certain sum of money, which for that age were not inconsiderable, to the conqueror at the Olympic contests 500 drachmas, at the Isthmian 100, and to the others in proportion 264. Lastly, something may be said upon the splendour of the 261 Lysias pro Aristoph. bonis, and Inscript. 158. §. 5. 262 No. 150. §. 15. 263 Lives of the Teu Orators p. 252. 264 Petit Leg. Att. I. 1. 29, 30. 286 Athenian Пoμal or sacred processions. These indeed yielded in nothing to the theatrical representations: no expence was spared for them, and even the cavalry was partly maintained in time of peace for their sake. Another expence connected with this subject were the public burials (inμórias Tapai), which indeed only occurred in time of war. Again, the greater and less Theorias or sacred embassies were of frequent occurrence, which were sent, after each of the four great Grecian games, to Delos and to other sacred places for the purposes of festivals, and united in themselves sacrifices and processions. One part of the expence was borne by the Architheorus as a Liturgy, another part by the State: thus the Delphian Theori, according to an ancient law, received money for their journey and all their other expences; and thus Aristo- phanes mentions the wages of a Theorus to Paros of so small an amount as two oboli 265; thus also the Delian Architheorus received a talent from the public purse 266. The Theori were obliged to appear with a splendour and dignity suitable to the character of their nation; they themselves, wearing splendid crowns, drove into the city upon crowned chariots, which were often expensively painted, gilt, and hung with carpets 267. When Nicias 265. Concerning the former see Androtion ap. Schol. Aristoph. Av. 1545. (comp. above book II. 6.); concerning the latter see Aristoph. Vesp. 1183. where neither the entrance-money into the theatre, nor the pay of the soldiers, can be meant, as the Scholiast thinks. The first does not at all suit the context; in the latter case a soldier may have been called in joke a Theorus, which is very improbable. 266 Inscript. 158. §. 5. 267 Hesych. in v. Bewgixòs and his Commentators, and Plutarch. Nic. 3. 287 went as Architheorus to Delos, he built a bridge from Rhenea to Delos, for his entry, four stadii in length 268. The passage of the Theori and Choruses from Athens to Delos cost on a later occasion 7000 drachmas 269, and the quadriennial Delian festival, which was celebrated entirely at the expence of this Theoria, cost, according to the accounts now extant, inclusively of this latter expence, but with the exclusion of many other items which have been lost, 4 talents 43 drachmas, although they were not paid out of the funds of the State, but from those of the temple of Delos. From all that has been said, it is easy to conceive that the State expended much money upon the celebration of festivals; and at times it even became necessary to resort to the public treasure for money to defray those expences. Thus in Olymp. 92. 3. five talents and a thousand drachmas were paid out of the treasure for the Athlothetæ, at the celebration of the great Panathenæa, and 5114 drachmas to the sacrificers for hecatombs, and an Olympiad earlier the Athlothetæ received at the same festival 255 Cyzicenic staters (7140 drachmas) 270. A large part of the other payments in Olymp. 92. 3. appear, according to an account of the money disbursed from the public treasure, of which the destination is not specified, to have been also for festivals 271. For the administration and superintendence of all reli- 268 Plutarch. ut sup. 269 Inscript. 158. §. 5. 270 Inscript. 147. 2d Prytan. Inscript. 144. Pryt. 3. Item 3. 271 Barthélemy Mém. de l'Acad. des Inscriptions tom. XLVIII. p. 378. calculates the money supplied out of the public treasure for the festivals, as given in the Choiseul Inscription, upon perfectly false suppositions; for which reason I have made no use of his computation. See Taylor ad Marm. Sandw. p. 18. 288 gious solemnities certain unpaid authorities were appointed, who ranked among the principal public officers. Of this description are the Managers of the Mysteries and of the Dionysia (ἐπιμεληταὶ τῶν μυστηρίων, τῶν Διονυσίων): to parti- cular Archons certain sacrifices also belonged 272, as well as to the Generals 273, together with the Collectors of the People (σuλλoyeïç тoũ dýμov) 274, and all sacred rites at Delos were managed by the Amphictyons; but the most numerous officers were the yearly and monthly Sacrificers, the former of whom were ten in number; and again there were Sacri- ficers for the Revered Goddesses or the Eumenides (iegoTool κατ᾽ ἐνιαυτὸν, ἐπιμήνιοι, ἱεροποιοὶ ταῖς σεμναῖς θεαῖς) 275. For the games there were Athlothetæ, who had the particular care of the great Panathenæa (though probably with the exception 272 Sigon. R. A. IV. 7. 273 Inscript. 157. §. 2, 3. 274 Inscript. 157. §. 2. 275 Hesychius in v. isgorool, and his Commentators, who quote Photius and other grammarians, Poll. VIII. 107. and his Commentators, Lex. Seg. p. 265. they also occur particularly often in Inscript. 157. I. p. 250. See also Barthélemy ut sup. p. 342. The iɛgoπoloi tãv oeµväv beãy, quoted by Photius, are taken from Demosth. in Mid. p. 552. 6. Whether they, as Creuzer represents them (Symbolik vol. IV. p. 518.), were properly priests for sacrifices might appear uncertain, if Demosthenes did not shew that they at least performed the commencement of the sacrifice, or the immolation of the victim (rò xarágkαobαi tãv iegŵv). The grammarians also consider the gorrotol as having actually performed the sacrifice. Aristotle Polit. VI. 8. expresses himself too generally to allow a safe conclusion to be drawn. That they had however certain duties of administration to perform is evident from the Choiseul Inscription and from Inscript. 158. That the oɛuvai Oɛai are the Eumenides is remarked by Ulpian, Photius, and Harpocration, in v. σeµval beat, and Lex. Seg. p. 303. 289 of the sacrifices) 276, as also the Agonothetæ, &c. Lastly, the Boval, or Purchasers of Oxen, were considered among the highest officers; Demosthenes ranks them with the Sacrificers, and Libanius with the Sitona, Generals, and Ambassadors: they were elected by the Public Assembly, and provided the cattle and animals which were slaugh- tered at the sacrifices and feasts 277: a proof how important to the people these institutions were, which suited equally their appetite and their principles of religion, and by which we are forcibly reminded of the Roast Beef of Old England. (13.) The public donations, or distributions among the people (diavopai, diadóσeis), were of frequent occurrence. To these belong the distributions of corn, which have been mentioned before 278, the Cleruchiæ, and the revenues from the mines, which before the time of Themistocles were divided among the citizens; and, lastly, the money of the Theorica, for the introduction of which Pericles is charge- able. For this statesman, finding himself unable by reason of the scantiness of his fortune to vie with other public leaders and demagogues in liberality, thought of supplying his private incapacity (according to the testimony of Ari- stotle, at the suggestion of Demonides of Ea) by a distri- 276 See the Choiseul Inscription Pryt. 2. although the gram- marians assert (see Barthélemy and Photius, and Lex. Seg.) that the sacrificers had nothing to do at the great Panathenæa. ¿ 277 Demosth. in Mid. p. 570. 7. and there Ulpian. Liban. Declam. VIII. Harpocrat. Suid. in v. Bowvns, Lex. Seg. p. 219. Harpocration: ὅτι λαμπρὸς ἦν ὁ βοώνης καὶ αἱ μέγισται ἀρχαὶ ἐπὶ τούτῳ ExagoToro. Pollux VIII. 114. falsely includes them among the inferior offices, or offices of service (vängsrín). They occur fre- quently in Inscript. 157. 278 Book I. 15. VOL. I. U 290 bution of the public revenue, and bribed the multitude partly with the Theorica, partly with the payment of the Dicasts, and salaries of other descriptions 279: while he at the same time maintained himself in popular favour by processions, feastings, and other solemnities. The great ad- mirer of the Lacedæmonian customs, who, like Plato and his master, formed a correct judgment in a moral point of view, perceived that Pericles had made his countrymen covetous and indolent, loquacious and effeminate, extrava- gant, vicious, and unruly, by maintaining them at the public expence with donatives, salaries, and Cleruchiæ 280, and by flattering their sensuality and love of enjoyment by sumptuous festivals; nay, even Pericles himself had too acute a mind to overlook the consequences of his own measures; but he considered that there was no other means of maintaining his own and the people's sovereignty in Greece, than by supporting the populace in this manner; he was aware that with him the power of Athens would cease, and he endeavoured to preserve it as long as was possible; but upon the whole his contempt for the people was as great as his liberality towards them. In the mean time the people, so long as Pericles lived, were neither wanting in activity nor public spirit, which tended to make these measures more harmless; and as long as neither injustice abroad, nor negligence in the national enterprizes, nor disorder in the State, resulted from them, it might appear just and equitable that the citizens should enjoy the fruit of their exertions and valour. Besides which Pericles could not suspect that, twenty Olympiads after his death, the multitude would rather consume the public J 279 Plutarch. Pericl. 9. cf. 11. 230 Plat. Gorg. p. 515. E. Plutarch. Pericl. 9. 291 : revenues in feasting, than equip an armament in defence of their freedom, a corruption which was first produced by the avaricious and treacherous demagogues of later days, who flattered every whim of the twenty thousand headed Hydra. These considerations might then appear to pal- liate the conduct of Pericles. But he must have been aware that the unavoidable result of his measures was to increase the oppression of the allies, the dominion of the multitude, and the injustice towards the opulent citizens; while Pericles himself only raised the tribute by a small amount, his successors were forced to augment it to a far greater extent, in order to keep up his profuse expenditure. The surplus of the tributes was brought by talents at the Dionysia into the orchestra to be distributed here the allies were shewn in what light their property was viewed 281. The oligarchical party was well aware that the abolition of these payments would be a severe blow to the democracy; and accordingly, during the government of the Five thousand (Olymp. 92. 1.), which was only of very short duration, no superior office received any sa- lary 282. Aristotle 283 has indeed already remarked, that the different kinds of salaries, for example, the wages of the Public Assembly, are dangerous to the chief persons in the State, for that they occasion the imposition of property-taxes, confiscations of property, and bribery of justice. Not only was it the practice to adjudge property to the State, in order to increase the revenue 284, but the demagogues publicly declared in law-suits, that if judgment 281 Isocrat. vμμax. 29. 282 Thucyd. VIII. 97. 283 Polit. VI. 5. 254 Lys. in Nicom. p. 851. # 292 was not given in some certain manner, the salaries could not any longer be paid to the people 285; and therefore the wealthy, in order to prevent this jealousy, made voluntary donations of their possessions 286. It sometimes happened that the proceeds of the confiscated property were distri- buted among the citizens without any authority; and even Lycurgus divided in this manner 160 talents, which the property of Diphilus had produced. Thus they were not satisfied that by these distributions the State was deprived of its most powerful resources for useful and advantageous objects, but those who profited by these measures encou- raged in the people a desire after the property of others, and widened the breach between the rich and poor, which in the States of antiquity was an incessant and highly dangerous evil. Aristotle justly compares these institutions to the per- forated vessel of the Danaides, as the Athenians were per- petually receiving taxes, and then paying them away, and were then compelled to raise fresh supplies; but the moral corruption which they caused was a far more pernicious consequence; the Athenians were themselves, to make use of an illustration of Plato's, the vessels of the Danaides, which were continually receiving the gratification of their desires, without ever being completely satisfied. The distribution of the Theorica, which, as we have seen, produced such fatal consequences to the Athenians, took its origin from the entrance-money to the theatre. 285 Lys. in Epicrat. init. 286 Herald. Animadv. in Salmas. Observat. ad I. A. et R. VI. 3. 13. C d [Aristot. Polit. VI. 5. Ὅπου δ᾽ εἰσὶ πρόσοδοι, μὴ ποιεῖν ὁ νῦν οἱ δημαγωγοί ποιοῦσι· τὰ γὰς περιόντα νέμουσι, λαμβάνουσι δὲ ἅμα καὶ πάλιν δέονται τῶν αὐτῶν· ὁ τετρημένος γάρ ἐστι πίθος ἡ τοιαύτη βοήθεια τοῖς ἀπόροις.] 293 The entrance was at first free, and crowds and tumults. having arisen from the concourse of many persons, of whom some had not any right to enter, it was evidently to be expected that in a theatre constructed of wood, which was the only one that Athens then possessed, the scaffold- ing would break; and this accident in fact took place; to avoid which evil it was determined to sell the seats for two oboli; but in order that the poor might not be excluded, the entrance-money was given them, on the delivery of which each person received his seat 287. Persons of high rank no doubt at first disdained this as well as other donations 288; although in the age of Demosthenes they received the Theoricon 289. It is possible that the entrance- money for the theatre was introduced before the Theoricon was first paid by the State: it may be fairly supposed that, the citizens having for a time defrayed it at their own expence, the State undertook to pay for the poor; and the introduction of the entrance-money may be fixed without improbability as early as the 70th Olympiad, at which time the scaffolding fell in suddenly, when Pratinas, and 287 Liban. Argum. ad Demosth. Olynth. 1. Schol. Lucian. Timon. 49. Suidas in the first article of bewgixòv, and Etymol. in V. Dewgixèv ágyúgiov, where, as in Photius, there is a mixture of the articles occurring in the other grammarians. The account given in Lex. Seg. (dix, óvóµ.) p. 189. 29. does not deserve to be men- tioned. 288 Cf. Herald. Animadv. in Salmas. Obser. ad I. A. et R. VI. 3. 11. 289 Philipp. IV. p. 141. 18. which oration, as Valckenaer and Wolf have justly remarked, is not the production of Demosthenes, but is composed of different passages of this orator, and is written in the style of a sophist. The defence of the Theoricon in par- ticular, which occurs in p. 141., is in direct contradiction with Demosthenes. 294 probably also Æschylus, were representing in the theatre 290. But the payment of the Theoricon out of the public money was first introduced by Pericles 291; and when Harpocration calls Agyrrhius the author of the Theoricon in the extended sense of a distribution of money, he refers to an increase of it made at a later period, of which I shall presently speak 292. This distribution of the Theoricon filled the theatre 293. We may observe, that the entrance- money was paid to the lessee of the theatre (sargúvns, Deα- τροπώλης, ἀρχιτέκτων)294, who was bound to keep the the- atre in repair, and who paid something to the State for rent, as we see in the case of the theatre at the Piraeus. Ulpian, a writer on whom very little dependence can be placed, affirms that one obolus was given to the lessee of the theatre, or, as he calls him, to the Architecton, and that the citizens received the other for their support; this statement is however without foundation, for, according to Demosthenes, the regular entrance-money was two oboli 295; although it is so far true, that a separate payment of Theorica was made for the banquet of the citizens 296. It 290 Vid. Græc. Tragoed. Princip. p. 38. and more particularly Her- mann's de Choro Eumenidum Eschyli Diss. II. p. VIII, XIV. 291 Ulpian. ad Demosth. Olynth. 1. Plutarch. Pericl. 9. 292 Petit IV. 10. 9. unjustly charges the grammarian with confusing this with the pay of the Assembly. 293 Plutarch de Sanit. Tuend. p. 373. vol. I. ed. Hutt. 294 Ulpian. ad Demosth. Olynth. 1. cf. Casaub. ad Theoph. Char. 11. [See Rose Inscript. p. 257.] 295 De Corona p. 234. 23. 296 Harpocrat. in v. ewgixòy (from Philinus), from which the second article of swgxà in Suidas, and the third in Photius, is transcribed. As this is frequently the case, I shall not always quote Suidas and Photius, where they have nothing new. 295 might also be supposed that, as Demosthenes reckons the entrance-money among the smaller revenues of the State, the payment was received on the public account, and not for the lessee; but even though the tenant received it, it might have been enumerated among the national profits, inasmuch as he paid a rent to the State; so that this example from Demosthenes, who only speaks in general terms, and without any great precision, proves nothing in contradiction to my opinion. The privilege of receiving the Theorica was obtained through registration in the book of the citizens (^nžiagXixòv ygaµµatstov) 297; the distribution was made both individually and by tribes 298, absentées receiving nothing 299; and it took place in the Assembly300; which was sometimes held in the theatre, particularly when the business related to the celebration of the Dionysia 301. The application of the Theorica was soon extended, and money was distributed on other occasions than at the theatre 302, though always at the celebration of some festival; and as either a play or procession was invariably connected with it, the name still continued applicable. Under the head of Theorica were also comprised the sums expended upon sacrifices and other solemnities 303. Not only at the Panathenæa 304, but at all the great festivals (iegoun- 297 Demosth, in Leochar. p. 1091 sq. 298 Herald. ut sup. VI. 3. 10. also Lucian Timon. 49. 299 Hyperides ap. Harpocrat. ut sup. 300 sch. in Ctesiph. p. 642. 301 Lex ap. Demosth. in Mid. p. 517. cf. Isocrat. ovuµax. 29. 302 Libanius ut sup. 503 Hesych. in v. θεωρικὰ χρήματα, θεωρικὸν ἀργύριον, and θεωρεί, and his Commentators. See above chap. 7. 304 Hesych. in v. Oswgixà xgńpata. Dem, in Leochar. ut sup. 296 vía) 305, Theorica were distributed. In the Choiseul In- scription we find that in Olymp. 92. 3. from the public treasure alone (probably however on condition of repay- ment) in the first seven Prytaneias 16 talents 4787 drach- mas were paid to the Hellenotamiæ, under the name of Diobelia, which formed a part of the Theorica. The citizens were thus enabled to celebrate the festival with greater luxury; and from this various application of the money there has arisen an uncertainty whence the Theo- ricon took its name; and Ammonius, in direct contradic- tion to Cæcilius, denies that it had reference to spectacles (θέαι) 306. From this uncertainty the question suggests itself, whether the rate of the Theoricon for the separate festivals was not raised when its objects were multiplied, and whether the difference in the statements of ancient writers may not be thus explained. The grammarians speak in general of two oboli 307; the inscription above referred to mentions the Diobelia, as also Aristotle and the Lexicon Rhetoricum 308. In an oration falsely indeed attributed to Demosthenes, but not on that account unde- serving of credit 309, the Theoricon, for the distribution of which a nominal assembly was held, is estimated at 305 Ulpian. ad Demosth. Olynth. III. 306 Ammonius in v. Osagòs, where he falsely derives it from dev ὠρεῖν: διὰ τὸ ἐν ταῖς ἑορταῖς εἰς τοὺς θεοὺς εὐσεβεῖν καὶ ἐπιθύειν (as Valckenaer corrects for ἐπιθεῖν) καὶ εὐφραίνεσθαι. 307 Ulpian, Libanius, Suidas, in the first article, Etymol. Pho- tius in the first article, Schol. Aristoph. Vesp. 1183. 308 Aristot. Polit. II. 5. (II. 4. 11. ed. Schneid.), who calls it dißoria, although he speaks of it with another view. Schneider has not examined the subject with sufficient accuracy. Lex. Seg. p. 237. διωβελία· ὀβολοὶ δύο, οὓς καθήμενος ὁ δῆμος ἐμισθοφόρες 300 περὶ συντάξ. p. 169. 1. 297 two oboli. On the other hand, Philochorus, as quoted by Harpocration, states, that "the Theoricon was originally a drachma for the theatre, whence in after times it re- ceived its name," and the grammarians mention the same amount 310; Lucian 311 speaks of the drachma and the three oboli, where from the context the former can only be referred to the Theoricon, and the latter to the pay of the Assembly or of the Dicasts; and in the spurious Proœmia to the Public Speeches of Demosthenes 312 it is said, “with the drachma, and the chus (of wine probably), and the four oboli (which latter I confess I cannot explain), the orators prolong the life of the people, as physicians do of the dying." The difficulty appears to vanish if we ad- mit that the Theoricon was very variable, which seems to be pointed at by Harpocration; nor will I deny that this was the case: since however two oboli are mentioned both in ancient and recent times, it does not appear to have been raised by increasing the regular rate; the change was probably effected by doubling or trebling the same two oboli for festivals which lasted several days, in such a manner that for a festival of three days a drachma was given, and for one of two days four oboli, to which the above-cited passage of the Pseudo-Demosthenes may be referred. Hesychius, Suidas, and Zenobius, indeed assert, that in the Archonship of Diophantus the Theoricon amounted to a drachma; but this is not contrary to my 310 Hesych. and Suid. in v. deaxù xaλaçãoa, Zenob. III. 27. 311 Demosth. Eulog. 36. where J. M. Gessner thinks that the drachma is the pay of the orators, which however is too small a sum for the regular stipend, to be meant here. He should have rather instanced the pay of the senators. 312 P. 1459. 27. 298 44 5 supposition. Diophantus was Archon in Olymp. 96. 2. according to Petit's correct remark, against which it is needless to object that the nation could not at that time have given so high a Theoricon, as it had not yet recovered from its impoverished State; for it was precisely at this moment that the condition of Athens began to ameliorate; and with the democratic constitution which then existed, it would undoubtedly have been the first object to restore the Theoricon: and this probably was in fact the case; so that for three great festivals of three days a Diobelia was paid three times. From a passage of Harpocration 313, rather obscurely expressed, it may be inferred that its renewal was effected by Agyrrhius, who flourished at this period, and who, as will be presently shewn, tripled the pay of the Assembly about the same time. Moreover it may be observed, that in the age which followed the Anarchy, the price of an ordinary place in the theatre remained at two oboli314; the price of the best places at 316 In v. Θεωρικά: Θεωρικὰ ἦν τινα ἐν κοινῷ χρήματα ἀπὸ τῶν τῆς πόλεως πρόσοδων συναγόμενα· ταῦτα δὲ πρότερον μὲν εἰς τὰς τοῦ πολέμου χρείας ἐφυλάττετο καὶ ἐκαλεῖτο Στρατιωτικὰ, ὕστερον δὲ κατετίθετο εἴς τε τὰς δημοσίας κατασκευὰς καὶ διανομὰς, ὧν πρῶτος ἤρξατο ᾿Αγύρριος ὁ Inaywyós. Photius has the same article, only the most im- portant part, the mention of Agyrrhius, he omits. 514 Demosth. pro Corona p. 234. where he says if it had not been ordered that the Architecton was to assign a place to Philip's ambassadors, they must have sat iv Toîv dvoîv ößoλoïv, which should not be taken with Hier. Wolf for dvov ißoλov, for in that case what would be the use of the preposition and the article? Reiske correctly refers it to a particular place; it means however a common, as opposed to a good, seat; such, for instance, as the place of those who had the privilege of Proedria (cf. Æschin. in Ctesiph. p. 466.), which the ambassadors occupied: what Ulpian (p. 281. ed. Bekker), or rather the collection of scholia com- 1 299 the representation of comedies was at the highest no more than a drachma 315. If we reckon that eight thousand people received the Theoricon-and the number of the receivers cannot have been well less-the Diobelia for one day amounted to a talent; and since it was without doubt paid on twenty-five or thirty days in the course of a year, the lowest rate at which we can estimate the annual expence of it, is from twenty-five to thirty talents. They were not however satis- fied with allowing it to remain at this point, but, as I have before remarked, they squandered away as Theorica all the money destined for the uses of war; that the funds however of the Theorica amounted to 1000 talents, which were dissipated in this manner, as asserted by a modern writer, is a statement of which I have been unable to find any confirmation. It was by this means that the Athenians delivered themselves to the power of Macedon. " With the death of Epaminondas," says Justin 316, who pro- bably avails himself of an idea of Theopompus, " perished also the virtue of the Athenians. For after the excitement which had been produced by the emulation existing be- tween the Athenians and Epaminondas had ceased, they resigned themselves to indolence and inactivity, and squan- posed of various kinds of notes, says in this place about a trio- bolon and of an obolus is mere absurdity. 315 Plat. Apol. Socrat. p. 26. E. Suidas also and Photius (in the second article) in v. Otwgxè, and Schol. Lucian. ut sup. assert that a drachma was the highest sum which was given for a place; but to suppose that a lower sum was never given, as they assume, with the exception of Photius, is absurd, since it would contradict what occurs before. 316 VI. 9. He says at the end, Dividi cœpium est, which is not entirely correct. 300 dered away on festivals and shows the public revenue which formerly had been used for the equipment of fleets and armies. Then were the taxes, with which soldiers and sailors used to be maintained, distributed among the inha- bitants of the city. Thus was Philip able to gain the ascendancy." What in Pericles indeed originated from no motives of patriotism, was employed by profligate Demagogues to work upon a depraved multitude; and we may here remark that nothing can be a more striking proof how destructive the immorality of the governors is to the welfare of the governed. For is it not the fact that the chief promoters of the Theoricon were men distin- guished for their effeminacy, immorality, and general de- pravity? Agyrrhius, who obtained such popularity by his profuse administration of the public revenue, that after the death of Thrasybulus (Olymp. 97.) he was ap- pointed to succeed him as general 317, was notorious for his effeminacy, farmed the taxes like an usurer, and was in prison many years for embezzlement of public money 318. Eubulus of Anaphlystus, by his distribution of the Theo- rica, arrived at the highest pitch of popular favour 319, and after his death great honours were decreed him (as had been done to Lycurgus and Demosthenes), which Hy- perides spoke of in his oration περὶ τῶν Εὐβούλου δωρεῶν; 317 Xenoph. Hell. IV. 8. 31. Diod. XIV. 99. 318 Concerning him see Harpocration in v. 'Ayúggos and there Valesius, and Suidas, also Demosth. in Timocrat. p. 742. 16. and Andocid. de Myst. p. 65. who ironically calls him ròv xañón xayatov, and the passages collected by Meursius, Lect. Att. VI. 4. 319 See book II. I. and 7. Concerning the Theorica which he distributed, see more particularly Philinus ap. Harpocrat. and Photius in v. θεωρικά. 301 but he was strongly suspected of being in the pay of Philip, and was actively instrumental to the downfal of his country. The severe but impartial Theopompus gave his character with perfect justice, " that he was a celebrated demagogue, active and indefatigable in his vocation, but that during his administration and by his distributions of money, Athens sunk to the lowest state of inactivity and indo- lence, exceeding even Tarentum in extravagance and de- bauchery 320." Lastly, what shall we say of Demades, who promised each Athenian fifty drachmas for the Choëis in order to hinder the equipment of a fleet against Alex- ander for the support of the common safety of Greece 321; and carried his effrontery to such a pitch as to call these distributions the cement of the Democracy 322? Even Es- chines 323 did not go so far as this, for he at least declared ، 320 Theopompus in the tenth book of the History of Philip had treated of the Athenian Demagogues, and particularly of Eubu- lus. Some account from that source is given by Harpocration in v. Eűßouλos, and more by Athen. IV. p. 166. E. according to whom he had called him caros. But the passage of Theopom- ἄσωτος. pus quoted as a proof refers to the Athenian people and not to Eubulus: καὶ τοσοῦτον ἀσωτίᾳ καὶ πλεονεξίᾳ διενήνοχε τοῦ δήμου τοῦ Τα- ραντίνων, ὅσον ὁ μὲν περὶ τὰς ἑστιάσεις εἶχε μόνον ἀκρατὴς, ὁ δὲ τῶν ᾿Αθηναίων καὶ τὰς προσόδους καταμισθοφορῶν διατετέλεκεν. Casaubon perceived this, but Schweighäuser confuses it all again, although the passage of Æschines (in Ctesiph. p. 300.) which he had already quoted upon the word xaraμclopogav might have taught him that the people is meant. Theopompus however had evidently censured Eubulus severely, and compared him to his disadvantage with Callis- tratus, the son of Callicrates, whose luxurious life he indeed blamed, but appears to have praised his political conduct. 321 See book II. 6. 322 Plutarch. Qu. Plat. X. 4. 323 Eschin. in Ctesiph. p. 642. 302 himself hostile to the distribution of the revenue; al- though his professions and his real opinions probably disagreed. What however was the public and private life of Demades? Though a man of such splendid quali- ties of mind that an ancient said of him, that he was above the State, while he could only call Demosthenes worthy of the State, he yet became openly a traitor to his country, indulging only his own appetites, and his principles became as loose and unsteady as his judgment was perverse. It is vain to urge in extenuation of his public conduct that a fragment only of the vessel of the State was left to his charge, which was scarce worth preserving from shipwreck; he himself was, as Plutarch happily expresses it, the shipwreck of the State 324. How dis- gracefully he yielded himself to the will of Antipater; how did he delight in every unlawful practice, and in dissolute opulence, fragrant with perfumes and walking in a costly chlamys! He lived in such a manner that Antipater could never supply him with money sufficient for his purposes; and aptly said of him when he grew old, that like a dressed ox upon the altar, nothing re- mained of him but belly and tongue 325. His profligate life hardly allows us to bestow upon his mournful death the compassion which common humanity would dictate. (14.) The salaries at Athens were of various kinds, but the most important were the wages of the Assembly, the Senate, and the Dicasts. The nature of Democracy re- quires that all public affairs should be determined upon 324 Plutarch. Phoc. 1. where he calls him the vaváyev rus Toλs, which does not however signify shipwreck, but a fragment of a vessel wrecked; there is however no other word by which it can be translated into our language. 325 Plut. Phoc. 20, 26, 30. 303 by the whole people in an assembly, and that the business and decrees be prepared beforehand by a select body, which should have the management of them, and execute the resolutions of the popular assembly; and unless the governing power is to fall into the hands of the mob, the people should receive no pecuniary compensation for their share in the government, an expence which it is impossible to defray by revenues justly raised; it is a condition requisite for good government, that all who wish to par- take in the ruling power should support themselves upon their own property. Athens was not however the only State in which the people were paid for governing; a similar system of salaries had been introduced at Rhodes by the Demagogues 326. As to the wages of the Dicasts, it is right that some compensation should be allowed for the performance of judicial duties, and it was at all times customary; Oligarchies indeed were enabled to compel the rich by the threat of punishment to execute these duties, whereas in Democracies the poor were paid for their labour 327. But from the number of judges in a democratical court of justice, this practice could not exist without the expences being defrayed by a tax, which it was impossible to raise without oppression. And if Athens like other States had only decided her own law-suits, it would not have been necessary to pay the Dicasts; the citizens would have remained at their business, active and industrious. But to the great injury of the allied States, Athens, in order to ensure her own power, usurped the jurisdiction over them, and the people were well pleased, that the custom-duties became by these 326 Aristot. Polit. V. 5. 327 Aristot. Polit. IV. 9. and 14. བ / 304 means more productive, that the judicial fees were multi- plied, and that the rent of houses and slaves was in- creased 328. Under these circumstances the number of causes was so much augmented that there were more to decide in Athens than in the whole of Greece; and the law-suits, particularly as the festivals produced so large a number of days on which no business was done, were extremely protracted, unless indeed they were accelerated by bribery 329, against which nevertheless at Athens as well as at Rome very excellent regulations were in existence. Nearly the third part of the citizens sat as judges every day: hence that passion for judging necessarily arose, which Aristophanes describes in the Wasps, and the citizens were thus not only made averse to every profitable and useful employment, but were ren- dered sophistical and litigious; and the whole town became full of pettifoggers and chicaners, who were without any real knowledge of law or justice, and on that account only the more rash and thoughtless. According to the expres- sion of the comic poet, they sat, like sheep, muffled up in their cloaks and with their judicial staff, for three oboli a day, thinking indeed that they managed the affairs of the State, while they were themselves the tools of the party- leaders. / The wages of the Assembly (μισθὸς ἐκκλησιαστικὸς) the sovereign people paid to itself. The honour of invent- ing this salary is contended for between Callistratus and Agyrrhius, and fortunately both claimants can be satisfied. Pericles, as far as we know, had no share in it, and it may be asserted with sufficient probability that this 328 Xenoph. de Rep. Ath. 3. Aristoph. Av. 1430, 1465. 329 Xenoph. ut sup. 3. 2. 305 payment had not been introduced in the early part at least of his administration. "When the noble Myronides ruled," observes Aristophanes 330, with reference to the wages of the Ecclesiasts, "no one administered the affairs of the State for money." Now Myronides was an early cotemporary of Pericles 331; after the time then of this Myronides, and consequently long after the beginning of the influence of Pericles, the payment of the Ecclesiasts was introduced, which at first amounted to one obolus and afterwards to three. Callistratus Parnytes first intro- duced the obolus as the pay of the Ecclesiasts 332, and this was a considerable time before the Ecclesiazusæ of Aris- tophanes, which was acted in Olymp. 96. 4.; but, at what particular period we are ignorant, since who this Callis- K 330 Eccles. 302. 331 Myronides was general in the 80th Olympiad, Thucyd. I. 105, 108. IV. 95. Diod. XI. 97, 81. Cf. Plutarch. Pericl. 16. The Myronides in Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 742. 25. is a dif- ferent person. [Myronides was introduced by Eupolis in the Ana (ap. Plutarch. Pericl. 24.) as holding a dialogue with Pericles: if therefore Eupolis first exhibited in 429. B. C. the year in which Pericles died (Clinton Fast. Hell. p. 63.) the Anuos must have been his first play; and consequently Myronides had a part in public affairs in the last year of the life of Pericles. Photius in μὴ παιδὶ μάχαιραν. Εὔπολις Δήμοις· μὴ παιδὶ τὰ κοινὰ, i. e. probably, “do not trust the management of public affairs to Alcibiades." This allusion is not inconsistent with the date 429. B. C. for two years afterwards he was mentioned by Aris- tophanes in the Aarraλus (427. B. C.), at which time, as Elmsley says, ad Acharn. 716. “inter claros oratores habitus est Alci- biades."] 352 Append. Vatic. Proverb. III. 35. 'Oßoλòv süge Пægvurns. That Petit should suppose (III. 1. 3.) that the Ecclesiasts here men- tioned might be the orators, is quite natural, as he always hits upon the most improbable explanation. VOL. I. X King 306 ! tratus was is wholly unknown. The most celebrated of the persons of this name is Callistratus, the son of Calli- crates, of Aphidna, the near relation of Agyrrhius 333, a famous orator and general in the 100th and 101st Olym- piads 334, censured for his private life by Theopompus, but praised for his zeal in the public service 335; he is said to have excited Demosthenes to the study of elo- quence by the famous law-suit concerning Oropus 336, and having been at first acquitted, was afterwards condemned to death in Olymp. 104. 3.; he lived in Macedonia, chiefly at Methone, and was the founder of Datum 337; and is doubtless the person to whom the improvement in the system of custom-duties in Macedonia is ascribed 338; finally, after his return from exile he was put to death. This person however lived at too late a period to have been the introducer of the obolus; and still less can we suppose it to have been the Callistratus, who was Archon in Olymp. 106. 2. Not then to mention less noted per- 333 Concerning him see Demosth. pro Corona p. 301. 18. in Timocrat. p. 742. 23. de Fáls. Leg. p. 436. 13. Orat. in Neær. p. 1353. 19. and p. 1359. 18. in Timoth. p. 1187. 7. p. 1188. 10. p. 1198. 10. The latter speech, together with that against Neæra, is probably not the work of Demosthenes, according to the sus- picion of the ancients ap. Harpocrat. in v. xaxorexviãõu. 334 See book III. 18. He also occurs in Xenophon's Hellenics. 335 Ap. Athen. IV. p. 166. E. 356 Cf. Ruhnken. Hist. Crit. Orat. p. 140. vol. VIII. of Reiske's Orators. 337 Demosth. in Polycl. p. 1220, 1221. Scylax p. 27. Isocrat. ovμμax. 9. Comp. Niebuhr Transactions of the Berlin Academy συμμαχ. for 1804-1811. p. 93, 94. 338 Pseud-Aristot. Econ. 2. 22. This he did in his exile, not for Athenians, as Schneider appears to think, but for the Mace- donians. my 307 sons of this name, it is more probable that Callistratus, the son of Empedus, is meant, who in Olymp. 91. 4. perished as commander of cavalry in the Sicilian expe- dition 339; or perhaps Callistratus of Marathon, who in Olymp. 92. 3. was treasurer of the Goddess 340, and pro- bably is the same person as the Knight of the tribe Leontis (to which Marathon belonged), who was killed during the Anarchy by the party in the Piraeus 341. The increase in the wages of the Ecclesiasts to three oboli evidently took place but a short time before the Eccle- siazusæ of Aristophanes; perhaps in Olymp. 96. 3.342, when Agyrrhius re-established the Theoricon; to him also the Scholiast upon Aristophanes 343 ascribes the first introduction of the wages of Ecclesiasts; from which it is evident, as Petit remarked 344, that he was the person who increased them. 339 Pausan. VII. 16. In the Lives of the Ten Orators (De- mosth, ad init.) this one is strangely confounded with the cele- brated Aphidnæan. 340 Choiseul Inscription, at the beginning. 1 341 Xenoph. Hell. II. 4. 18. 342 K Aristoph. Eccl. 302, 380, 392, 543. This increased pay also occurs in the Plutus vs. 329. which passage is therefore from the second edition produced in Olymp. 97. 4.; the date of the first is Olymp. 92. 4. The triobolon in the Ecclesia is also men- tioned by the Schol. Aristoph. Plut. 171. 343 Eccl. 102. 344 Leg. Att. III. 1. 3. The Scholiast of Aristophanes (Plut. 329, 330.) speaks of the pay being raised to three oboli, which was said to have been done by Cleon, but we must avoid under- standing this of the wages of the Ecclesiasts, which are there confounded with the pay of the Dicasts, although the words are not ambiguous; it refers to the wages of the Dicasts. Both have been frequently confounded with one another by both ancient and Sp T 308 The number of the Athenian citizens cannot be taken on an average, as has been before shewn, at more than 20,000; it is absurd then to suppose that there were assemblies of 30,000 persons. But of these 20,000 many were absent in the country on military service, or upon mercantile business; or even if they were in the city, they did not attend the assembly; so that, particular cases being excepted, it is impossible to imagine that the assembly ever contained even this number to the full. But after the introduction of the three oboli, there was a more numerous attendance of the poor citizens. Formerly when the Ecclesiasts only received one obolus," says Aris- tophanes in the Ecclesiazusæ, "the people sat talking; now that they receive three oboli they crowd in num- bers 345; and jostle against one another for this small sum 346." But the wealthy usually were glad to stay 66 S modern interpreters, for instance by Spanheim upon Aristo- phanes, and by the Scholiast to the same poet. The author of the note to the 861st verse of the Clouds even explains the ὀβολὸς ἡλιαστικὸς as the pay of the Ecclesiasts, which passage is not to be corrected, but the mistake is solely to be attributed to the ignorance of the writer. I may also mention that I have intentionally omitted Pollux VIII. 113. as his words are too indefinite to allow us to infer from them with Meursius (Lect. Att. V. 12. VI. 4.) that the wages of the Ecclesiasts ever were an obolus; it is evén preferable to refer the three words that occur there, τριώβολον, διώβολον, and ὀβολὸς, all to the pay of the Dicasts. 345 Aristoph. Eccl. 302 sqq. Compare with this the opinion of Aristotle, that where the nation is wealthy or the Ecclesiasts receive pay, the people being unoccupied frequently assemble and decide every thing, without the Senate having any great influence. 346 Aristoph. Plut. 329. 309 away from the public assemblies, so that Aristotle 347 recom- mended that a fine should be imposed upon them if they did not attend, and to give wages to the poor alone, in order to produce a salutary mixture of both classes; the rich there- fore always composed the minority. It is probable that we should not err much if we took an assembly of the people at about 8000°; we know that in certain cases, particularly for the ratification of a decree, which related to an indi- vidual (privilegium), such as Ostracism or the admission of a fresh citizen, 6000 votes were requisite 348, in order to secure a large majority; in general then not many more than 6000 could have been present. If we suppose 8000, the wages of an Assembly taken at three oboli amount to about 4000 drachmas. Now there were forty regular As- 547 Polit. IV. 14. Cf. IV. 6. ? e The author says in the Addenda that "the number of citizens attending the Ecclesia is estimated too high. According to the Oligarchs in Thucydides VIII. 72. there never was an assembly of 5000 to deliberate on the most important questions: καίτοι οὐ πώποτε ᾿Αθηναίους διὰ τὰς στρατείας καὶ τὴν ὑπερόριον ἀσχολίαν ἐς οὐδὲν πράγμα οὕτω μέγα ἐλθεῖν βουλεύσοντας, ἐν ᾧ πεντακισχιλίους Evveλev. According to this passage then it must be assumed that the 6000 votes, which was the number prescribed for cer- tain questions, was not the number of those who voted for the particular subject in debate, but only of the citizens who voted both ways on the question, which indeed is expressly stated to have been the case with regard to the Ostracism, although when I wrote the passage in the text it appeared to me impro- bable. The accurate investigation of this point must however be deferred to some other occasion." - 348 Petit. Leg. Att. II. 1. 8. II. 3. 10. Sigon. R. A. II. 4. The remarks that Fetit has made in different places (II. 1, 8. JII. 1. 3. III. 3. ad fin.) concerning this majority of the votes, which was not by any means necessary for all decrees, arise from mere misapprehension and delusion. 310 ! ; semblies in a year; the extraordinary meetings (which were numerously attended) at very disturbed seasons exceeded the number of the regular 349; but upon an average not more than ten can be fairly assumed, one being reckoned to each Prytaneia. Consequently the wages of the Assembly cannot be estimated at more than thirty or thirty-five talents, and thus it is not true that they fell more heavily on the public than the wages of the Dicasts 350, The money was paid to each person as he entered the Assembly by the Thesmothetæ 351, which officers received it from the treasurer of the administration: those who came too late received nothing 352. Of nearly equal amount were the wages of the Senate of Five hundred (μiolòs Bouλeutinós). These amounted to a drachma for each day on which the Senate assembled 353. Now the Senate sat mostly on the same days as the courts of justice; that is to say, every day, with the exception of the festivals, which were the only holidays the Senators had; and consequently the number of days on which they sat was about three hundred 354. The annual expence therefore amounted to 25 talents. In what manner the wages of the Senate were paid, we are not informed; probably by . Prytaneias. When the Four hundred abolished the demo- 349 Esch. de Fals. Leg. p. 251. 350 As Meiners says in his History of the Origin, Progress, and Decline of the Sciences, vol. II. p. 150. 1 351 Aristoph. Eccl. 290. 352 Aristoph. ibid. and 381. 353 Hesych. in v. Bovλñs λaxeiv, Xenoph. Hell. II. 3. 18. and his Commentators. 354 Cf. Aristoph. Thesmoph. 85. The senate originally sat on some feast-days, and was not released from these duties till later times, as is shewn by the document in Athen. IV. p. 171. E. 311 cracy, and drove the Senate out of the Senate-house, they gave the Senators the whole pay for the rest of the year in advance 355. (15.) The largest item among the salaries regularly paid in time of peace was the wages of the Dicasts (μισθὸς δικα- στικὸς), the introduction of which is ascribed to Pericles by Aristotle 356, on whose accurate acquaintance with anti- quity perfect reliance can be placed. And from the testi- mony of the same writer we learn that the wages of the Dicasts did not remain the same, but underwent some 556 Thucyd. VIII. 69. 356 Petit II. 10. It is therefore unnecessary to refute the Append. Prov. Vatic. III. 35. which attributes the first institu- tion of this pay to Callistratus. [The passage in the Politics referred to, τὰ δὲ δικαστήρια μισθοφόρα κατέστησε Περικλῆς, is from a chapter which appears not to be the production of Aristotle (see Göttling ad loc. p. 345.; another statement in the same chapter is called in question by the author himself, vol. II. p. 261.); it is however confirmed by Plutarch, Pericl. 9. καὶ ταχὺ θεωρικοῖς καὶ δικαστικοῖς λήμμασι . . . . συνδεκάσας τὸ πλῆθος, &c. The testimony of the Scholiast to Aristophanes (Vesp. 682.), cited in the next note, seems to be unfairly made use of. It is as follows: τὸν φόρον λέγει ἀφ᾽ ὧν ἐδίδοτο τὸ τριώβολον. τοῦτο δὲ ἄλλοτε ἄλλως ἐδίδοτο, τῶν δημα γωγῶν τὰ πλήθη κολακευόντων, ὥς φησιν Αριστοτέλης ἐν Πολιτείαις, i. e. wages were given to the Dicasts at different rates at different times, the demagogues flattering the populace, as Aristotle says in the Politics, viz. IV. 4. ὁ δημαγωγὸς καὶ ὁ κόλαξ οἱ αὐτοὶ καὶ ἀνάλογον, &c. and V. 11. διὸ καὶ ὁ κόλαξ παρ᾽ ἀμφοτέροις ἔντιμος· παρὰ μὲν τοῖς δήμοις ὁ δημαγωγὸς, ἔστι γὰρ ὁ δημαγωγὸς τοῦ δήμου κόλαξ. No objection can be made from the use of the plural Πολιτείαις ; for Aristotle himself says IV. 7. ὥσπες Πλάτων ἐν ταῖς Πολιτείαις. The same expression with regard to the variable rate of the Dicasts' wages is used by Hesychius, without any mention of Aristotle: δικαστικόν· ᾿Αριστοφάνης ἐν Ωραις τριώβολόν ψησιν εἶναι· οὐ μέντοι ἔστηκεν, ἀλλ᾽ ἄλλοτε ἄλλως ἐδίδοτο.] . e } 312 change 357. What then were these alterations, and when did they take place? Strepsiades says in the Clouds 358 that he had given the first Heliastic obolus to his son, when he was six years old, to buy a little cart; hence we learn that originally the pay of the Dicasts amounted to an obolus; and since in Olymp. 89. 1. the child is re- presented in the Clouds as a practised rider, this obolus must have been introduced for at least four Olympiads. The Scholiast tells us that the wages of the Dicasts. amounted to two oboli in the time of the Frogs of Aristo- phanes; it is also stated that they were a drachma at the same period 359. With regard to the latter statement, there is evidently a confusion either with the drachma of the Diætetæ, or with the pay of the advocates (olds oumyo- gixòs), of which latter Aristophanes speaks in a passage that the Scholiast perhaps referred to the wages of the Dicasts. But no traces occur of their wages ever having been two oboli, except a vague report in the Scholiast to the Birds, that the Dicasts had for a time received two 357 Schol. Aristoph. Vesp. 682. from Aristotle's State of Athens. Schol. Nub. 861. Plut. 329. Av. 1540. Hesych. in v. dinaσTixò, Suidas in v. iarraí. Concerning the expression of the grammarians compare Hemsterhuis ad Plut. ut sup. Petit as usual (III. 1. 3.) founds a false view of the subject upon a false interpretation of the Scholiast of Aristophanes. 358 Vs. 861. 359 Schol. Aristoph. Ran. 141. (Cf. Schol. Vesp. 658. con- cerning the drachma). Welcker, at the above passage in the Frogs, allows that the Triobolon may have been introduced pre- viously, but he prefers adhering to the explanation of the Scho- liast, as he thinks that Aristophanes mentions two oboli accord- ing to the ancient usage, although they received three at that time. This is not very probable, and I do not doubt that he will prefer my interpretation. Vô 313 oboli; either the grammarian inferred this from the words of Aristophanes (ὡς μέγα δύνασθον πανταχοῦ τῷ δυ᾽ ὀβολώ), or he had heard something of the Diobelia, and supposed it was the wages of the Dicasts. But the words of Aristophanes unquestionably refer to the Diobelia. That this was in full force in Olymp. 92. 3. we know from the Choiseul Inscription, and why should it not have been equally so in Olymp. 93. 3., the year in which the Comedy of the Frogs was acted? If the wages of the Dicasts had been raised before this time to three oboli, no one will suppose that the Athenians would have lowered this rate in opposition to their pecuniary interest; and in fact we find that it had been introduced previously. In the Birds of Aristophanes 360, which was acted in Olymp. 91. 2., the Triobolon occurs as the wages of the Dicasts, as is proved by the connection with the Colacretæ ; and indeed it is mentioned at a much earlier date, viz. in the Knights (Olymp. 88. 4.) and the Wasps (Olymp. 89. 2.) 361. In both plays Cleon is the chief object of ridicule, and in the Knights he is distinctly mentioned as the favourer of the Triobolon 362; in the latter comedy he boasts of having always taken care that it did not fail; and he flatters the people by telling them that, according to ancient oracles, the pay of the Dicasts would be in Arcadia as high as five oboli; i. e. as the Scholiast adds, when the Peloponnese should be conquered 363. If we add 360 Vs. 1540. 361 Eq. 51, 255. Vesp. 607, 682, 688, 797, 1116. 562 Eq. 257. 363 Eq. 797. This passage has been strangely misunderstood by Spanheim (ad Nuh. 861.), who has inferred from it that in Arcadia the pay of the Dicasts amounted to five obuli. The Ar- cadians probably never thought of the Dicasts' wages: but Cleon -- 314 to this the testimony of the Scholiast to the Plutus 364, it follows with certainty that none other than this noxious demagogue, at the time of his greatest power, about the 88th Olympiad, raised the wages of the Dicasts from one to three oboli'. From this it seems that the rate of pay- ment never was at two oboli; yet Pollux 365, as well as the Scholiast to Aristophanes, appears to have believed in its existence. Otherwise the grammarians, in speaking of the wages of the Dicasts, generally mention three oboli, at the same time recognizing their mutability 366. The hero forcibly represents to the Athenians the extension of their juris- diction to the middle of the Peloponnese, and its consequence, a plentiful harvest of money. 364 Vs. 330. which, although adduced in an improper place, should be referred to the pay of the Dicasts. f f [Zenobius and Photius in v. ὑπὲρ τὰ Καλλικράτους-᾿Αριστοτέλης δέ φησιν ἐν τῇ ᾿Αθηναίων πολιτείᾳ Καλλικράτην τινὰ πρῶτον τοὺς δικαστι- κοὺς μισθοὺς (δικαστῶν τοὺς μισθοὺς Zen.) εἰς ὑπερβολὴν αὐξῆσαι. From the expression "a certain Callicrates, Kaλλgáτn Tiva," it seems Καλλικράτη τινὰ,” that the increaser of the Dicasts' wages could not have been a well-known person. Callistratus, the son of Callicrates, flou- rished about the 100th Olympiad (see above p. 306.); his father therefore might have carried this measure ten Olympiads before that time; which nearly agrees with the date given in the text for the supposed increase by Cleon.] 365 VIII. 113. According to the explanation of Spanheim ut sup. which, as I have above mentioned, I prefer to that of Meur- sius, without however believing the account of Pollux, as Span- heim does. 366 Poll. VIII. 20. Hesych. in v. dinaσrınòv, Suid. in v. ¿λaσtai ηλιασταὶ and Banτngia, Schol. Aristoph. in the passages quoted above and Plut. 277. Suid. and Phot. in v. cíußodov, Schol. Demosth. in Reisk. Demosth. vol. II. p. 131. Lucian. Bis Accus. 12. and 15. Several other passages, as e. g. Hesychius in v. ßoλol, I omit, as they contain nothing to make them worth quoting. 315 Lycus, under whose protection the system of judicature was placed, regularly received his three oboli, if he had a sanctuary in the court of justice 367. The payment of the wages of the Dicasts, which was the duty of the Colacretæ, took place at each sitting of the court 368, in the following manner. Besides the judicial staff, each person received at his entrance into the court a small tablet (called σúµßoλov); at the close of the sitting he gave this to the Prytanes, and received the money for it; whoever came late into court ran the risk of receiving nothing 369. The Prytaneia were first appointed for defraying the expence; if these were not sufficient (and how could they ever have been so), the other branches of the revenue contributed, particularly the fines, and probably in ancient times the tributes 370. Aristo- phanes reckons the annual amount at 150 talents, assuming 300 days on which the courts sat, and 6000 Dicasts a day who received the Triobolon 371; and that the expence was not less we learn from other sources. It is however to be remarked, that Aristophanes in forming his calculation · • 367 See Hudtwalcker von den Diäteten p. 14. 368 Lucian. ut sup. 369 Schol. Aristoph. Plut. 277. whose information is chiefly taken from Aristotle's State of Athens quoted by the Scholiast at v. 278. also Suidas in v. ßanrngia, Etymol. in v. cußoλov, Poll. VIII. 16. Aristoph. Vesp. 710. 370 Cf. Schol. Aristoph. Vesp. 682. 371 Vesp. 660 sqq. and the Scholiast. About sixty holidays, on which the courts did not sit, are not too many for Athens; this leaves 300 sitting-days. But I am not able to find any confirmation of Hudtwaicker's supposition (von den Diäteten p. 30.) that the courts did not sit through the whole of Sciro- phorion. 316 S has taken the Dicasts at 6000, their highest number, who did not perform their duties every day. Six thousand were appointed for each year; and from these the Dicasts were first selected for each particular cause, and it was not till they were actually assigned to some court that they re- ceived the pay. The ten regular courts of justice at Athens, consisting each of 500 Dicasts, required only the daily attendance of five thousand 372. Now it is true that large tribunals occur of 1000, 1500, 2000, and even 6000 Dicasts; but, on the other hand, small ones of 201, 401, &c. 373. It is therefore possible that the expence was something less than Aristophanes states it; I am willing however to allow his estimate to pass as an approximation to the truth, when applied to the times preceding the Anarchy, and to compute the expences of jurisdiction generally at 150 talents, particularly as many small ex- pences, in addition to the pay of the Dicasts, must ne- cessarily have been incurred in the courts; but after the Archonship of Euclid, when the allies had revolted, it is not possible that there could have been so many Dicasts, and the expence must therefore have been less. And as in time of war the courts did not always continue sitting 374, these expences occasionally ceased. The wages of the Diæteta were not provided out of the public money; these persons were paid for each separate cause by the litigant parties themselves. The Diætetæ received a drachma from the plaintiff at the commence- 372 See Matthiä Miscell. Philog. vol. I. p. 251 sqq. comp. also p. 158. 373 Besides Matthiä see Pollux VIII. 53 and 48. Lex. Seg. p. 310. 30. and p. 189. 20. Phot. in v. aia. 374 57 Lys. περὶ δημοσ. ἀδικ. p. 590. 317 ment of the suit, and again the same sum from both par- ties at the Antomosia, and at every Hypomosia 375. A grammarian of mean authority 376 states that the Diætetæ arbitrated many law-suits, and that the public authorities. employed every possible means to prevent the sitting of the courts, in order that the State might not be compelled to expend so much money upon the wages of the Dicasts ; but, judging from the disposition of the Athenians, we can at the most believe that such a motive might have influ- enced them at seasons of the greatest national distress; for in ordinary times they demanded pecuniary largesses for the maintenance of the people. (16.) The wages of the public advocates or orators (μiodòs ouunyoginòs) occasioned a small expence, which amounted every day, i. e. for the 300 days of busi- ness, to a drachma, and not for each speech, as the Scholiast of Aristophanes erroneously asserts 377. As these advocates were ten in number, the whole expence amounted to half a talent a year. The ambassadors also received a stipend in ancient times; and although resident embassies (a practice first introduced by the French) were unknown, it is not yet impossible that they were reckoned among the regular expences, since ambassadors were very frequently despatched to foreign States; and when they travelled to a distance, as, for example, to Persia, were 375 This is the παράστασις or παρακατάστασις. Pollux VIII. 39. 127. Harpocrat. in v. zagúcracıs, and thence Suidas, Photius, and Lex. Seg. p. 290, 298. Пaganaráσтaris occurs in Photius, Etymol., and Lex. Seg. See Hudtwalcker von den Diät. p. 14 sqq. 377 Schol. Demosth. ap. Reisk. ut sup. to which statement Hudtwalcker assents, p. 34. 377 Aristoph. Vesp. 689. and the Scholiast. 318 f tet. 海苔 ​น bide Carto to 1 necessarily absent for a long time. The ambassadors to Philip of Macedon attended him even on marches and journeys 378. All ambassadors, during the time that they were able to have fixed residence, were never compelled to live at their own expence; they were supported by pre- sents which they received both in free States 379 and in countries where the government was monarchical. It may be seen from the speech of Demosthenes for the Crown, that in the Greek cities they were not only honoured with the first place in the theatres, but were hospitably enter- tained, and generally resided at the house of the Proxenus, although an instance occurs of an embassy to Philip having for particular reasons preferred the public inn 380. The treasurer however usually paid them a sum in advance for thirty days, as travelling money (épódiov, Togelov) 381. In the time of Aristophanes the ambassadors received two or three drachmas a day 382. The highest pay which we meet with, such indeed as never was given in any other State, is 1000 drachmas, which was received by five Athe- nian ambassadors who were sent to Philip. These ambas- sadors remained absent three months, although they might have equally well returned at the end of one 383. In 378 Demosth. Philipp. III. p. 113. 18. 379 Demosth. de Fals. Leg. p. 393. 25. Lys. pro Aristoph. bonis p. 629. Ælian. Var. Hist. I. 22. Decree of the Arcadians in Crete in Chishull's Ant. Asiat. p. 118. 380 Orat. de Halon. p. 81. 19. Xenoph. Hell. V. 4. 22. Dem. de Fals. Leg. p. 390. 26. 381 Casaub. ad Theoph. Char. XI. Etymol. in v. ogɛov, Chand. Inscript. II. 12. 3S2 Acharn. 65. and from the context 602. 383 Demosth. de Fals. Leg. p. 390. That there were only five of 319 general however the Athenians sent ten ambassadors, and occasionally not more than two or threes. The Sophro- nistæ, or inspectors of the youths in the training schools, of whom there were ten annually elected by Cheirotonia, one from each tribe, received a daily stipend of one drachma 384; the Episcopi also, who were sent to subject States, received a salary, probably at the cost of the cities over which they presided 385. The Nomothetæ, a law- commission consisting of. 501, 1001, or 1501 persons, who them is evident from the decree in Demosth. pro Corona p. 235. Demosthenes was indeed one of the number, but his name is not in the decree, and therefore the 1000 drachmas should only be referred to the five mentioned in it, unless a subsequent decree was framed, and other ambassadors were appointed in addition to the former. My space however does not permit me to treat of this point at full length, particularly as there are great chronological difficulties connected with it. 5 Four drachmas a day appear to have been given in later times. Menander ap. Phot. in pigulv..... Mer' 'AgioToTÉλous yàg ᾿Αριστοτέλους τέτταρας τῆς ἡμέρας Ὀβολοὺς φέρων. 384 Lex. Seg. p. 301. Phot. in v. cwQgovorai, cf. Etym. in v. in the two latter read ixάorns Quañs eis. The words of the Etymo- logist are both in Phavorinus and Stobæus. See Fischer's Ind. Æschin. in v. ow@govioral, where however, together with Hem- sterhuis ad Poll. VIII. 138. he falsely assumes that there were a hundred Sophronistæ, from the incorrect reading in the gramma- rians above quoted. In the times of the emperors there were only six, and probably the same number of Hyposophronista, who entered their office together at the beginning of the month Boedromion, as may be concluded from an Inscription in Wheler p. 402. Spon, vol. III. part II. p. 158. The Gloss refers to Demosth. de Fals. Leg. p. 433. 3. where however there is only an allusion to this office, which is also mentioned in the Axiochus p. 367 A. 385 Aristoph. Av. 1023 sqq. 320 were selected from those who had been Dicasts, also per- haps received a stipend; for in their former capacity they had been accustomed to the Triobolon; and the Senate was commanded by law to administer the money for the Nomothetæ 386. The collection of the public revenue did not require any paid officers, as it was let out in farm; even when the Senate found it necessary to appoint a collector in order to enforce payment of the farmers, he was but scantily paid. All the servants of the different authorities received salaries, for example, the Prome- tretæ 387; it is however probable that these officers were paid by the sellers of the commodities measured. Ori- ginally there was an important distinction between service (ingeσía) and an office of government (agx); the former received a salary, the latter none. The heralds and clerks particularly deserve notice; since certain heralds, as well as the clerk of the Senate, the clerk of the Senate and People, and the checking-clerk and under-clerk of the Senate, were fed at the cost of the State in the Tholus or Prytaneum 388, where doubtless they also resided. To the transcribers of the laws a stipend was allowed for a fixed time, within which they were bound to complete their labours 389; and a particular sum of money was set apart for engraving the decrees 390. How large the salary of the physicians and the pay of the singers and musicians were at Athens and in other places has been shewn in the 386 Petit Leg. Att. II. 1. 1. See Wolf Proleg. ad Lept. p. CXLVII. 587 Harpocrat. in προμετρηταί. 388 See the Inscriptions quoted in Book II. 8. and Demosth. de Fals. Leg. p. 419. 25. 389 Lysias in Nicom. 390 Book II. 6. 321 first book 391. And how great must have been the number of persons whom the State remunerated for their services (either by its own means or by those of subordinate corpo- rations), such as Citharists, Gymnasts, and others of the same description. The poets also received a salary, which was allowed them by the Senate of Five-hundred; and we have reason to suppose that its amount was not incon- siderable; for Agyrrhius having been offended, as it seems, by the ridicule of comic poets, thought it worth while to persuade the people to reduce it 392. Lastly, several hundred sailors received regular pay in time of peace. In early times the Athenians had two sacred triremes, the Paralos, the crew of which bore the name of Paralitæ (παραλῖται, also πάραλοι), and the Salaminia or Delia (sometimes simply called Theoris), and its crew were named Salaminians 393: the latter vessel belonged to the Delian Theoria; and both these triremes, as being quick sailers, were used for other Theorias, as well as for em- bassies and for the transport of money and persons; in battles also, and then they conveyed the admiral. That the crew of the Paralos, although it was mostly in harbour, always received four oboli a day, we know from distinct 391 Chap. 21. 392 Schol. Eccl. 102. Aristoph. Ran. 370. and the Scholiast. Archinus is mentioned in the last Scholium; but the Scholiast on the Ecclesiazusæ appears better informed; and perhaps Ar- chinus is only an error of the transcriber for Agyrrhius. 393 Concerning both these vessels see Sigon. R. A. IV. 5. In and the Paralos are stated Photius (in v. ágaλo) the Salaminia to be the same ship, which is false. But in the word wágaλos, and in the first article of régano, they are correctly distinguished. Concerning the name of the crew see Pollux VIII. 116. Hesych. in v. Tagaλíτns. Concerning the Delia vid. ad Inscript. 158. §. 1. VOL. I. Y 322 ÷ testimony 394; and as the Salaminia performed the same services, we may without any hesitation assume that the Salaminians received the same pay. The pay of the tri- reme-crews having been generally calculated by estimating the wages of two hundred common sailors, the pay of two triremes at four oboli a man per day: for a year reckoned at 365 days (the intercalary month being divided among the several years) will amount to 16 talents 1333 drachmas two oboli. In latter times we meet with a trireme named Ammonis, which is undoubtedly different from the two first; and an Antigonis and a Demetrias, so called no doubt from the names of those much honoured kings; and finally a Ptolemais 395, of which it is probable, that like the tribe Ptolemais, it only succeeded in the place of the Antigonis or the Demetrias. We are not informed how the pay of these vessels was regulated; but as the Ammonis had a treasurer, it is probable the others had the same, and since the Ammonis served in time of peace, it must occasionally have had sailors who would then have received pay. I will presently speak of two other kinds of salaries paid in time of peace, the pay of the cavalry, and the maintenance of the infirm, which was also called μotos or pay 396; all these taken together caused a considerable expence. In order however to produce some diminution in the amount, and to prevent any person from obtaining greater emolu- ments from the State than was fair, the law ordered that no one should receive pay from more than one source (un dixóber μiotopogeiv) 397. Thus the wages of the Dicasts, διχόθεν μισθοφορεῖν) 394 Harpocrat. and Phot. in v. ágaños. 395 Harpocrat. and Suidas in v. 'Auuavis and there Maussac, Lex. Seg. p. 267. Phot. in v. ágaños and wágaños. 396 Esch. in Timarch. p. 123. 397 Demosth. in Timocrat. p. 739. 6. Petit alone (Leg. Att. 323 orators, Ecclesiasts, senators, soldiers, sailors, cavalry, in short all salaries whatever, precluded any person from receiving pay for other services upon the same day. More- over the grammarians assert that pay was given out by Pry- taneias 398, a statement which is incorrect in this general sense. For the Dicasts and the Assembly were (as well as the Theorica) paid by the day, the soldiers and sailors in war by the month; but of all other persons receiving salaries it may have been true. Nothing seems more natural than that the Senate of Five-hundred, the orators, clerks, and other inferior officers should have been paid by Prytaneias; with regard to the maintenance of the infirm, this was certainly the regulation, and for the soldiers and sailors in the time of peace we may suppose that it was adopted for the sake of uniformity. This mode of pay- ment was also the most convenient for passing the accounts, which took place in every Prytaneia. (17.) The maintenance of those citizens, who on account of bodily defects or infirmities were unable to obtain a This livelihood (adúvaro), was a laudable institution. practice however, as well as the custom of supporting children whose fathers had died in war, until they reached the age of manhood 399, belonged exclusively to the Athe- V. 6. 2.) has believed the absurd idea of Ulpian that this means a prohibition to follow more than one occupation at the same time. 398 Ammonius and from him Thomas Mag. in v. zgvravitov. πρυτανεῖον. Hesychius in the same word says that ἡ ἐπὶ μηνὶ μισθοφορία is also called evτavior, which probably means the pay of the Prytanes and the other Senators, which was paid by Prytaneias, for in later times the Prytaneias coincided with the months. 399 Aristid. Panath. vol. I. p. 331. ed. Cant. [Aristotle how- ever (Pol. II. 5.) states that in his time this last institution 324 nians, as compassion was a virtue rarely met with among the Greeks. With regard to the maintenance of persons who had been mutilated in war, Pisistratus is mentioned as the originator of this custom 400; an account which has every probability, since Pisistratus was of a mild disposition, and usurpers are generally glad to seize every opportunity of conferring a benefit, with a view to make themselves popular; nor would the Athenians with their hatred of tyranny have attributed this honour to him, if he had not deserved it. According to others 401 this pro- vision derived its origin from a law of Solon, who certainly gave the example to Pisistratus by the proposal being made, as Heraclides in Plutarch informs us, for the benefit of an individual. In early times Athens could boast of having no citizen in want of the necessaries of life, nor did any one ever disgrace the nation by begging 102, but after the Peloponnesian war, poverty made itself every where manifest; and no small number stood in need of this assistance, if they were infirm or maimed. The bounty was restricted by law to persons whose property was under. three minas 403; but even in the age of Socrates an income of this amount was very inconsiderable; and, accordingly, all those who received this bounty were in fact nearly destitute. The Athenians however do not seem to have 402. A existed in other States except Athens: ἔστι δὲ καὶ ἐν ταῖς ᾿Αθήναις οὗτος ὁ νόμος νῦν καὶ ἐν ἑτέραις τῶν πόλεων]. 400 Plutarch. Solon. 31. 401 Schol. Æschin. ap. Taylor. ad Lys. vol. V. p. 739. ed. Reiske. et ap. Reisk. vol. III. p. 738. 402 Isocrat. Areop. 38. 105 Harpocrat. Suid. Hesych. and the above-quoted passages of the Lexica in Taylor. ut sup. and the commentators upon Hesychius. 325 been very sparing of this donative; the individual for whom Lysias 404 wrote his speech in order to prove that he was deserving of this support, carried on certainly some trade, although he asserts it was not sufficient to maintain him, and it appears that he rode occasionally, although indeed not upon his own horse, and also because he was unable to walk without the help of crutches. This bounty was awarded by a decree of the people 405; but the ex- amination of the individuals belonged to the Senate of Five- hundred 406; the payments were made by Prytaneias; consequently if any one deferred his examination in one Prytaneia he was obliged to wait till the next 407. 400 The unpublished Scholiast to Æschines, who is quoted by Taylor in his notes, states that this bounty amounted to three oboli a day; here then again we meet with the Triobolon of the Dicasts, which is always crossing the path of the grammarians. The money paid to the infirm was never more than two oboli or less than one: between these two rates ancient writers are divided; the obvious supposition is that some received more than others, according as their necessities were more or less urgent; but a closer consider- ation teaches us that the difference refers only to the times. In the time of Lysias one obolus was given 408; afterwards Περὶ τοῦ ἀδυνάτου. This speech is written in such a jesting tone, that I consider it to be a mere rhetorical exercise, which was never delivered: at least the Athenians must have been very much astonished at the jocularity of this poor man when petitioning for a pecuniary allowance. 405 Herald. Anim. in Salm. Observ. ad I. A. et R. III. 8. 4. 406 Æschin. in Timarch. p. 123. Harpocrat. Suid. Hesych, and a Lexicon in the Bibl. Coislin. p. 603. p. 238. 407 Eschin. ut sup. 40s Lys. ut sup. p. 749. p. 758. 326 when the difficulty of procuring subsistence had increased, this rate was doubled. The time at which this increase took place may be nearly ascertained from the gramma- rians. Harpocration 409 states" that the infirm or impotent (ådúvator) received two oboli a day, as some say, or one obolus, as Aristotle in the constitution of Athens states; but as Philochorus says, nine drachmas every month." Suidas gives the same account from Philochorus 410; Hesychius mentions two oboli without any farther limitation. In Suidas and other Lexicons 411, it is stated that some re- ceived one, and others two oboli; but Bast has proved that the reading in Suidas is erroneous; and according to the true reading the grammarian says that some writers mention that they received one, and others two; it is evident therefore that the error should be corrected in the same manner in the other Lexicons. We see from these passages that Aristotle as well as Lysias spoke only of one obolus 412: and we may thence infer that up 409 In v. adúvato, where the right reading is preserved in the Paris MS. in Bast's Epist. Crit. p. 176. duo ßoλoùs Tйs nμégas of μέν φασιν ἑκάστης. 110 In v. åðívato, comp. Zonaras in v. adúvaro. The Lexicon in the Bibl. Coisl. p. 603. falsely charges Philochorus with saying that they received five oboli a day; but there is an error of the copyist, viz. ' instead of evvéa deaxuas, as Alberti has shewn by the comparison and correction of Bibl. Coisl. p. 238. 411 Suid. in v. åðívato, Zonaras, and the Lexicon in Bibl. Coisl. p. 238. In Suidas it should be written oi μév Qaoiv ixdorUS μέν φασιν ἑκάστης ἡμέρας ὀβολοὺς δύο, οἱ δὲ ὀβολόν. See Bast's Epist. Crit. p. 176. 412 For although the Lexicon in Bibl. Coisl. p. 603. represents Aristotle to have said that they received two oboli, without making any mention of one, this is an evident error, which is not worth the trouble of refutation. 327 to the time of the latter this bounty was not greater; it must therefore have been subsequently raised, perhaps, between the times of Aristotle and Philochorus, who was a youth when Eratosthenes was an old man. For the state- ment of Philochorus is the same in substance with the other account, that they received two oboli a day; which for the month of twenty-nine days gives nine drachmas four oboli; the latter the grammarians omit. Philochorus's computation by months proves of itself that he is speaking of later times, when the Prytaneias coincided with the months; it does not however follow from this that the increase did not take place before the introduction of the twelve tribes. If we could now ascertain how many upon an average were in need of this bounty, an estimate of the expence might be made; but the assumption of Meursius that they amounted to five hundred, is founded upon a false reading in Suidas 413. Considering however the necessitous condition of most of the Athenian citizens, and the frequency of wars, five hundred may be assumed as the lowest number of the old, blind, lame, sick and maimed, who were to be maintained; and the expence of their maintenance, according as we reckon it at one or two oboli a head, may be at the lowest estimated at five or ten talents. To this must be added the support of the orphan children, whose fathers had perished in war; for whose instruction also the State provided until their eighteenth year, in order that their education might be completed before they were sent forth into society 414. That the 413 Meurs. Lect. Att. VI. 5. The passage in Suidas which others thought that they had corrected, was first ingeniously emended by Bast Epist. Crit. p. 176. ¹¹¹ Comp. Petit Leg. Att. VIII. 3. 6. 12 328 number of orphans after so many wars was considerable, might have been assumed without the authority of Iso- crates 415. The support which private individuals pro- cured by means of a particular agreement which they made by entering into a society (pavos) differed from public maintenance 416. The society itself and the money sub- scribed were each called Eranos, the members Eranistæ, their whole number, the company of the Eranista (Tò xowòv Tŵv égaviot☎v), and their president an Eranarch. Their objects were of the most various description; if some friends wanted to provide a dinner, or a corporation to celebrate a solemnity, to give a banquet, or forward any particular purpose by bribery 417, the expence was defrayed by an Eranos. Associations of this kind were very common in the democratic States of Greece, and to this class the numberless political and religious societies, corporations, unions for commerce and shipping, belonged: many of them, more particularly the religious associations (@íaσoi), were possessed of real property 418, and like States and subordinate corporations they had power to make decrees, which they recorded upon stone 419; and lastly, there 415 Συμμαχ. 29. 416 I only mention this subject in a few words: several early writers have treated on it at full length, who mutually correct one other, of which the chief are, Petit Leg. Att. V. 7. 1. Sal- masius de Usuris chap. 3. Defens. Misc. chap. 1 sqq. Herald. Observ. chap. 43. Animadv. in Salmas. Observ. ad I. A. et Rom. VI. 1-8. An account more suited to common readers but not without some errors may be seen in Birger Thorlacius' populäre Aufsätze das Gr. Röm. und Nord. Alterth. betreffend. German transl. p. 71 sqq. 417 Demosth. pro Corona p. 329. 15. 418 Pseud-Aristot. Econ. II. 2. 3. 419 See for example Chandl. Inscript. II. 22, 127. 329 were laws concerning these companies (gavxoì vóμoi), and law-suits called after their name (gavixal díxaı), in which, as well as in the commercial causes, a more rapid course of justice was prescribed 420, Another kind of Eranos is that which was made for the support of the destitute citizens; it was founded upon the principle of mutual assistance, and it was expected that the members who had been relieved should pay the money back again when they had raised themselves to better circum- stances 421. (18.) A small expence was occasioned by one part of the public allowances and rewards. Under this head may be mentioned the public entertainments (σίτησις ἐν πρυτανείῳ), which many others, besides the fifty Prytanes and certain inferior officers, received as a mark of distinction, and which must have cost two or three talents a year. The donation of the golden crown (orépavos) was by no means a rare occurrence; the Senate of Five-hundred, if it per- formed its duties honestly, was presented with a crown every year 422; nations gave crowns to one another, and private individuals were frequently crowned by the State: how great was the weight of these golden crowns has been already shewn 423. In ancient times however they were not frequently given; those who after the Anarchy brought back the people from Phyle to Athens, only received chaplets of leaves; the value of which at that time was greater than of golden crowns in the age of Demosthenes 424, 420 See book I. 9. Pollux VIII. 144. 421 Isæus de Hagn. Hered. p. 294. Theophrast. Char. 17. 422 Dem. in Androt. cf. Æschin. in Timarch. p. 130. 193 Book I. 5. ༥༠༢ 424 Esch. in Ctesiph. p. 570 sqq. and particularly p. 577. 330 The erection of a metal statue (ɛixwv) to a person who had deserved well of the State, was in early times still more unfrequent; after Solon, Harmodius, and Aristogiton, this honour was first conferred upon Conon, as having liberated his country from the intolerable yoke of the Spartans 425. But in later times this reward ceased to confer any distinc- tion; Chabrias, Iphicrates, and Timotheus received crowns in honour of their services, as well as others, although their deeds were not thought worthy to be recounted 426. But in that age trifling or even negative services were highly celebrated, and in the time of Demetrius Phalereus this practice was carried to such a pitch, that in one year they erected to him three hundred and sixty statues, in chariots, on horseback, and on foot 427. This frivolous ex- penditure partly owed its origin to the Theoricon, by which the Demagogues had made the people indolent, and had in- duced them to flatter their corruptors 428; and partly resulted from the general decline of the State and of morals, and the loss of that simplicity and honesty, which disdaining 1 425 Demosth. in Lept. p. 478. 426 Esch. in Ctesiph. p. 635. See the oration Tigì cuvτážews περὶ συντάξεως p. 172. 427 Diog. Laert. V. 75. and the passages there quoted by Menage. 428 Comp. Nepos Miltiad. Of these and of other marks of honour the learned K. E. Köhler has treated at full length in his excellent dissertation of which the title is Etwas zur Beant- wortung der Frage, gab es bei den Alten Belohnungen des Verdienstes um den Staat, welche dem Ritterorden neuerer Zeit ähnlich waren, third book, in the Dörptische Beiträge for 1814, first and second half; which dissertation I have not been able to make use of, as I did not meet with it till after the completion of this work. 331 outward splendour; finds a sufficient reward in the exercise. of virtues. Athens from her republican constitution, which would always have prevented this corruption from attaining its utmost height, only displays a feeble shadow of what in monarchies or despotisms, in which the moral state of the people and the government is at a low ebb, appears to excess. Then are the citizens, both for the State and for themselves, covetous of titles and rank, as may be seen remarkably in the eastern and western Roman empire: titles of every description were created and lavishly dis- tributed; regulations concerning rank, and the splendour of the oriental courts, were introduced into the west; out- ward show and pageantry, which render the mind vain and slavish, became the substitutes for intrinsic excellence; and as no claims could be advanced on the ground of personal merit, all consideration was derived from the favour of the ruling power. On particular occasions pecuniary rewards were bestowed at Athens. After the return of the people from the Piraeus, those who at Phyle had undertaken the restoration of the democracy, received a thousand drachmas for sacrifices and sacred offerings, which however did not amount to ten drachmas apiece 429. According to Isocrates 10,000 drachmas were given to Pindar for his splendid praise of the Athenians, for which the Thebans had sub- jected him to a fine; according to others the reward given was the double of the fine which he had been condemned to pay 430. Aristides received in honour of his father, 429 Eschin. in Ctesiph. p. 575. 430 Isocrat. de Antidosi p. 87. ed. Orell. The other account is given by the author of the Fourth epistle of Æschines p. 669. Tzetzes and others state that the fine itself was only a thousand drachmas. See the fragments of Pindar p. 74. Heyn. Schneider's 332 upon the proposal of Alcibiades, a hundred minas of silver, a hundred plethra of wooded land, and as much unplanted land in the island of Euboea, and in addition four drach- mas a day a day 431, a most absurd expence for an insig- nificant and worthless individual. With better reason they gave 3000 drachmas to the two daughters of this distinguished man, and to the daughter of Lysimachus the privilege of being maintained in the Prytaneum, like the victors at the Olympic contest; and other donations in money were granted to the successors of Aristides down to the time of Demetrius Phalereus 432. These single exam- ples, to which many others might have been added, prove that the Athenian people were not illiberal in bestowing pensions. Lastly, rewards for the discovery of offenders (unvuτga) deserve to be mentioned; thus in Andocides 433, two rewards of this kind occur, one of 10,000 and another of a thousand drachmas, which were both actually paid. (19.) Although the most opulent citizens equipped them- selves at their own expence, there is no doubt that the Athenian State was under the necessity of providing a store of arms, as well in time of war as during peace, that in case of need it might be possible to arm not only such citizens as from poverty could not provide for themselves, but the resident aliens, and even the slaves. That such was the practice is rendered highly probable, by the circum- Life of Pindar p. 39. and the Life of Pindar which he has published before the Theriaca of Nicander. 431 Dem. in Lept. 95. and Wolf's note. 132 Plutarch. Aristid. 27. an obscure passage, the interpreta- tion of it however would lead me too far. 433 De Myst. p. 14. Of the nature of rewards were the prices which were set upon the heads of offenders. Cf. Aristoph. Av. 1072 sqq. 333 stance that large sums were expended upon naval prepa- rations in time of peace. In the Piraeus was the marine storehouse, which contained sails, ropes, leather-bags for provisions, oars, and other articles for the equipment of vessels; and the building of ships of war was carried on unceasingly both in peace and war. Themistocles passed a law that twenty new triremes should be built every year: Diodorus 434 indeed relates this event under Olymp. 75. 4. but it is probable that he, like many other historians, has on this occasion confounded together institutions of different periods, in order to introduce the circumstances which in the narration immediately follow; and Themistocles had perhaps in fact carried the law at a much earlier period, viz. when he obtained the decree which directed the money derived from the mines to be applied to the building of ships for the Æginetan war 435. We are not informed whether subsequently the same number of ships was built every year; but we cannot well suppose that they provided a less number; for the triremes would be falling into decay, and there were generally three or four hundred in existence. The Senate of Five-hundred had to superintend the building of the triremes 436; if this was not done, the customary crown was denied them; the personal superintendence was dele- gated to commissioners called the builders of the triremes. In the time of Demosthenes the building was stopped for 434 Diod. XI. 43. 435 See my dissertation upon the silver-mines of Laurion in the Memoirs of the Berlin Academy. 436 Demosth. in Androt. p. 598. 20 sqq. where there is also the account of the paymaster who ran away. The following story of Demetrius is given by Diod. XX. 46. Plutarch. Demetr. 10. 334 a year, the treasurer of the trireme-builders having eloped with two and a half talents: from the smallness of this sum it would be natural to conclude that not many triremes were building at the time; but as it is probable that the timber and other necessaries had been previously laid up in store, the stolen money may have been applicable only to the payment of the labourers: even this sum too may have been destined only to some particular portion of the labour; and therefore it would not be safe to infer from this fact that less than twenty triremes were built every year. After the time of Alexander the building nearly ceased, as the supply of timber from Macedonia then failed. Deme- trius Poliorcetes in Olymp. 118. 2. promised the Athenians timber for a hundred triremes, a proof that there was a scarcity of it at Athens. Another part of the military force for which Athens incurred some expence in time of peace, was the Cavalry, which was maintained partly on account of the sumptuous appearance which from the beauty of the riders and horses and the magnificence of their trappings it produced at processions; and partly because the Athenians were well aware that if both men and horses had not gone through previous training, they were unserviceable in war. The particular superintendence of this body belonged to the Senate of Five-hundred, who also examined the horses and riders 437; the rich were bound by law to serve in it. The pay of the cavalry in time of peace was called Cata- stasis 438, by which name the examination of the horsemen 437 Xenoph. de re Equestri 1. 8. Econ. 9. 15. and in the Hipparchus. Also Lycurgus ap. Harpocrat, in v. dexquarteis. δοκιμασθείς. 458 Lys. pro Mantith. p. 574. Harpoc. Suid. Phot. in v. xatástaσis, Lex. Seg. p. 270. Reiske's error in his note upon 335 made by the senate is also stated to have been called; probably because the distribution of the pay and the examinations were connected with one another; it was however a regular pay, and not an extraordinary donative, as Reiske supposed. In the speech of Lysias for Man- titheus it is mentioned, that the horsemen who had served during the Anarchy, were compelled after the restoration of the democracy to refund the money which they had received during that time: hence the grammarians by a false generalization of a particular case have inferred, that if the State dismissed the cavalry and appointed others, it required them to refund their pay to the Phylarchs 439. But the public would probably have preferred giving none at all. The truth is that this measure was effected by a special decree, and only on that single occasion, as the knights had been the chief attendants of the thirty tyrants, and had incurred the public hatred to such a degree, that to have been a knight under the thirty tyrants was reckoned a disgrace. The expence of the cavalry in time of peace amounted, according to Xenophon 440, to forty talents; which agrees with the Choiseul Inscription, in which it is stated that there were paid out of the public treasure in four Prytaneias, 16 talents 2148 drachmas 3 oboli, viz. in the first, three talents 3328 drachmas 34 oboli, in the third five talents 4820 drachmas, in the fourth three talents, in the seventh four talents; the rest of the pay appears to have been defrayed out of the current revenue. The object of these payments was to supply the provender Lysias had been already corrected by Larcher Mem. de l'Acad. des Inscript. tom. XLVIII. p. 92. 459 Properly it was collected by the Demarchs. vid. ad In- script. 80. 140 Hipparch. 1. 19. I 336 of the horses; Ulpian expressly says that pay was given for the keep of the horses 441, and in the above-mentioned inscription this money is accounted for under the name of provender for the horses (σitos inπois). The amount which each person received out of this grant has been dif- ferently determined by modern writers, according as they assumed a thousand or twelve hundred as the number of knights at Athens 442. In the latter case it has been calculated that they received sixteen drachmas a month or two oboli a day, in the former twenty drachmas a month or about four oboli a day. Both estimates appear to be too low; for even the sailors who were paid in time of peace received four oboli a day, while the knights were not only obliged to keep a servant, but also two horses. The provision of a horseman in war cost the Athenians a drachma a day 443. Doubtless the same sum was allowed in peace, and the only difference was, that in war they received provision-money in addition to their pay. This view is confirmed by the fact that the Catastasis (which was in truth nothing more than the knights' allowance for provision in time of peace, and which they were forced after the Anarchy to refund) amounted to a drachma. I state this however solely upon the authority of an in- scription, with respect to which I entertain no doubt that it refers to and establishes this fact. It thus appears to me probable, that the whole cavalry did not receive pay in time of peace, but only about six hundred; and for a long time Athens had not more than this number. Now the p. 341 Ad Demosth. in Timocrat. p. 460. 442 Petit Leg. Att. VIII. 1. 2. Barthél. Anachars. T. II. 184. Larcher ut sup. p. 92. 413 See Book II. 22. 337 pay of these, reckoning the year at 360 days, as Xenophon does in another place, would exactly amount to thirty-six talents for that time. Xenophon too only says that the State paid annually to the cavalry nearly forty talents; nor can the payments made out of the public treasure, according to the above-quoted Inscription (which are moreover unequal in different Prytaneias) be adduced against my hypothesis, for they were contributions which might in part have been paid for arrears of preceding Prytaneias. Lastly, Barthélemy 444 asserts that the Knights frequently kept their own horses, an error into which he is led by referring to the public cavalry a passage which relates only to those citizens, who expended money upon horses either from fondness of the animal, or in order to contend for the prize at the public games. (20.) These expences when taken together, if the lowest estimate be made of each item, did not amount annually to less than 400 talents; to these however if great works of building, extraordinary distributions of money, and large sums for festivals were added, the State might have easily consumed 1000 talents in a year, even without carrying on war, the expences of which are unlimited. Four hundred talents, which are equal to about £96,666, were in ancient times at least worth three times as much as at the present day, if the value of the precious metals is compared with that of the common necessaries of life; with this view then we may consider that the former sum is equal to triple its amount, or in the currency of modern times to about £290,000; which is in fair proportion to a population of 500,000 souls, or indeed if we consider the 444 Mém. de l'Acad. des Inscriptions tom. XLVIII. p. 351. referring to Lycurg, in Leocrat. VOL. I. Z 338 high rate of interest, low in comparison with the incomes of the inhabitants. If however in consequence of war or some particular extravagance the amount was increased (an event which was unquestionably of no unfrequent occurrence) to 1000 talents or more, and as the citizens were at such a period (as indeed at all others) forced to serve the Liturgies required by law, the expence was evidently incommensurate with the means of the State, and could not be well defrayed without oppressing the more wealthy classes by property-taxes, and without the help of tributary allies. Now war, it is certain, produced un- usually large and inevitable expences. At the present day indeed the equipment of armies costs the State immense sums of money; an expence from which the Greeks were very nearly exempt; for every citizen carried with him clothes and arms into the field, which indeed may be considered as a tax levied in another form; the mercenaries also came completely armed; sometimes perhaps it happened that poor citizens, foreign settlers, or slaves, were sent into the field, and assistance on the part of the State was necessary; a point however on which we have no accurate information. Another considerable expence in modern warfare is caused by artillery and ammunition; but as in ancient days the heavier engines of war were on account of their helplessness seldom brought into the field; they in general only had to provide them upon the occasion of a siege or of the defence of fortified places: the quantity of light darts or jave- lins used was inconsiderable. The equipment of fleets, which was necessary for Maritime Warfare, created a separate branch of expenditure; for which it was altogether impossible that such effectual provision could have been made during peace as to leave nothing to be provided at the breaking out of war. Lastly, the infantry and cavalry, 339 together with the persons attending upon them, and the crews of the different ships, were to be supplied with pay and provisions: and if the total expence of providing for these services should appear to be less than would be neces- sary in the times in which we live, it must be remembered that although the Grecians maintained no standing army, and the funds for the pay and provision of their troops were required only for a short time, yet on the other hand the soldiers were not only better paid, and also that during the most flourishing periods of the history of Athens war was almost incessant. In order to enable the reader to take a ge- neral survey of these subjects, I will treat of them separately, after having in the first instance acquired some general know- ledge of the magnitude of the military force of Athens. (21.) Although the numbers of which the armies con- sisted were in the ancient times of Greece very different according to circumstances and the necessities of the oc- casion, and although to state any one precise number of men is no more possible than in the case of any European nation, yet it can be safely asserted that no modern State, even in the latest times in which armies have been sent into the field, maintained so large a regular force in proportion to its population as was supported by Athens. And it is equally true that her military force was not only on a par with that of all the other States of Greece, but, with the ex- ception of Sparta, it was superior to them. What Demos- thenes 445 says of Athens at the period at which he is speak- ing, that of all the Grecian States it had the most nume- rous naval force, heavy-armed infantry, and cavalry, and the greatest quantity of money, must have held good in a higher degree when the strength of Athens had not been H 445 Philipp. I. p. 51. 20. 340 CON broken, excepting that Sparta could send into the field a larger number of land-forces. Upon the irruptions into Attica at the beginning of the Peloponnesian war, the Pelo- ponnesian and Boeotian forces, which were then enumerated, amounted in heavy-armed soldiers alone to 60,000 men 446, and consequently the whole army was more than double this number. We meet indeed with far more numerous armies in the Grecian States of Sicily and Italy. According to Diodorus 300,000 Sybarites contended with 100,000 in- habitants of Crotona; Philistus stated the military force of Dionysius at 100,000 foot, 10,000 horse, and 400 ships of war, which required an equipment of 80,000 men. The first is an evident exaggeration, greater even than modern newspapers are accustomed to make; whether the latter is possible, I leave to others to decide. Hume 447 has already exposed the exaggerations in numbers com- mitted by the ancients, and on the whole not without success, although he may have erred in particular points. It is not enough to know that Athens had about 20,000 citizens who were bound to serve in war were we to estimate its military strength merely from this datum, we should form a very incorrect judgment. The safest way to arrive at a satisfactory result is, without pretending to a complete enumeration, to collect the principal accounts of the land and sea forces at the different periods. First, it is needless to speak of the Trojan war, at which the Athe- nians appeared with fifty, or, according to another report, with sixty ships 448: a somewhat more certain account may 446 Plutarch. Pericl. 33. 447 Essay upon the Populousness of Ancient Nations, vol. II. p. 230. Lond. 1760. 448 Il. B. 556. Eurip. Iphig. Aul. 247. Cf. Græc. Tragoed. Princip. p. 238. • 341 however be given of the times of Solon. Before the consti- tution of Cleisthenes, Athens had twelve Phratrias, and in each of them four Naucrarias or Naucarias, which, as pub- lic corporations, were originally the same that the boroughs were afterwards; they must indeed have been in existence before the time of Solon, as the presidents of the Naucrari (πρυτάνεις τῶν ναυκράζων) are mentioned before the period of his legislation 449, and probably all that Aristotle 450 means when he ascribes their institution to Solon is, that the existence of their office was confirmed by that lawgiver. Now each Naucraria furnished two horsemen, amounting altogether to ninety-six, and one vessel, making therefore in all forty-eight; and the whole military system, in respect to defraying the expences, was doubtless regu- lated according to Naucrarias 451. When Cleisthenes afterwards introduced the boroughs, the Naucrarias were still retained, probably with a financial and military view; but he so far altered their constitution, that he created fifty Naucrarias, five in each tribe 452, and con- sequently they now furnished a hundred horsemen and fifty ships. This is perfectly consonant with the fact mentioned by Herodotus 453, that the Athenians in the war against the Æginetans anterior to the Persian wars, 449 Herod. V. 71. Instead of these Thucydides (I. 126.) mentions the nine Archons, who probably were at the head of the Prytaneias. 150 Ap. Phot. in v. ravxgagia. ναυκραρία. 451 Poll. VIII. 108. from which passage Zeun. ad Xenoph. Hipparch. 9. 3. has drawn some false conclusions, Hesych. in v. vauxλagos, Phot. ut sup. Schol. Aristoph. Nub. 37. Ammon. in V. vauxλngo, Harpocrat. and Suidas in v. vavxgagia. 452 Cleidemus ap. Phot. ut sup. 453 VI. 89. 342 could only send out fifty ships of their own, and were compelled to receive twenty ships from the Corinthians in order to increase their force; and we may observe that in this case triremes and not smaller vessels are meant, as is proved by their connexion with the Corinthian ships, the Corinthians being the first who had triremes. Now Mil- ¦ tiades after the battle of Marathon undertook the expedi- tion against Paros with seventy ships 454. But it was precisely at this time that Themistocles increased the naval force, and brought it to the height at which we find it in the Persian war after the battles of Artemisium and Salamis. In the former action 271 triremes were engaged, among which there were 127 belonging to Athens, which were in part manned with Platæans, they having no ships of their own: besides these the Athenians gave twenty to the Chalcideans 455. To these were added fifty-three other Athenian vessels, so that Athens num- bered two hundred vessels among those engaged at Salamis, although the whole Grecian fleet present at that battle only amounted to 378 triremes 456. Demosthenes in the oration for the Crown 457 agrees exactly with these state- 1 454 Herod. VI. 132. 455 Herod. VIII. 1. Herodotus in this and in nearly every place where he speaks of ships of war, means triremes, as is shewn by their being opposed to Penteconters. Comp. also VIII. 42-48. 456 Herod. VIII. 14. 42--48. If however all the separate numbers are added together, the sum is only 366; something therefore must have been lost in the text, as others have already remarked. Concerning the 200 triremes, or 180 without the Chal- cidean, compare also Herod. VII. 144. VIII. 61. Plutarch. The- mistocl. II. 14. The more ambiguous passages of Isocrates (Paneg. p. 79, 82, ed. Hall.) I pass over. 457 P. 306. 21. 343 ments of Herodotus, as far as the Athenians are concerned; for out of 300 Grecian he reckons 200 Athenian triremes: how it came to pass that in the speech upon the Sym- moriæ 458 only 100 Athenian vessels are mentioned among 300 Grecian, I am unable to explain: this circumstance might indeed lead one to suspect that this oration is spurious, if there was not such strong internal evidence in favour of its authenticity. We may farther observe that the manning of 180 triremes required 36,000 men, of whom only a few were Platæans; but as the Athenians had at that time wholly deserted their country, it would not have been difficult to man that number of triremes solely with citizens, and aliens, taking both old and young, even without slaves; land-forces, as such, were for the moment not in existence. And how numerous these were, we learn from the battles of Marathon and Platææ. In the first of these 10,000 Athenians were engaged, including of course none but Hoplita; we cannot suppose that in those times there were any slaves among the regular forces; and al- though Pausanias 459 asserts that slaves fought for the first time in the former battle, it may be inferred from his words that they were in the ranks of the Platæans; so that as far as Athens is concerned, his testimony does not apply. Athens could not then have raised a larger number of troops, otherwise it would have done so at the times of the greatest necessity for probably only the three superior classes were Hoplita, and the Thetes were light-armed; subsequently the Thetes were employed as Hoplitæ, although this is pointed out as an uncommon event -- 458 P. 186. 5. 459 I. 32. 3. They appear to have been runaway Boeotian slaves, who lived at Platææ. 344 in the times of the Peloponnesian war 460. The Athenians had not any bowmen or cavalry in this battle461; even the small number of horsemen, which must have been in exist- ence according to the former regulations, were not at their post, and the whole order of Knights was at that time no more than a name. Attica, from the nature of the country, was little suited for cavalry 462; and as this species of mi- litary is powerful among undisciplined masses of infantry, the aristocracy or oligarchy in ancient days was generally composed of horsemen, a form of government which the Athenians of all the Grecian States were most averse to. Boeotia, Phocis, Locris 463, and Thessaly, were the highlands, in which the cavalry was most numerous: even the Pisistratidæ had 1000 Thessalian horsemen, which a Thessalian prince had sent to support them against the Spartans 464, and according to an ancient alliance, the Thessalian cavalry came to the assistance of the Athenians before and during the Peloponnesian war 465. At Platææ the heavy-armed infantry of the Greeks amounted to 38,700 men, together with 69,500 light-armed troops, besides 1800 light-armed Thespians: among them there were 5000 Spartans, with 35,000 light-armed Helots and 5000 Lacedæmonian Hoplitæ, with 5000 light-armed troops; the Athenians had only 8000 Hoplita, together with the same number of light-armed troops, for Hero- dotus expressly reckons upon an average one light-armed man to each Hoplites, with the exception only of the 460 Cf. Harpocrat. in v. Tes. Thucyd. VI. 43. 461 Herod. VI. 112. 462 Herod. IX. 13. 465 Thue. II. 9. 464 Herod. V. 63. 365 Thục. I. 102, 107. II. 22. 345 Spartans, of whom each one had seven with him 466. The allied Grecian army appears not to have had any cavalry, as the equestrian nations were on the side of the Persians; but the Athenians at this battle had bowmen for the first time on land 467, who were doubtless citizens belonging to the light-armed troops, and of the class of Thetes; by sea more than 700 bowmen had already been employed at the battle of Salamis. The Athenians would without doubt have had more troops for the battle of Platææ, if they had not at the same time been compelled to furnish crews for the fleet which was engaged at Mycale, and consisted, according to Herodotus, of 110, according to Diodorus, of 250 triremes, under the command of Leoty- chides, and on the side of the Athenians Xanthippus 468. In the next age the Athenian force remained nearly the same: Cimon commanded 200 Athenian and 100 allied triremes, according to one account, but, according to the more credible statement of Thucydides, both taken toge- ther amounted to 200 triremes: by land they were not stronger than before. In the battle of Tanagra (Olymp. 80. 3.) the whole Athenian land-forces were present, ex- cepting what were at that time in Egypt; 1000 Argives were on their side, together with other allies, and yet 466 Herod. IX. 28 sqq. cf. 61. In the number of the light- armed troops Herodotus reckons 800 more than results from his own data: this difficulty cannot be solved. I pass over the accounts of Diodorus and Pausanias, which cannot have much weight. Plutarch (Aristid. 11.) agrees in the number of the Athenian Hoplitæ. 467 Herod. IX. 60. cf. 22. Concerning the archers in the battle of Salamis see Plutarch. Themistocl. 14. 468 Herod. VIII. 131. Diod. XI. 34. 346 altogether they only made up 14,000 men 469, that is, exclusively of the ught-armed troops, which were usually not taken into the account. At the same time moreover there was a fleet of 50 ships cruising against the Spartans at sea, which likewise required 10,000 men. The Athe- nians however endeavoured at all times to improve and to increase both the land and sea forces. It is stated by Andocides, and also Æschines in a most obscure passage 470 (from which however, after the errors have been corrected, some truth may be extracted), that in thirteen years pre- ceding the Æginetan war (from the 77th to the 80th Olympiad) 100 new ships were added to the 200 which before existed; besides which they had formed a regiment of 300 horsemen, and had purchased the first Scythian bowmen, to the number of 300. During the armistice, which was shortly afterwards concluded with Sparta, in Olymp. 83. 3. and which was observed up to the time of the Peloponnesian war, the Athenians again made great exertions in the building of ships, so that in Olymp. 87. 2. they were enabled to decree that a hundred new tri- remes should be provided for particular purposes 471; the cavalry was also raised to 1200, and the same number of bowmen appointed 472. Also after the peace of Nicias (Olymp. 89. 3.) Eschines states that they procured The 300, or, according to Andocides, 400 triremes. estimate of Pericles at the breaking out of the Pelo- ponnesian war agrees sufficiently well with the principal 469 Thuc. I. 107. Diod. XI. 80. 470 Esch. de Fals. Leg. p. 334-337. taken from the begin- ning of Andocides de Pace. 471 See below chap. 23. It was this that floated in the mind of the orator. 472 See above chap. 11. 347 statements which have been here quoted 473. According to his account Athens had not at that time more than 3000 heavy-armed men fit for active service; besides these, 6000 of the oldest and youngest of the citizens, and as many of the resident aliens as were heavy-armed, were appointed to defend the fortifications of the city; to which must be added 1200 cavalry, including the mounted bowmen, 1600 bowmen who served on foot, and 300 triremes ready to put to sea; and, according to Xeno- phon 474, there were in the docks and on service altogether 400. Isocrates, with the amplification of an orator, gives the numbers at double the amount stated by all the other writers. If we reckon that 300 triremes were manned with 60,000 men, the sum total of the crews does not amount to less than 91,800 men, a number incredibly great for a popula- tion of 500,000 souls, four-fifths of which were slaves. It might indeed be said that Athens was not able to man 300 triremes, if all the Hoplita were deducted; but even if about 10,000 Hoplitæ are reckoned as included in the ships' companies, the number which remains is still very considerable. This fact may however be accounted for by the following considerations. The number of Hoplitæ is larger than we find in the accounts of earlier times, as 473 Thuc. II. 13. The inaccurate Diodorus (XII. 40.) dis- agrees in some points, and is not so explicit as Thucydides. 474 Cyr. Exped. VII. 1. 27. Isocrat. Panegyr. p. 85. With regard to the number 300 compare Aristoph. Acharn. 544. The places for the ships in the Piraeus were calculated for 400, as Strabo mentions in the ninth book, adding at the same time that the Athenians had sent out that number. Whether the 400 Trierarchs who were formerly appointed every year refer to this circumstance may be questioned. See book IV. 12. 348 persons of greater or less age were included, who only served on garrison-duty and not in the field; and it was farther increased by the addition of some resident aliens. All indeed were regularly armed; but the whole together was not essentially unlike the rising in mass of a popula- tion on the alarm of invasion; and it comprised every individual capable of bearing arms, from eighteen to sixty years of age. The resident aliens were originally, when armed as Hoplitæ, only used as garrison-soldiers; in later times they also served in campaigns, to which aliens not yet domiciliated were occasionally summoned 475, but they were prohibited from serving in the cavalry 476; nor could there have been many among the Hoplita; for several Athenian boroughs supplied a large number of these. Acharnæ (by which we are not to understand the little village of the charcoal-burners, as is generally supposed, but a more considerable town which was celebrated for the heroism of its ancient inhabitants) 477 alone supplied 3000 478; consequently a greater number of aliens could be spared for the fleet; for this class of persons was probably more numerous in Attica at the time of Pericles than in that of Demetrius Phalereus; and it is well known that they chiefly served in the fleet 479. In addition to these the State also took into its service the out-dwellers (oi 475 Thuc. IV. 90. 476 Xenoph. de Vectig. 2. 2. 5. Cf. Hipparch. 9. 6. That the : resident aliens frequently went into the field is also observed by Ammonius in v. iooreλns, and I have remarked various passages in different authors to the same purpose. 477 Pindar. Nem. II. 16. 478 Thuế. II. 20. 479 Thuc. I. 143. III. 16. Xenoph. de Rep. Ath. I. 12. De- mosth. Philipp. I. p. 50. 22. and others. + : 349 xwgis oixoũvtes) as they were called, by whom we must either understand with the grammarians, freedmen, or else persons, who, though still slaves, lived apart from their masters, and supported themselves by their own labour 480. If it is borne in mind that the Spartans brought their Helots with them into the field, that the Thessalian mounted Penesta were bondsmen, that a considerable number of slaves was always employed in war as at- tendants on the army, who were sometimes even manu- mitted 481, that slaves are said to have fought as early as at the battle of Marathon, and afterwards at Chæronea when the Athenians granted them their liberty 482, it can- not excite any surprise that a large proportion of the rowers were slaves. It is remarked as an unusual circum- stance that the seamen of the Paralos were all freemen 483. At the successful sea-fight of Arginusæ there were many slaves in the Athenian fleet 484; and it equally redounds to the honour of both parties, on the one hand that victory was chiefly owing to the slaves, and on the other that the Athenians immediately emancipated them, and made them Platæan citizens 485. This must have taken place at an 480 Demosth. ut sup. and Hier. Wolf's note, but more particu- larly Harpocrat. Suid. and Photius in v. Tous xwgis oixovvtas. Lex. Seg. p. 316. The author of the speech against Euergus and Mne- sibulus p. 1161. 15. says of a freedman xwgis xs. 91 481 See book I. 13. 482 Dio Chrysost. XV. 485 Thuc. VIII. 73. C 484 Xenoph. Hell. I. 6. 17. 485 Schol. Aristoph. Ran. 33. cf. 193. A clearer reference to it is made by Aristophanes himself, ibid. 706. This play was produced in the same year (Olymp. 93. 3.) in which the battle was fought, but later in the year, in the month Gamelion. Con- 350 S earlier period in the time of the Peloponnesian war; for according to Hellanicus, who could not have been alive at the time of this action, slaves who had been engaged in sea-fights were made Platæans 486. A large number of slaves was considered not as useful only, but as neces- sary to a State which possessed a naval force 487. The Athenians also employed foreign seamen who served for hire, and who remained as long only as they pleased, so that if the enemy offered better pay they immediately changed sides. Thus the Athenians were able to man far more ships than appears to have been possible if we merely judge from the numbers of the free population. It was only on some pressing emergency that citizens were em- ployed as rowers; excepting indeed in the sacred triremes, in which the rowers were generally Thetes; Knights indeed were so employed on rare occasions, and at times even Pen- tacosiomedimni. Lastly, they sometimes pressed sailors in the countries of the allies, and made compulsory levies of troops, as for instance before the battle of Arginusæ, G cerning the fact comp. also Schol. Aristoph. Nub. 6. Diodorus expresses himself inaccurately XIII. 97. 486 Schol. Aristoph. Ran. 706. τοὺς συνναυμαχήσαντας δούλους ῾Ελλάνικός φησιν ἐλευθερωθῆναι καὶ ἐγγραφέντας ὡς Πλαταιεῖς συμπολι Tevoba. Sturz (Fragment. Hellan. p. 119.) has wholly mis- understood this passage, as he was not aware that Platæans were a kind of Athenian citizens. The Plataan rights of citizen- ship were first introduced at Athens in Olymp. 88. I.; conse- quently this occurrence cannot be placed earlier, nor can it by any means be referred with Sturz to the battle of Salamis. [Hellanicus died in 411 B. C. the year in which the history of Thucydides breaks off; consequently he could not have alluded to the enfranchisement of the slaves after the battle of Arginusæ. See however Schol. Aristoph. Ran. 732.] 487 Xenoph. de Vectig. 4. 42. de Rep. Athen. I. 11. 351 and for the Sicilian expedition 488; and this even in the subject States, although they had long redeemed their obligation to serve in war, which arrangement the Athe- nians willingly concurred in, as they were rejoiced to see them thus deprived of the means of revolting 489. Upon the whole then it would be assuming too much, if we reckoned, according to the usual computation, a servant for each Hoplites over and above the ship's com- pany; there can be no doubt that we must consider those who served at sea in the capacity of rowers, as analogous to the servants who attended the heavy-armed soldiers by land. The cavalry was composed of the order of Knights, but as a military force it at first increased slowly; the numbers of one hundred and three hundred I have already quoted: afterwards, according to the Scholiast on Aristophanes and Suidas 490, the number amounted to 600, and last of all there were 1200 Knights at Athens, according to the statements of Thucydides and Eschines. The ratio of the cavalry to the infantry was among the Greeks as one to ten, and 1200 horsemen are consequently nearly in this ratio to 13,000 Hoplite; but were all the 1200 composed of Athenians, and of the order of Knights? That this order might have contained 1200 persons no one will 488 Xenoph. Hell. I. 6. 18. Thuc. VI. 43. 489 Thuc. I. 99. Plutarch. Cim. 11. This had been brought about by the management of Cimon himself. 490 Schol. Aristoph. Eq. 624. and thence Suidas in v. izzûç. Diod. XIII. 72. cannot be referred to this with safety, as there may be auxiliary troops among his 1200 Athenian cavalry, for instance Thessalians. The passage of Harpocration quoted by Zeune ad Xenoph. Hipparch. 9. 3. has nothing to do with this point. 352 deny; and even if it contained fewer, there might have been that number of horsemen, for probably there were many Pentacosiomedimni among them. But Aristophanes only reckons a thousand Knights 491, and this too in the comedy called by their name, which was produced in Olymp. 88. 4.; the same number was given by Philochorus in the fourth book of the Atthis 492, who did not however omit to mention that their number occasionally varied; Demosthenes states the very same number 493; and Xeno- phon proposes, in order to bring the cavalry more rapidly and easily to 1000 men, which he evidently considers as the usual number, that they should keep foreign horse- soldiers 494. Larcher 495 very properly rejects the suppo- sition of Petit 496, that the ancient writers had made use of 1000 as a round number, upon the ground that 1200 would have equally suited their purpose; and he sup- poses that the origin of the difference in the statements was, that from the beginning of the Peloponnesian war, until the date of the Knights of Aristophanes, they had been diminished about 200; which supposition appears to be untenable. My opinion coincides rather with Schneider's 497, that in the 1200 the mounted bowmen are included, as Thucydides expressly states; it is possible that besides these bowmen there were a thousand, viz. a hun- 491 Eq. 225. 492 Ap. Hesych. in v. iππйs. 493 De Symmor. p. 181. 17. 494 Hipparch. ut sup. 495 In his otherwise superficial Memoir on the Class of Knights in Greece, Mém. de l'Acad. des Inscript. tom. XLVIII. p. 92. 496 Leg. Att. VIII. 1. 2. 497 Ad Xenoph. Hipparch. ut sup. 353 dred from each tribe, who were Athenians, and armed in the Greek manner; while the 200 mounted bowmen were doubtless in the cavalry what the Scythians were in the infantry, i. e. light-armed. In this capacity they rode in front, even before the Hipparch 498; and in an oration attributed to Lysias it is considered degrading to an Athenian to serve in the cavalry among the bowmen 499. It is no objection to the above hypothesis, that Xeno- phon not only makes no mention of the existence of the foreign cavalry at Athens, but himself first proposes that such a body should be formed; for these bowmen, being light-armed soldiers, did not come into consideration when he was treating of the maintenance or improvement of the cavalry, which was composed of citizens. Thucydides mentions 1600 bowmen who served on foot, the orators only 1200; this difference also may probably be accounted for by the fact that the mercenary Scythian bowmen were at most 1200 500, but that the others were either citizens of the poorer classes, or resident aliens, who were light-armed, and chiefly trained in shooting. Bowmen occur in the battles of Salamis and Platææ, before any Scythians had been procured; and it may be distinctly seen from an inscription still extant, that a difference was made between foreign bowmen and those who were citizens (evixo) and άσTIXO): finally, the bowmen, who occur in two Athenian military lists 501, appear to have been citizens, especially 498 Xenoph. Socrat. Mem. III. 3. 1. 499 Lys. in Alcib. λuzetaž. II. p. 565. This passage is de- cisive, although the speech is probably not the work of Lysias, but of some other contemporary. 500 See book II. 11. i Inscript. 80. I. p. 119. ed. Boeckh. 501 In the well-known list of the killed, of the date of Olymp. VOL. I. А а 354 as in one immediately after the bowmen a new division begins with the superscription "foreigners" (évoi). The Athenians also had Cretan bowmen in pay for a time, as Thucydides and Pausanias mention. The accounts of the military force which was in action during the Peloponnesian war appear to coincide with the numbers here ascertained; and of this I will now adduce some examples. At the very beginning of the war Pericles sent 100 ships to the Peloponnese, to which 50 Corcyræan and other allied ships were added; at the same time 30 vessels were sent to Locris, and some must without doubt have been reserved for the defence of Attica itself 502. So again, in the second year of the war, while the enemy's troops were in the country, Pericles went to Epidaurus with 100 Athenian and 50 Lesbian and Chian triremes, having on board 4000 Hoplitæ and 300 horsemen. In the fourth year of the same war, the Lesbians having revolted, 40 triremes were sent against them; at the same time 30 were sent to the Peloponnese, and 30 others were equipped in order to protect Athens from invasion; these were manned with Athenians, who were however neither Knights nor Pentecosiomedimni, and with resident aliens 503. At the end of the summer 1000 Hoplita were sent to 80. . which has been edited by Spon, Maffei, Corsini, and others, in which indeed some names sound rather common and not of Athenian origin, but they may be the names of inferior persons admitted to the rights of citizenship from foreign coun- tries; and in another inscription which I have published in the Catalogue of the Winter Lectures of the University of Berlin, 1816, 1817, as well as Clarke in his Travels. The passage of Pausanias I. 29. 5. refers to the Cretan bowmen. 502 Thuc. II. 24 26. III. 3, 7, 16. 503 Thuc. II. 56. 355 Lesbos, who themselves rowed the ships thither 504, Thucydides remarks, that at that time the number of ships in use was very large, but that it was still greater at the beginning of the war, when Attica, Salamis, and Euboea, were guarded by 100 ships, 100 had been de- spatched to the Peloponnese, and 50 more to Potidæa and to other places, amounting altogether to 250; besides these there were 4600 Hoplita before the walls of Potidæa (only 1600 however for some time), and an equal number of attendants 505. Thus we find in this instance, in addi- tion to the land-forces that remained in Attica, a body of 60,000 men in service. In the expedition to Sicily the numbers were not inferior 506. Although the war was continued in Greece, the Athenians decreed that 60 ships should be sent to Sicily, under the command of Nicias and Alcibiades; but Nicias, rightly 'estimating the magnitude of the enterprize, saw that it would be necessary to have land-troops in addition to a powerful naval armament, and counselled them to send a large number of Hoplita, bow- men, and slingers, both of their own and of the allies, together with provision-ships and apparatus for baking. He disapproved however of the war altogether; but in consequence of his advice the People sent 60 swift-sailing triremes with 40 military transports, to which were also added 34 allied triremes and the provision-ships: the Hoplita were 5100 in number, of whom 700 were Thetes created for the occasion, and 1500 Athenians from the list of citizens; the others were mostly subject allies and a few mercenaries; also 480 bowmen, of whom 80 were Cretans, 304 Thuc. III. 18. 30s Thuc. III. 17. 506 Thục. VI. 8, 21, 22, 31 sqq., 43. 356 700 Rhodian slingers, 120 light-armed Megarian exiles, and 30 horsemen. If we reckon the crews of 134 triremes, each at 200 men, and the attendants of the Hoplite and cavalry, we find that they amounted to 38,560 men: 250 dismounted horse-soldiers followed at a later period, who were to have been mounted in Sicily, and also 30 mounted bowmen 507. And yet they were able at the same time to send 30 ships to the Peloponnese 508, and other small fleets were dispersed about in various places. Nor was this all; for ten ships were sent as a reinforcement under Eury- medon to Sicily, and twenty for the blockade of the Peloponnese; where soon afterwards thirty more were sent under the joint command of Charicles and De- mosthenes, with sixty Athenian and five Chian vessels, together with 1200 Hoplitæ from the list of the citizens, and others from the islands; the Thracian Peltasts, who arrived too late, were sent home again on account of the scarcity of pay; fresh troops however were received in different places; other ships were also provided, but some of them were again dismissed. When Demosthenes and Eu- rymedon arrived in Sicily they had 73 triremes, 5000 Hop- litæ, together with a number of Grecian and Barbarian ja- velineers, slingers, and bowmen 509. Now if we add together the whole number of men of all descriptions who went, after the departure of the first fleet, to Sicily, viz. cavalry, Hoplitæ, light-armed soldiers, and ships' crews, together with the servants of the cavalry and Hoplitæ, it gives 507 Thuc. VI. 94. cf. Plutarch. Alcib. 20. 508 Thục. VI. 105. 509 Thuc. VII. 16, 17, 20, 27, 42. Diodorus is less precise in his statements than Thucydides; but he agrees with him upon the whole. See XII. 84. XIII. 2, 7, 8, 9, 11. 357 about 26,000 men; so that the whole military force which was sent to Sicily amounted to about 65,000 men. In this moreover the Sicilian auxiliaries are not included, but only the Grecian and Italian. But in the decisive sea fight at Syracuse only 110 ships were engaged, and some of these were in very bad condition 510; 40,000 men sur- vived the battle, as Thucydides informs us 511; of whom many were destroyed by land, 8000 were put to death, 7000 made prisoners in a body; of the rest some were kept as slaves by the soldiers, and others sold 512. Diodorus there- fore makes Nicolaus underrate the number, when he states the Athenian forces in Sicily at more than 200 ships, and above 40,000 men513; he might have said above 60,000 men. This loss was the greatest that the Athenians had ever experienced; although nearly equal reverses had been sustained in earlier times. "In Egypt," says Isocrates 514, whose account of the defeats of Athens, although inaccu- rate, is very remarkable, " 200 triremes were lost, with all 510 Thuc. VII, 60. 511 Thục. VII. 75. 512 Diod. XIII. 20. 513 Diod. XIII. 21. Manso charges Diodorus with some false statement, and censures him for exaggerating: see his History of Sparta vol. II. p. 455. 514 Evµµax. 29. To what the loss of 10,000 Hoplita in the Pontus refers I am wholly ignorant; but hardly to the auxiliary troops of Cyrus, which had nothing to do with the Athenians. Ælian Hist. Var. V. 11. transcribes this passage of Isocrates, but purposely omits these 10,000 soldiers. The manner in which Isocrates counted the 240 ships has been shewn by Perizonius upon Elian. Cneius Piso justly observed that the population of Attica in later times was a conflux of vagabonds and rabble, Tacit. Annal. II. 55. 358 I their crew, 150 off Cyprus; and in the Pontus 10,000 Hoplite of the Athenians and the allies; in Sicily 40,000 men, and 240 triremes; and afterwards in the Hellespont 200 more: but as to the triremes which had been lost by tens and fives, and the men who had been destroyed by thousands and two thousands, who could enumerate them?" In consequence of these calamities, the Phratrias and the register of the Lexiarchs were filled with aliens, in order to replenish the number of the citizens; and the races of the most celebrated men and the noblest families, which had hitherto preserved an unbroken descent through in- ternal troubles and disturbances, and through the vicis- situdes of the Persian wars, were at length sacrificed to their struggles for dominion, and became extinct. Per- haps no country ever adopted so many strangers as Athens: hence that mixture of languages soon arose, which Xeno- phon complains of in his Essay upon the Athenian State; but whatever may have been the inconveniences resulting from this practice, no other means would have sufficed, after such great and repeated losses, to keep up the numbers of the citizens with regard indeed to the defeat in Sicily, many strangers were involved in it; the greater part of the citizens were at home: for as at that precise period, after Alcibiades had been recalled from Sicily, the Spartans occupied Decelea, and kept it constantly garrisoned, it was impossible to leave the city in a defenceless state. The fact of there having been only 5000 Hoplitæ admitted into a share of the government which was introduced in Olymp. 92. 1., immediately after the Sicilian expedition 515, may indeed in part have been occasioned by the misfortunes of war, but is chiefly to be accounted for from the circumstance that the Thetes are not comprised in this number; for by 515 Thuc. VIII. 97. 359 law they were prohibited from serving as Hoplite; and in this instance they would have been still more strictly excluded, as the registration was made in reference to an aristocratical constitution, in which the Hoplita were to compose the Public Assembly; for which reason many citizens, even who were not Thetes, were unquestionably debarred from a participation. The same holds good of the 3000 in the Anarchy 516, who were Hoplite; but it is impossible that persons of this description alone were admitted, and we may conclude that they were selected arbitrarily from among the citizens who remained at home. By these means Athens sustained herself in the years immediately following the Sicilian expedition; and, not- withstanding her unfavourable condition, defeated the Lacedæmonians off Abydos (Olymp. 92. 2.) with eighty- six ships517; and, soon afterwards, for the second time, off Cyzicus 518. Then Alcibiades appeared with 100, and afterwards Conon with 70 ships519; and this fleet being unsuccessful, the Athenians in Olymp. 93. 3. equipped 110 ships within thirty days, the crews of which were composed of all persons who were able to serve in war, both slaves and citizens; and there were even some Knights who went with them. To these were added ten Samian and more than thirty other allied vessels, and several which had been detached to different places were recalled; making altogether 150; while Conon retained seventy under his immediate command, of which thirty were lost 520. The crews of the ships that fought at 516 Xenoph. Hell. II. 3. 12, 13. 4. 2. 518 Xenoph. Hell. I. 1. 519 Xenoph. Hell. I. 5. 520 Xenoph. Hell. I. 6. 517 Thuc. VIII. 104. and Diod. XIII. under Olymp. 92. 2. Diod. XIII. under Olymp. 92. 2. Diod. under Olymp. 93. 1, 2. Diod. under Olymp. 93. 3. 360 Arginusæ alone amounted to more than 30,000 men; those of Conon's fleet to 14,000, and many persons capable of bearing arms must necessarily have remained at home. Lastly, in the battle of Egospotamos the Athenian force amounted to 180 triremes, which would require alone 36,000 men 521¸ 4 Even after the unfortunate termination of the Pelopon- nesian war, the Athenians soon recovered themselves, and in Olymp. 100. & were enabled to think of equipping, ac- cording to Polybius, a hundred ships and 10,000 Hoplitæ ; or according to Diodorus, 200 ships, 20,000 Hoplitæ, and 500 cavalry 522. The forces of Chares, Timotheus, Cha- brias, and Iphicrates were not inconsiderable, as we learn from the Historians; according to Isocrates the State pos- sessed 200 triremes even at a later period than this; Demosthenes in the 106th Olympiad reckons the naval force at 300 vessels which could be sent to sea on an emergency, together with 1000 horse-soldiers, and as large a number of Hoplitæ as might be wished 523; Ly- curgus provided the State with 400 triremes 524, and so completely filled the docks that they could not contain any more; the Athenians sent to the assistance of the Byzan- tines not less than 120 ships together with Hoplitæ and a supply of missiles 525; and before the battle of Chæronea, they decreed to send 200 ships to sea 526. At this time how- Sin 521 Xenoph. Hell. II. 1. 13. Diod. under Olymp. 93. 4. 522 Diod. XV. 29. Polyb. II. 62. Comp. Book IV. 4. 523 Isocrat. Areop. 1. Demosth. de Symmor. p. 181. 17. p. 183. 186.8. 15. p. 524 See Meurs. Fort. Att. VII. and more particularly the third decree after the Lives of the Ten Orators. 525 Decree of the Byzantians in Demosth. pro Corona, p. 256. 526 Decree in Demosth. pro Corona, p. 290. 361 ever the military force was in a continually declining state, as the citizens were unwilling to serve, and preferred carrying on war with mercenaries, while they were squan- dering away the public revenue in shows and banquets at home. It is undoubtedly true that mercenaries had been frequently employed in the Peloponnesian war, both in the fleet as rowers, and by land as heavy and light-armed troops; but it had not at that time become a principle, that the whole war should depend on the services of mercenaries. Isocrates 527 at the time of the Social war complains that his countrymen no longer exerted themselves; so far from it that they employed refugees, deserters, and other criminals, who would immediately turn their arms against Athens if any body offered them higher pay: this the Athenians did at a time when they were hardly able to defray the expences of the administration; whereas formerly when there was abundance of gold and silver in the Acro- polis, the citizens themselves served in war. It was a common practice to write down 10,000, 20,000 mercena- ries; but it was a force which existed only on paper, and nothing more than a decree to that effect went out with the general: they chose ten Generals, ten Taxiarchs, ten Phylarchs, and two Hipparchs; but with the excep- tion of one, they all remained at home, and together with the sacrificers, superintended the processions. Every general was two or three times put upon his trial for life or death, and when defeated with his mercenaries, was made the object of party accusations. In order to diminish this evil, Demosthenes counselled the Athenians that the fourth part of the standing army should be composed of citizens. In addition to this it often happened that the 527 Συμμαχ. 16. 362 foreign leader of the mercenaries was a general, the equipments of the army were never ready at the right time, and that the war was carried on upon unsound military principles 528. The greatest number of mercenaries which Athens collected at this time against Philip was, according to the statement of Demosthenes, 15,000 to- gether with 2000 cavalry, which were furnished by the Euboeans, Achæans, Corinthians, Thebans, Megarians, Leucadians, and Corcyræans, in addition to the other force composed of the citizens of these nations 529: others than these Athens was forced to maintain at her own expence. The total numerical amount of the land army must always be estimated at twice the number of men which is stated by ancient authors, when they merely mention Hoplitæ and cavalry. For each Hoplites had an attendant (ὑπηρέτης, σκευοφόρος) who carried his baggage and provi- sions, and also his shield; the horseman too had a servant who attended to his horse (iTπоxóμоs) 530. This regulation diminished the labour of the soldiers; but it must neces- sarily have produced a regular and continual system of depredation. That the armies were also attended by a large train of carriages and asses 531 and of suttlers does not require to be stated. 528 Demosth. Philipp. I. p. 45, 47, 53. 529 Demosth. pro Corona p. 306. And thence Plutarch, in his Life of Demosthenes 17. The statement in the first decree at the end of the Lives of the Ten Orators and in Æsch. in Ctesiph. p. 488. is lower. Cf. ibid. 536. Æschines states a less number, as he does not include the Theban mercenaries. 530 Thuc. III. 17. VII. 75, 78. Xenoph. Hell. II. 4. comp. Barthel. Anachar. vol. II. p. 145. 531 Xenoph. Econ. 84. and frequently in the Historians. 363 (22.) In ancient times the troops received no pay, excepting such foreign soldiers as engaged themselves in the service of a State; a practice which the Carians were the first to introduce, and which among the Greeks the Arcadians, who resembled the Swiss in such mercenary habits, were particularly prone to. Pericles first introduced the pay of the citizens who served as soldiers 532. The payment was made under two different names; one being the wages (μolòs) paid for actual service, which the soldiers when the cost of their arms and clothes had been deducted, were able to lay by; and secondly the allowance for pro- visions (σιτηρέσιον, σιτάρκεια, σῖτος), they being seldom furnished in kind. The soldiers being free citizens, it was thought that the State was bound to pay them highly, and that if freemen voluntarily undertook this hazardous service and discharged their duties at the risk of their lives, they were entitled at least to a maintenance: the generals and commanders were however proportionally ill paid, as their distance from the common soldiers was not so great as at the present day; the honour of their situa- tion was also considered as sufficient indemnification, and they had the chance of being remunerated by booty and contributions. The pay was generally given out in gold; by the Athenians probably for the most part in their own silver 533; the provision-money was also given at the same time, which for that reason has not always been properly distinguished by the ancient writers from the pay, and consequently it will be impossible for us always to ascertain 532 Ulpian ad Demosth. πgì cvvráž, p. 50. A. 533 That Athens sometimes paid in Cyzicenic staters, may be inferred from Demosth. in Mid. p. 570. (See however book I. note 84.) 364 the difference. The pay of an Hoplites never amounted to less than two oboli a day, and the provision-money to the same sum: which was still the common rate in the age of Demosthenes; since this orator reckons ten drach- mas a month for the provision-money of the Hoplita, and thirty drachmas for that of the cavalry, together con- sequently they amounted to four oboli a day for each Hoplites; the attendants were not always paid separately. The life of a soldier was proverbially called, on account of this rate of pay, the life of a Tetrobolon (TETgwßóλov Blog) 534. At the same time higher pay was frequently given. In the beginning of the Peloponnesian war, the Hoplita who besieged Potidæa received daily two drachmas a head, one for themselves, the other for their servants 535; in which instance the pay was doubtless rated at three oboli, and the provision at the same sum. In the Acharneans of Aristophanes 536 some Thracian soldiers are introduced demanding two drachmas for pay, including of course the provision-money: the Thracians who were sent back in the Sicilian war on account of a scarcity of money, were to have received a drachma each day 537; this was the rate of pay for every description of force in the Sicilian expedition. If here again we reckon one half for the pay, and the other for provision, each amounted to three oboli; and this was the sum which the bowmen at Athens, who composed the city-guard, received, and as they were 534 Eustath. ad Odyss. p. 1405. ad Il. p. 951. ed. Rom. A passage of the comic poet Theopompus, where he speaks of a payment of two oboli, can only be understood of the pay, without the provision. See book I. 22. 535 Thuc. III. 17. to which Pollux IV. 165. refers. 536 Vs. 158. The date of this play is Olymp. 88. 3. 57 Thục. VII. 27. 365 bondsmen it was probably not paid as wages, but provision- money 538. Cyrus the younger at first gave a daric a month to the Grecians in his service, and afterwards one and a half 539; the former pay would amount to twenty, the latter to thirty drachmas of silver, reckoning the ratio of gold to silver as one to ten, which is probably far too low for that age. Seuthes gave a Cyzicenic stater a month to the common soldiers, twice that sum to the Lochagi, and four times that sum to the generals 540: this same gold coin is also mentioned in other places as monthly pay 541; the double and fourfold scale for the commanders! was probably the established rate of payment; thus Thimbron offered the common soldiers a daric a month, and the commanders in the same proportion as Seuthes 542; sometimes indeed common mercenaries, if they particularly distinguished themselves, received from those who under- stood how to ingratiate themselves with them, two-fold, three-fold, and four-fold pay (διμοιρία, τζιμοιρία, τετρα- Morgía) 543. In these cases the provision-money is included, μοιρία) without its being particularly specified. After the defeat at Mantinea, the Spartans and their allies having decreed to raise an army, the allies were permitted to contribute money instead of troops, at the rate of three Æginetan oboli a day for each foot soldier, and four times this sum for the cavalry 544; now three Æginetan are five Athenian 538 Comp. above book II. 11. 539 Xenoph. Cyr. Exped. I. 3. 21. 540 Xenoph. ibid. VII. 3. 19. cf. VII. 6. 1. 541 Xenoph. ibid. V. 6. 12. 542 Xenoph. ibid. VII. 6. 1. 543 Xenoph. Hell. VI. 1. 4. Aquoigital is interpreted incorrectly in Lex. Seg. p. 242. 544 Xenoph. Hell. V. 2. 14. 366 t oboli, which were in this case evidently to be given for pay and provision together. In the time of the Peloponnesian war, the same sum was stipulated for provision alone. For in the alliance of the Athenians, Argives, Mantineans, and Eleans, it was fixed that the State affording assistance should provide the troops which they sent with necessaries for thirty days; and that if the troops remain longer, the State to whose assistance they came should give the in- fantry three Æginetan oboli a day, and the cavalry twice this sum, for provision (σītos) 545. It follows at the same time from these facts, that the cavalry were treated very differently from the infantry, as their pay or provision- money sometimes amounted to twice and even three or four times the pay received by the latter at Athens the three-fold scale was adopted; if the Hoplitæ received two oboli for provision-money, the horsemen received a drachma 546. This latter proportion existed among the Romans 547. : These examples shew that during the Peloponnesian war, the soldiers who served on land were the best paid; afterwards, and particularly in the time of Philip, less was given, as the multitude of adventurers and mercenaries had increased, and the wealthy citizens seldom served, who would have required a higher pay to have enabled them to live in a manner suitable to their habits. The pay of the naval forces was in like manner variable; although it does not appear to have fallen off in a degree at all corresponding to that of the land service; but it was first higher, then it became lower, and then something 545 Thucyd. V. 47. 546 Demosth. Philipp. I. p. 47. 647 Lipsius Milit. Rom. V. 16. 367 higher again. As the statements given are generally of the sum total of the pay of the whole ship's company, it will be necessary first to ascertain the numbers of the crew of a trireme. In the sea as well as in the land service a distinction was made between pay, and provision (σ- géσov) 548; in the sea service the latter was frequently given in money 549, and was supplied at the public ex- pence, although if it happened that the generals had no money, the Trierarchs perhaps would either contribute some part, or engage the whole number of seamen at their own cost 550. Demosthenes reckons twenty minas a month as the provision-money of a trireme 551; which, upon the supposition that the 200 men in a trireme were paid ac- cording to the same rate, or rather that 200 times the pay of a common sailor was required for the payment of the whole crew, would come to two oboli a head, the same sum that a common land-soldier was to receive according to the plan of Demosthenes. Now since the pay and pro- vision-money used to be equal, the common soldier received at that time four oboli for both, the sum paid to the Paralitæ as wages in time of peace 552. On the other hand, the Athenians in the beginning of the Pelo- ponnesian war gave the seamen as much as a drachma a day 553; which was the case afterwards in the expedition against Sicily; when the Trierarchs also made additional 548 Demosth. in Polycl. p. 1209. 12. 549 Orat. in Timoth. p. 1187.21. Demosth. in Polycl. p. 1223. 19. p. 1224. 1. 550 The latter for example in the case in Demosth. in Polycl. p. 1208. 15. 551 Philip. I. p. 47, 48. 352 Book II. 16. 335 Thuc. III. 17. 368 allowances to the Thranite, and to certain other persons employed in the ship, such as the steersman, &c.554 If at this rate of payment we reckon the crew at 200 men, the monthly pay amounted to a talent; according to which the Egestæans, for the purpose of promoting the war against Syracuse, sent sixty talents to Athens as monthly pay for sixty vessels 555. In general however the Athe- nians at that time only gave three oboli, which, it clearly appears, were both for the daily pay and provision of a sailor; if they gave a drachma, it was for the purpose of stimulating the exertions and augmenting the numbers of the men. Thus Tissaphernes promised to the seamen at Sparta an Attic drachma a day, and at first he kept his word (Olymp. 92. 1.), although afterwards at the instiga- tion of Alcibiades he refused to give more than three oboli, until the king had allowed the whole drachma, as even Athens only gave three oboli; in withholding which he was not influenced by want of money; but, in addition to other reasons, he feared lest the possession of so much more money than they wanted should produce insubordi- nation amongst the seamen, and lead them into dissolute habits, by which their bodies would be enfeebled. At the same time he consented, instead of three oboli a day for each man, to give three talents a month for five ships, i. e. for every ship 36 minas; if therefore we reckon 200 men to a trireme, eighteen drachmas a month or 3% oboli a day would be the pay of each man 556. In the agree- 554 Thuc. VI. 31. with the Scholiast. 555 Thục. VI. 8. 556 Thuc. VIII. 45, 29. The latter passage Palmerius and Duker have alone rightly understood: the note of the latter is the best worth consulting. It should evidently be written, ἐς γὰς πέντε ναῦς τρία τάλαντα ἐδίδου τοῦ μηνὸς, and the words 369 ment between Sparta and Persia the rate fixed had been only three oboli 557, and Tissaphernes gave the rest merely as a voluntary addition, and without the approval of the king. Again at a subsequent period, the Spartans de- manded a drachma of Cyrus the younger, and maintained their unreasonable claim by saying that the Athenian sailors would desert to their side, as they only received half as much in answer to which Cyrus appealed to the agreement, by which each ship was to receive only thirty minas a month, or three oboli for each man; however, Cyrus allowed himself to be prevailed on by their en- treaties to give to each sailor an additional obolus, after which they received four oboli a day 558. In this instance also 200 men are reckoned to the trireme. It may be far- ther observed that the seamen, when they were first engaged, received bounties and advances of money, that they gene- rally made considerable demands, and after all were with difficulty retained in the service. The travelling expences of those who went away either by land or water were frequently paid, and particularly by private indivi- duals 559. xai vτýzovτæ are an unintelligible addition from VIII. 26. The preceding sentence ὅμως δὲ παρὰ πέντε ναῦς πλέον ἀνδρὶ ἑκάστῳ ἢ τρεῖς ὀβολοὶ ὡμολογήθησαν contains the same sense, since παρὰ πέντε means, by every five ships, and the following sentence from xai τοῖς ἄλλοις down to ἐδίδοτο, shews the justness of this correction. 557 Concerning the agreement see Thuc. VIII. 5. That only three oboli was the sum fixed in it is evident from Xenoph. Hellen. 1. 5. 3. 558 Xenoph. Hell. 1. 5. 3, 4. 559 Demosth. in Polycl. p. 1208. 16. p. 1212. 9, 19. de Trie- rarch. Corona p. 1231. 10. Thuc. VI. 31. Lysias pro Mantitha p. 579. VOL. I. B b 370 : The foregoing statements relative to the pay of the sailors, concur throughout in the fact that there were 200 men to be paid in each trireme and in these accounts the marines or soldiers, as well as the sailors, must have been included, since otherwise a separate payment for them would have been somewhere mentioned; and they are evi- dently comprised among the ship's company, when the ancients speak of the pay of the seamen. But as a doubt has been raised whether a trireme did in fact contain so large a crew, it appears necessary to produce additional testimony in order to confirm our supposition. According to Herodotus, Cleinias, the son of Alcibiades, served in the battle of Salamis with a trireme of his own and 200 men 560. The same author 561 estimates the whole force of Xerxes, which consisted of 1207 ships, at 241,400 men, taking 200 for each as the regular number, inclusive of the marines that belonged to them; the 30 Epibata who were also on board, did not belong to the regular comple- ment, but were added to the full crew from the Persians, Medes, and Sacæ. Plato in the Critias 562 gives a sketch of a military force for the inhabitants of Atlantica accord- ing to the custom prevalent in his own time, excepting that he speaks of military chariots, which were but seldom used even in the times between the Persian and Pelopon- nesian wars. Of the 6000 lots into which he divides the country, each is to supply, besides a chariot and its driver, two Hoplita, two bowmen, two slingers, three light-armed 560 Herod. VIII. 17. 561 VII. 184. cf. 96. Duker ad Thucyd. VIII. 29. unjustly blames Meibomius (de Fabrica Triremium) for not including these thirty Epibatæ in the calculation. 562 P. 119. A sqq. 371 soldiers for throwing stones, and the same number for throw- ing javelins, and lastly four seamen for the manning (πλý- gwμa) of 200 ships, which gives 200 apiece. There is how- ever one statement which does not agree with this number. In the Lexicon Rhetoricum 563 the complement of a Pente- conter is stated at 50 men, or one Lochus, and the trireme at 300 men, or six Lochi. It is possible that the rowers of the triremes were distributed into six Lochi, each row upon either side being separately considered a Lochus; but that each Lochus amounted to 50 men is unquestion- ably false; it is more probable that the number was 25 men or thereabouts, if the Lochus was numerous, and that the marines made up the rest of the crew. But it may be said, if there were 200 men to each trireme, how could the pay of the whole crew have been exactly 200 times that which the common sailor received; a talent a month, when the common sailor received a drachma, and a half talent when he received three oboli? must not the commanders and the experienced seamen have received more than the common rowers? To this I answer as follows; that in the payment of a ship's crew it was settled once for all, that the of a trireme should be 200 times the wages of a pay common seaman: it must at the same time be considered as possible, or rather probable, that the seaman received less than the average rate of pay, and that the able seaman received somewhat more, so that what was deducted from the former was added to the latter. The Scholiast of Aristophanes 564 distinctly asserts that the Thalamitæ re- ceived lower wages, because they had the shortest oars, and consequently the lightest labour: the Thranitæ on 563 Lex. Seg. p. 298. 564 Acharn. 1106. 372 1 the other hand from having the largest oars had the great- est fatigue, and for this reason in the Sicilian expedition the Trierarchs made them an additional allowance, toge- ther with some other inferior persons in the vessel, proba- bly the steersman, the Proreus, &c.; but that their regular pay was higher we are neither told by Thucydides nor his interpreter 565, who have been adduced as authorities for the fact. But even if the pay was graduated according to rank, we could not apportion the different rates for each description of seamen; especially as we are not able to ascertain with accuracy the respective numbers of each class. It is indeed scarcely possible even with the aid of conjecture to determine the proportion which the sailors in a ship bore to the soldiers; I will therefore make some addition to what has been already observed on this point with a view to render more intelligible our assumption respecting the numbers of the crew of a trireme. Triremes were of different kinds, either swift (TaxeÏαι), or military transports (στρατιώτιδες, ὁπλιταγωγοί): the latter were completely filled with land-forces, who, as they were put on board solely for the purpose of being carried from one place to another, were for this reason ineffective in battle, and therefore never called on to fight except on emergencies 566; the former kind however took on board no more than the full complement of men (λngwμa) which was necessary for working and defending the ship. The troops on board the military transports in addition to the proper crews were, like all persons who travelled by sea, called Epibatæ; 5100 men were transported in forty such vessels, according to the account of Thucydides, making } 565 VI. 31. 566 Thucyd. I. 116. affords an instance of this. 373 altogether with their respective attendants more than 200 men to a trireme; the Thebans sent 300 men to Pagasæ in two triremes 567, whose motion was consequently much retarded. The Hoplite upon a few occasions transported themselves, performing the labour of rowing with their own hands (avregéra) 568. The crews of the swift triremes (αὐτερέται) however consisted of two descriptions of men, of the soldiers or marines appointed to defend the vessels, who were also called Epibatæ; and of the sailors. These Epibatæ were entirely distinct from the land-soldiers, such as Hoplitæ, Peltasts, and cavalry 569; and belonged to the vessel: but if it was an object to increase the usual num- ber, it was easy to give an additional quota of land-soldiers, as for instance, the 30 to each trireme in Xerxes' fleet. The seamen, under whom I include the whole crew with the exception of the soldiers, are called sometimes servants (úπngétαi), sometimes sailors (vautai): in the more limited sense however the rowers (égétai, nuπyλátαi) are dis- tinct from the servants and sailors, and only comprise those who were employed at the steerage, sails, cordage, pumps, &c. Finally, the rowers Finally, the rowers were of three kinds, Thranitæ, Zugitæ, and Thalamitæ. If now the regu- lar crew of the swift triremes amounted to 200 men, how was this number divided? Meibomius reckons 180 rowers, in three rows, so that there were 30 upon each bank, on either side. This is a most singular hypothesis. For if there were 180 rowers, there would only remain 20 567 Thucyd. VIII. 43. Xenoph. Hell. V. 4. 56. There were 300 citizens who were on board the triremes as Epibatæ and no rowers. 568 Thuc. III. 18. cf. VI. 91. 569 Xenoph. Hell. 1. 2. 4. 374 for all the rest of the crew, whereas the navigation of the ship alone would have required this number; if we consider only the steersman, the Proreus, the Celeuustes, the Trie- raules, the Nauphylax, the Toicharchs, the Diopes, the Eschareus, and the many others that were unquestionably employed; and what room do we then leave for the ma- rines? The supposition of Meibomius is borrowed from the Quinquireme, to which Polybius assigns 300 rowers, and 120 fighting men; the former in five rows of 60 men, 30 on each side; but his reason for crowding as many rowers into the long side of the trireme, which he reckons at 150 feet, as into that of the Quinquireme which measured 105 feet, is arbitrary. Not to go into farther details, the rowers could not have amounted to more than 130 or 140 men, if we leave a sufficient number for that part of the crew which worked the ship, and for the Epibatæ. In the Quinquireme the rowers were to the marines in the ratio of five to two; in a Penteconter there were 30 men besides the 50 rowers 570, most of whom were undoubtedly soldiers, as the number required for the working of the vessel must in this case have been smaller; probably only about ten men, so that the ratio of the rowers to the fighters was again as five to two. If therefore we reckon that there were in a trireme 130 or 140 rowers, and 40 or 50 Epi- batæ, in addition to twenty other seamen, the number of rowers assumed is proportionally large. I know only of two definite accounts of the number of the Epibata which refer to particular occasions. Herodotus 571 tells us that the Chians having revolted from Persia, and equipped a hundred ships, distributed 40 opulent citizens as Epibatæ 370 Herod. VII. 184. 571 Herod. VI. 15. ! 375 in each trireme, which agrees perfectly with my computa- tion. Plutarch 572 informs us that only eighteen men fought upon deck on board the Athenian triremes at the battle of Salamis; that of these, four were bowmen and the others heavy-armed; this estimate is however singu- larly low. With regard to the mode of fighting it may be observed, that the rowers struck their opponents with oars, the Epibatæ used arrows and darts at a distance, spears and swords in close combat 573. It must not how- ever be supposed that the rowers were so nearly defence- less. Isocrates 574 indeed in the passage in which he com- plains that foreigners were then serving as fighting-men, and citizens as rowers, remarks, that in descents upon the enemies' territory, the former fought as Hoplita, while the latter landed with the cushions on which they sat; from which it might be inferred that the rowers were un- provided with any weapons of defence: there can however be no doubt that they were armed, only not in any regular manner, every one providing for himself as he could, or as accident determined for him, some as Peltasts, bowmen, &c. that is, the Thranite and Zeugitæ 575, and probably the Thalamitæ also. They were therefore able to serve on land, which was necessarily the case with the Hoplitæ who rowed themselves 576. Since then the arming of the rowers was irregular, some preparations were frequently required in order to make them serviceable on land. Thus Thrasyllus armed 5000 seamen belonging to his fifty 572 Themist. 14. 573 Compare for example Diod. XIII. 46. 574 Συμμαχ. 16. 373 Thuc. IV. 3. 2. 576 See the passages referred to in note 568. 376 1 triremes as Peltasts 577; and on an occasion mentioned by Thucydides 578 the sailors were obliged to be provided with shields before they could serve upon land. This irregularity in the equipment of the seamen is the less surprising, as we find that even the Hoplita and the Epibatæ were not armed with perfect uniformity; for, had this been the case, there would have been no foundation for the story which Herodotus relates of an Hoplites in the battle of Platææ, who brought an anchor with him, in order to fasten himself to the ground 579; or an Epibates, who made use of a spear-sickle (dogudgéπavov) instead of a spear, as Plato 580 mentions. The land and sea forces generally received their pay and provision at the same time; if any portion of it remained in arrear, it was commonly the pay; and the provision-money, as being necessary, was usually supplied first. In the expedition of Timotheus against Corcyra, the mercenaries had received three months' provisions in advance, but no pay had been supplied; so that there would have been considerable danger of their going over to the enemy, if Timotheus had not inspired them with confidence in his pecuniary resources by giving them the provision-money 581 in advance. Demosthenes 582 produces another instance, in which the Trierarch had received the whole of the provision-money for his crew, though he obtained no more than two months' pay for the whole time of his Trierarchy. Here too should be mentioned a 577 Xenoph. Hell. I. 21. cf. I. 1. 24. 578 IV. 9. 578 Herod. IX. 74. 580 Laches p. 183. D. 581 Pseud-Aristot. Econ. II. 23. 552 In Polycl. p. 1209. 12. 377 suggestion of the same statesman in the first Philippic, which however was never put into execution. He pro- posed to maintain a standing army, in order to carry on war against the Macedonians without intermission; ten ships and 2000 infantry, at an expence for each of forty talents; and 200 cavalry, at twelve talents a year: these sums however were only to be given them as provision- money; he would not allow any pay, but they were to have unlimited permission to plunder. This proposal is worthy of remark, as having no parallel in any Grecian author; it is the outline of a plan for embodying a military force to maintain itself at free quarters, and at the same time to form a permanent standing army; though its continuance was indeed limited to the duration of war. A standing army in time of peace would not only have utterly ruined the finances, had it received pay, but, if it had consisted of citizens, would have led to a military government; as the Thousand at Argos, who were required to devote themselves exclusively to the exercise of arms, and received pay for their services, took forcible possession of the sovereign power, and changed the democracy into an oligarchy 583. The Greeks were well aware that a standing army obtained a greater degree of skill in the art of war; but they were prevented from introducing it by the nature of their constitutions: for neither were they able to realize the ideal state of Plato, in which the stand- ing army, formed according to philosophical and moral principles, is at the head of the government; nor could they return to the oriental form of castes, an institution of universal adoption in remote antiquity, and under A 585 Diod. XII. 75, 80. Thuc. V. 81. Pausan. II. 20. Aristot. Polit. V. 4. 378 which Attica had in early times had her military caste; nor, lastly, could they have endured the oppression of a military government. The Romans were of the same opinion: even after their government had declined into a barbarous military despotism, it was nevertheless consi- dered indecorous that an armed force should reside in the capital, for the purpose, as it were, of overawing the people ; and in order to preserve the decorum to which they owed the continuance of all ancient forms, and even of the Senate itself, the imperial guards at Rome were compelled to wear the civil toga, and their helmets and shields were kept in the armoury 584. With regard to the scheme of Demos- thenes mentioned above, it seems strange, according to our notions, that the soldiers were to have first received money merely for provision, and to have had no pay whatever; as it appears more natural to have given them pay, and have supplied provisions by means of requisition and quartering: but the former method was too tedious and difficult in an enemy's country, if it was to be exacted regularly; and the latter was very rarely practised in the Greek States. In the first place, it was unnecessary, war being generally carried on in the favourable time of year, and the life of a camp in so mild a climate was healthy and pleasant; in the second place, it was inadmissible upon military in a foreign, and on political principles in a friendly, country. The ancients, on account of the freedom of their governments, would not, any more than England, have submitted to an institution from which every sort of oppression and injustice is inse- parable, and which endangers the very existence of liberty; considering too the greater dissoluteness of their morals 584 See Lipsius ad Tacit. Ann. I. 38. 379 (particularly with regard to the intercourse of the sexes and their proneness to unnatural vices), the susceptibility of their passions, the want of discipline in the armies, and the great claims and pretensions of the soldiers, the neces- sary consequences of such an institution would have been murders, insurrections, and revolutions. In the case of friendly States it was first necessary to ask whether an army in march or a naval force could be received into the city alone, and even this was frequently denied: if per- mission was granted, every thing was paid for on the spot. When Athens sent an army to the assistance of the Thebans, they received it in so friendly a manner, that the Hoplitæ and cavalry being encamped without the city, the Thebans admitted them into their houses: but in how marked a manner does Demosthenes boast that no disturbance ensued. "The three most splendid encomia of your virtues," he says 585, "the Thebans shewed on that day to all the Greeks; the first of your courage, the second of your justice, the third of your moderation: for by giving into your power what with them and all people is guarded with the greatest sanctity, their wives and children, they shewed that they had a firm assurance of your continence: and in that they judged rightly, for after the army had entered the city, no inhabitant made any complaint against you, no, not even an unjust one." The Persians however managed their army in a different manner: in their expedition to Greece they encamped indeed in the open fields, but were supported by the inhabitants: the reception and maintenance of Xerxes' army cost the Thasians alone, for their towns situated upon the main-land, 400 talents, which were paid out of 1 365 Pro Corona p. 299. extr. 380 the public money, so that individuals did not directly bear the burden; and the Abderite said with justice that the whole State would have been destroyed if Xerxes had breakfasted as well as dined there 586. Datames the Per- sian provisioned his troops in the same manner in a foreign country 587. The Romans oppressed the provinces most grievously with their armies, especially for winter-quar- ters; the Prætors were not ashamed to burden one State with money for expences which had been defrayed by another these bribes were called the Vectigal Prætorium, whence in subsequent times the Epidemeticum arose 588. Whether the allowance for provision was given out in money or in kind, it was the imperative duty of the generals to attend to the provisioning of the troops, espe- cially for voyages, when food could not be purchased day by day. It usually happened that a large market esta- blished itself in any place where the armies either re- mained for a time, or were expected. Here the soldiers supplied their wants, and upon a march their servants and beasts of burden carried provisions in the rear; sut- tlers and handicraftsmen followed for the sake of their own-gain: Datames the Persian even supported a number of these traffickers, in order to have a share in their profits, and prohibited all others from entering into competition with them 589. With great armies the supply of pro- visions was necessarily on a large scale: the Grecian army at Platææ was followed by large stores from the Pelopon- 586 Herod. VII. 118 sqq. 587 Pseud-Aristot. Econ. II. 24. 588 Burmann de Vect. Pop. Rom. XII. An action of similar oppression is mentioned by Tacitus, Hist. I. 66. 589 Pseud-Aristot. ut sup. 381 nese, the care of which belonged to the attendants 590; in like manner the Persian army was followed by whole fleets of store-ships. The provident Nicias stated it as an indis- pensable requisite to the undertaking of the Sicilian expe- dition, that wheat and roasted barley should be sent from Attica to Sicily, and that they should take with them hired bakers, who were procured from the mills by a compulsory levy 591; the provision-fleet collected at Cor- cyra consisting of 30 corn-vessels, with the bakers and other handicraftsmen, such as stone-masons and carpenters, and the implements required for a siege; also a hundred smaller vessels were constrained to attend the store-ships, and many others both smaller and larger followed the army for the sake of traffic 592. When such was the case however the soldiers doubtless purchased their provision either from individuals or from the State, which had only the care of procuring supplies, without any thing being given freely to the soldiers, unless perchance no provision- money had been paid them. When Timotheus besieged Samos, a scarcity of provisions was produced by the concourse of so many strangers; he therefore prohibited the selling of ground corn, and did not allow it to be sold plain in less quantities than a medimnus, or any liquids 590 Herod. IX. 39. cf. 50. 591 Thuc. VI. 22. where the bakers are called йvaynaoμÉvor quito, as, although they received pay, they had been forced to follow this expedition. The worthy critic, who was puzzled with this expression, did not know how many men serve for pay contrary to their will. Пgès égos Duker rightly interprets pro Πρὸς μέρος rata portione; it is not however in reference to the corn, but means that a proportional number should be taken from each mill, ix tãv pevλávwv πgòs µégos, for example, two out of each. 592 Thuc. VI. 30, 44. 382 · in less quantities than a metretes; by these means the strangers were obliged to bring their provisions with them, and they sold whatever remained unconsumed; while the Taxiarchs and Lochagi bought food by wholesale, and re- tailed it among the soldiers 593. The same must be considered to have been the case in the Sicilian expedition, and other similar occasions. If the provision was supplied in kind, which was necessarily more general with the sea than with the land service, the commanders received the Siteresion, and with that money they purchased a store of pro- visions. The Trierarchs supplied their inferiors with barley-meal (λora), cheese, and onions 594, or garlic, which were carried in nets 595; the maza was baked from the barley-meal 596, with water and oil 597; and if it was wished particularly to stimulate the rowers, wine also was added 598. Probably each man received a choenix of barley-meal a day: a comic poet indeed says of a man, who boasted of eating 24 medimni in a day, that he would consume the provisions of a long trireme 599, although what he eat was in fact only 120 chonices; but who will require of a jester accuracy on such a subject as this? Ptolemy gave the Rhodians, for the provision of ten triremes, 20,000 artabæ of corn 600, probably of wheat, 593 Pseud-Aristot. II. 23. Polyæn. III. 10. 10. 594 Plutarch. de Glor. Ath. 6. 595 Thence the saying, σxógodov v dixTús, see Suidas in v. σκοροδίοις. 596 Schol. Aristoph. Ran. 1105. 597 Hesychius and Zonaras in v. μáča. μάζα. 598 Thuc. III. 49. comp. Scheffer Mil. Nav. IV. 1. This μála is the oivourra, Athen. III. p. 114. F. οἰνοῦττα, 599 Athen. X. P. 415. C. 600 Polyb. V. 89. 383 making ten artabæ a year for each man, if we reckon 200 to a trireme; which amounts to almost one choenix and a half a day, if large artabæ are meant, and if small, only three quarters of a choenix. To estimate the amount of the pay and provision-money required for a war, another condition is necessary besides the numerical force of the army and the rate of the pay, viz. the length of the campaign. As soon as the campaign was over, the payment of the troops ceased; even mer- cenaries did not constantly receive wages, but were paid for a portion only of the time 601. In early times war was carried on with the Lacedæmonians for four or five months; but Philip made no difference between summer and win- ter 603. Yet as early as in the Peloponnesian war, armies were paid in winter, as in Sicily and elsewhere; and Pericles used regularly to keep sixty ships eight months at sea, and to pay them for the whole time 603: these alone must have cost 480 talents a year, if each man received a drachma a day. But how could Athens have raised pay and provision-money for more than 60,000 men in the Sicilian expedition, the cost being 3600 talents in a year, i. e. in the money of the present day, £870,000, which, according to the prices of commodities at that time, may be considered as equal to more than two millions sterling. We must not therefore wonder that, notwith- standing the high tributes and the oppression of the allies (though the independent confederate States in great mea- sure paid their own troops), a scarcity of supplies quickly arose; nor need we be surprised that Pericles, who, in the - 601 For an instance of this see Thucyd. VIII. 45. 602 Demosth. Philipp. III. p. 123. 603 Plutarch. Pericl. 11. 384 beginning of the war, kept an equally large force on foot, although not throughout the whole year, was compelled to have recourse to the public treasure. (23.) The expences of war were also considerably in- creased by the equipment of fleets, and the preparation of machines used in war and of instruments for sieges. Be- sides the ships which were built in time of peace, they were accustomed, as soon as any severe struggle was appre- hended, to apply themselves with extraordinary zeal to the construction of vessels; yet, before the ships could be ready to sail, there remained always much to be done in order to complete their equipment; part of which was furnished by the State, and part by the Trierarch at his own cost. Besides the swift triremes, it was also necessary to provide many transports (λxades), auxiliary vessels (ὑπηρετικὰ πλοῖα), and cavalry transports (ἱππαγωγὰ πλοῖα); which latter, although the Greeks had taken horses with them to the siege of Troy, and the Persians had employed many ships of this description in the war against Greece, were yet for the first time regularly introduced at Athens in the second year of the Peloponnesian war, and were afterwards frequently used 604.. On rare occasions only it happened that the Athenians had a fleet equipped and ready for battle, such as that appointed in Olymp. 87. 2., when it was decreed that the 100 best triremes should be selected, to which Trierarchs were immediately assigned, in order that Attica might be defended in the event of an attack from the sea; and at the same time a thousand 604 Thuc. II. 56. IV. 42. VI. 43. and elsewhere, Demosth. Philipp. I. p. 46. 5. Plutarch. Pericl. 35. Concerning the Persians see Diod. XI. 3. Herod. VII. 97. 385 talents were ordered to be laid by for the same object 605. The preparations for sieges were particularly expensive, as much carpenters' work and masonry and many handi- craftsmen were required for these purposes: machines for attack and defence were used in early times, not only in the Peloponnesian war, but even at an earlier period, as, for example, by Miltiades, and by Pericles at the siege of Samos; although the art of besieging did not attain its greatest perfection among the Greeks until the time of Demetrius Poliorcetes. That considerable outlays were made for missile weapons is evident from several passages in ancient writers. With regard to Athens, it will be sufficient to mention the two decrees 606 by which honours were conferred on Demochares and Lycurgus; the former, for having procured arms, darts, and machines; the latter, for having brought arms and 50,000 darts into the Acro- polis. (24.) If all these several heads are added together, it will be at once evident how immense must have been the whole expences of a war after the time that Pericles had introduced the pay of the forces. Whereas in earlier times the building and equipment of the fleets were the only things that caused any expence to the State. The fine of fifty talents, to which Miltiades was condemned on account of the failure of his expedition against Paros, might there- fore have been taken as equivalent to the whole expence, as Nepos 607 thinks it was, did we not know that this sum 605 Thuc. II. 24. VIII. 15. Esch. de Fals. Leg. p. 336. Andoc. de Pace p. 92. Suid. in v. äßvoros. The money was laid by only once, and not annually, as some writers have erroneously supposed. 606 At the end of the Lives of the Ten Orators, II. III. 507 Miltiad. 7. VOL. I. се 386 was a common fine, without any regard to a particular compensation. The siege of Samos in Olymp. 84. 4. appears, according to Diodorus, to have cost 200 talents; for Pericles required a contribution to this amount, as an indemnification for the expences which had been incurred 608 The Olympian Jupiter must however have reckoned very leniently in this case; for a nine months' siege by land and sea, in which, according to the account of Thucydides, not less than 199 triremes were employed, or at any rate a large part of this number for a considerable time, must evidently have caused a greater expence; and the state- ment therefore of Isocrates and Nepos 609, that 1200 talents were expended upon it, appears to be by no means exaggerated. But the expences of the Peloponnesian war are the most extraordinary in the financial history of Athens. If we assume that the ships employed at the beginning of the war received only six months' pay, they must have cost 1500 talents; and in this number the forces employed at the siege of Potidea are not included. This siege was extremely expensive, having been continued uninterruptedly during both summer and winter for two years; Thucydides reckons the expence at 2000 610, Iso- crates at 2400 talents, a part of which Pericles took from the public treasure 611. A separate war-tax of 200 talents 608 Diod. XII. 28. cf. Thuc. I. 117. 609 Thuc. I. 116, 117. Isocrat. de Antidosi p. 69. Nepos Timoth. 1. 610 Thuc. II. 70. where the reading xine is undoubtedly false, Isocrat. de Antid. p. 70. Diodorus (XII. 46.) reckons the expences some months before the surrender at more than 1000 talents. 611 Thuc. III. 17. II. 13. According to the latter passage 3700 talents were taken out of the treasury, which Diodorus 387 was levied for the siege of Mytilene, and twelve ships were dispatched for the purpose of collecting money from the allies 612. No enterprize went so far beyond the resources of the Athenian State as the Sicilian expedition. The annual pay alone amounted, as we have already seen, to 3600 talents, nearly the double of the whole annual re- venue of Athens, if we take it at the highest estimate; and at how great an amount must we reckon the other expences of this war? By these means both money and provisions soon almost wholly failed; nor were the sub- sidies furnished by the Egestæans at all considerable, viz. sixty talents given at the very commencement, as monthly pay for sixty ships, and thirty talents sent at a subsequent period 613. There was little plunder taken, although 100 talents were once obtained from that source614: the remit- tances from Athens were by no means large, 20, 120, or 300 talents, and these, as it appears, even came, in part at least, from the public treasure 615, to which, both then and afterwards, they were compelled to have recourse, in order to support the expences of the war, for which purpose indeed it had been originally collected. Nothing but a fortunate issue could have put Athens in a condition to (XII, 40.) less accurately calls 4000. Barthélemy reckons 3000 for the public works of Pericles, and 700 for the first part of the siege (Anach. tom. I. note VIII.). This assumption is however quite arbitrary; Potidea and the works of building and art might have cost more than 5000 talents, and those 3700 have been only an advance from the public treasure, in addition to what was paid for out of the current revenues. 612 Thuc. III. 19, 613 Diod. XIII. 6. 614 Diod. ibid. 615 See Inscript. 144. according to my interpretation. · 388 познани defray the immense sums required for pay; without which however it would have been impossible to adopt so vast a plan. If Pericles had not introduced the pay of the soldiers, Athens could not have carried on the Pelopon- nesian war for so long a time; nor again, could the youthful imagination of Alcibiades have conceived the lofty notion of obtaining a footing in Sicily, as a new centre from which they might subdue Carthage and Libya, Italy, and finally, the Peloponnese 616; the people and the soldiers were moreover favourably inclined to this expedi- tion, because they hoped to receive money immediately, and to make conquests, by which they would be enabled to receive their pay without intermission 617. In the age of Demosthenes also much treasure, levied chiefly by property-taxes, was applied to the uses of war; but with much money little was effected. A fruitless expedition to Pyle cost, together with the expences incurred by private individuals, above 200 talents 618; Isocrates complains of the loss of more than 1000 talents, which had been given to foreigners619; Demosthenes of the squandering of more than 1500, which, as Æschines remarks, were not expended upon the soldiers, but upon the ostentatious splendour of 616 Thuc. VI. 15, 90. Isocrat. Zvμpax. 29. Plutarch. Alcib. 17. The idea was new; for although in the Knights of Aristo- phanes (vs. 174, 1300.) a plan is hinted at for attacking Car- thage, it only owes its existence to a false reading. In both places Kaλyndavy should evidently be read for Kagxndar, as the Scholiast at vs. 1300 writes, and as the sense requires in vs. 174. 617 Thuc. VI. 24. 618 Demosth. de Fals. Leg. p. 367. 21. 619 Isocrat. Areopag. 4. 389 the generals 620, at the very time they lost the allied cities and their ships. The State had been impoverished by the Theorica, while individuals had enriched themselves; there was not in the military chest money enough for a single day's march 621; and if any funds were collected for war, the mismanagement and maladministration would surpass all belief, did we not know that the same mischief has recurred in all times. Commanders or demagogues, who received pay for the troops, drew it for empty places 622, as was the expression; in the same manner that in modern times generals have received pay for what were termed men of straw, or soldiers that existed only on the roll. To ascertain the extent of these practices, commissioners were sent out to discover whether there were as many mercenaries, as the generals reported; these enquirers however frequently allowed themselves to be bribed 623. The Trierarchs, as early even as in the time of the poet Aristophanes, were accused of embezzling the pay of part of the crew, and stopping the unoccupied apertures for the oars in their ships, in order that it might not be seen that there was a 620 Demosth. Olynth. III. p. 36. 8. (and thence mel ouvτáž. p. 174. 11.) Esch. de Fals. Leg. p. 249. 621 Demosth. in Aristocrat. p. 690. 622 This is the meaning of μισθοφορεῖν ἐν τῷ ξενικῷ κεναῖς χώραις, Æschin. in Ctesiph. p. 536. Others cheated the soldiers, as e. g. Memnon of Rhodes and Cleomenes. See Aristot. Econ. II. 29, 39. Timarch. p. 131. wɛgì 623 These are the Tarral, Esch. in Tagaлgroß. p. 339. Lex. Seg. p. 252. The passage in the oration gì GUYτážews p. 167. 17. seems also to refer to the Exetastæ; those however mentioned in the decree communicated by Chishull Ant. As. p. 164. from Ainsworth, which probably belongs to Athens, are of a different description. 390 deficiency of rowers 624. In the mean time the public money was squandered away by such generals as Chares and many resembling him, who were distinguished by every kind of profligacy. If in an age of simplicity and decorum, Themistocles was not ashamed to drive through the Ceramicus in the morning with a carriage full of courtesans 625, it is easy to understand how Alcibiades, who, notwithstanding his extraordinary talents, was a man of the most immoral and irreligious character, did not scruple (as at least his enemies said of him 626) to carry women about with him in his campaigns, and to embezzle 200 talents; how Chabrias, according to Theopompus, was not able to remain in Athens on account of his debauched habits; and how, according to the same authority, Chares had with him in the field women even of the lowest descrip- tion, and applied the public money to uses wholly at variance with its proper destination. But the Athenians could not censure such a course of habits, for they themselves lived in an equally depraved manner, the young men with female flute-players and courtesans, the old in gambling; while they consumed more money in public banquettings and distributions of food than for the real service of the State, and allowed themselves to be entertained in the market place at a triumphal festival for a battle won over the mercenaries of Philip with an expence of sixty talents, which Chares had received from Delphi 627. Theopompus is decried as censorious for having painted from nature the dissolute manners of a corrupt age: for most people 624 Schol. Aristoph. Pac. 1233. 625 Heraclides ap. Athen. XII. p. 533. D. 626 Lysias in Alcib. λuzorak, 1. p. 598. 627 Theopompus ap. Athen. XII. p. 532. 532. B sqq. 391 are inclined to view every thing on its fairest side, especially if they view it from a distance, when all the passions are silent, and the benevolent feeling which is implanted in the heart of man is not contradicted by immediate and personal experience: but honour is due to the Historian who knows how to distinguish the covering from the substance, and, like the judge of the infernal regions, drags the souls before his judgment-seat, naked and stripped of all pomp and and pageantry. Timotheus the son of Conon, deserves to be honourably mentioned as a warrior equal to his father, and among all the Athenian generals of being that one who knew how to carry his enterprizes into execution with the least outlay of money, and therefore without burdening the allies, and making himself and his country odious through extor- tion. I pass over his other services, which will be men- tioned hereafter; but his skill in maintaining his soldiers ought not to be left unnoticed. Timotheus generally received little or nothing in the beginning of the cam- paign; though there arose the greatest scarcity in the army, he was still successful in the war, and paid his soldiers to the last obolus 628. He subdued four and twenty States with less expence than the siege of Melos had occasioned in the Peloponnesian war 629; the siege of Potidea, which had cost such vast sums in the time of Pericles, he carried on with money which he had raised himself, together with the contributions of the Thracian cities 630; according to Nepos he gained in the war against 628 Isocrat. de Antidosi p. 72. ed. Orell. 629 Isocrat. ibid. p. 70. 630 Isocrat. ibid. p. 70. 392 Cotys 1200 talents of prize-money 631. In the expedition against Olynthus having no silver money he issued a coinage of copper tokens, and induced the merchants to take it by promising them that they might use it in paying for whatever property either in land or plunder they might purchase, and he pledged himself to redeem whatever should remain over 632. In the expedition round the Peloponnese to Corcyra, there was likewise great scarcity: for Timotheus had received only thirteen talents 633. He accordingly compelled each of the Trierarchs to give pay to the sailors to the amount of seven minas, for which he pledged his own property 634: afterwards being unable to furnish any more pay to the troops, he gave them the provision-money for three months in advance, in order that they might believe he was in the expectation of large sums which were only detained by the unfavourable state of the weather 635; and in the mean time he sent for a fresh supply of money from Athens for his numerous fleet 636. But he and Iphicrates also paid away some of the prize-money on this occasion 637. Lastly, Timotheus kept thirty triremes and 8000 peltasts in pay (with which 631 Nep. Timoth. I. 632 Pseud-Aristot. Econ. II. 2. 23. Polyæn. III. 10. 1. 633 Isocrat. ut sup. p. 68. 634 Orat. in Timoth. (in Demosthenes) p. 1187, 1188. 635 Pseud-Aristot. Econ. ut sup. 636 Xenoph. Hell. V. 4. 66. 637 Diod. XV. 47. cf. XVI. 57. Xenophon indeed (Hell. VI. 2. 23.) relates the accounts, which Diodorus ascribes to both, of Iphicrates alone, and undoubtedly with more correctness; but it can be safely asserted of Timotheus that he assisted himself at that time with plunder. 393 he besieged Samos for eleven months) sustaining them wholly from the enemy's country, whereas Pericles had not been able to take the same island without incurring a vast expence 638. ་ 638 Isocrat. ut sup. p. 69. Aristot. Econ. ut sup. Polyæn. I. 10. 5, 9. VOL. I. MAY 8 - 1915 D d Note to p. 374. l. 12. "-reckons at 105 feet." In the original it is printed "auf 150 Füssen anschläght." The words of Meibomius (De Fabrica Triremium, Gronov. Thes. Ant. Rom. vol. XII. p. 584 B.) are, Longitudinem triremis antiquæ facio circiter pedum CV. lati- tudinem pedum XI. sedilia cujusque ordinis XXX. ut caperet remiges CLXXX.” .. buciekut, kA. ARABIAALAAN AANANAIA 1837 VERITAS 3) •T. PLURIBUS UNŮM ARTES LIBRARY UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 1 SCIENTIA OF THE QUAERIS PENINSULAM AMOENAME CIRCUMSPICE! VAJAJAJAJAJAJAPAGKUKIKONUKLADACIA JATAON A 581739 JAGA BEQUEATHED BY THOMAS SPENCER JEROME CLASS Or 1884 SAAAAS MA AAR 11 Tir mad.com Kadena. ܐ ܕܪ we we