§ ..º.º. gº tº º "tºº º *** !!! ſaeſsä §§;: ſae; §§ī£55)!=--~~~~ -.. ·· ·,≤) © ® • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • ► ► ► • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • D • • • • • • • • • • • • • •■ ºg:§§§ ĒĒĒĒĒĒĒĒĒĒĒĒĒĒĒĒIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIËH!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!= ý. tº eas ºº eas ºr sº as ºr ºs * * * * * * * * * * º º ºs º ºs º ºs º sº tº sº ºm º ºs º ſº ºr sº dº º is dº º dº - D IN It -4 Dººleºvº-º-º-º-º-º-º-º-º-º- ºr ººººººº-º-º-º-º-º-º: I REC ©_---- ſae 3,2% ±±(pºſeſvºj „Al.I. zº, 2,2©. Q-T (NT ITA ș#ffffffïĪſáffffffffff№ĪĪĪĪĪĪĪĪĪĪĪĪĪ ----[I] # ſ= ſā Q = 0 ± \ E 8 E Q ! | 5 0 # № # # ſā }} §= }}= № E Ë # t = ! E ſ= № HÆ № ## [] # # ## ## №. 806. "I Z 'MW'ſ "lwd A “N ‘2’snoe. As ‘so.19 p.uol Aeo S-SN-Svrºv c <) ſ İi IIII SHANGE XC V r A. EIVE * _º \S \\-N e-Q-\\ c ||||||||||||||||Illllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllſ|| Hiſſiſſiſſiſ sœ • • • • • • ► H NIMMO. Lls; ºak Y { ###. JF #|CH. * º 5EC15'1917 DISPENSING POWER. {} THE REGULATION OF COMMERCE THROUGH A !A’ ·ë �L}* « º.ſ. À* **… !º : : „''x , ** **U * & * & “...), š„~~~~-* - &, . . .- 4. †*-+---- → $r→g … =* __^…-- 3$ º-----------* .…!--**#,^O • — :--_. - - - --&-------- :..? -- -• ... .____________)- … ► ► ► ► ► ► ... . … - ~~~~~ --№-* * * * *e: ** -----|-*:(.*-r : ** ---· x) = x - a *-• ~ ?~~~~ ~----šsŤžºſ, – ?, ~~~~<-- -*=-- ~~~~ ~ ~----… … ………:). -***** • • • • • • •: ** * * * *=+-***#!***.**.**…*..*… :(----Ř. № šā sae … x → * , w' + s +_+ * ºș***, ** * $-ºſ, x) '.*******.*¿¿-?!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! :) ---<!--(.*,,…), š − × × × × ×---~ !! !! !!!!! ::::::::::::::*№sſzae, ſae-ſae,, !? ſaeº :((?:?, ¿?: …..????¿? · ·…!!!!!!!--************,--• • •-----! !!.*::*?)& №:-*-·-şar;3, ±√(********::::zaeae&f. §-a a, * * · * * æš x ************** * * · !!!!!!!!!!!!!!! !!:º::::::::::::::* .*ſ*… :º)*: < .·、。、、。(?)、。 。.*»…• • • >***·!!!!!!!!!!!!Ē№. !! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! *-->-w:-~--! 5-* * * … .±√(√∞, √≠√±,±,±,±,±,±,±,±,±,±), - - ****-;-, & x^*, x ≤ ≥ ± − × ******** -*********、、、、、、、、、、、、、、、。(?)、。 .*.*..*$2:',•*.*,$£§!!!*** • ** *********...;&*)****ț¢&& §-gae : •• →å *****…Yxxº§* º *.*?) ***** ***,.*..**:\;5 æ:æ æ , æ-- ******************* • • ► -, º+*…*...- ***§§::::::::::::::::::ex aey × (-∞ √+ √(x ********14) × , • , ſºwº :**********șaeae × ± •± = −, ×, tae+|-- CONTENTS. Introductory Remarks.............. .......................................... W Historical Sketch................................................................ The Future Policy of the Commission.................................. What is Involved in “A Dispensing Power”....................... Magnitude of the Proposed Power.......... , e s is e s p → ~ ºn e s tº e s is e º e º e s e e º e º º e Rights of Property Violated................................................ Regulation by Preliminary Judgment .................................. A Judicial Opinion.............................................................. - The British Railway Commission.......................................... Commissioner Prouty's Attitude toward the Railroads.......... Antagonism of Interstate Commerce Commission.................. Conclusion.......................................................................... CoPYRIGHTED, 1903, BY Joseph NIMMo, Jr. CO M P L 1 M ENT s o F Joseph NIM Mo, JR. 1 33.1 F ST. R. E. ET No RT H W E ST, W. As H | N G TO N, D. C. THE REGULATION OF COMMERCE THROUGH A DisPENsing Power. Efforts of the Interstate Commerce Commission to gain Autocratic Control of the Internal Corm rmerce of the United States. THE POLITICAL ASPECTS OF THE 0UESTIOM. . By Joseph NIM Mo, Jr., LL.D. For M. E R c + i E F of rº E Bu REA u o F stratistics ru rºi E rºt Easu ny D, E Part an ENT, A N p - LAT E PR Est D, E N T o F T H E R AT I o N A L sºr ATI stric Ai. Assoc i AT I o N. war As H 1 R GTo N, D. c. : TH E R U F U. S. H. DAR BY PRI tº Tº N G CO. 1 9 O 3. tºº & & Nºssº o–49448 NOTE BY THE PUBLISHER. This document, in a somewhat extended and revised form, will constitute one or more chapters of a volume which Mr. Nimmo has in coarse of preparation on The Evolution of the American Railroad System. THE REGULATION OF COMMERCE THROUGH A - DISPENSING POWER. T H E PC LIT CAL ASPECTS OF THE CAS E. In the entire range of current populistic thought it would be difficult to mention any expedient more seriously fraught … with danger to the commercial interests or the political * i integrity of this country than the proposition to confer upon the Interstate Commerce Commission unlimited power * to prescribe in advance the rates which shall be charged * for transportation services on railroads and thus to exercise autocratic control over the internal commerce of the United - # States. Such delegation of power would necessarily devolve º upon the National Government full responsibility for both the absolute and the relative prosperity of the various localities, States and sections of the country. Besides, it would overload the government with jurisdiction and in- evitably beget sectional strife such as that which the Consti- tution of the United States was mainly intended to arrest. The granting of the proposed power would unavoidably involve the creation of a fourth branch of our National Government, namely, A DISPENSING POWER IN THE UNITED STATES.” As hereinafter shown this would radically change the character of our political institutions. It is not only admitted, but firmly maintained that the rail- roads should be effectually regulated, in a manner con- *. *. { *The word dispense is employed in this article as a transitive verb, signifying to supersvise, to control, to manage, to give out. Its deriva- tives are used in the same sense. 4. formable to the exigencies of our civilization and the funda- mental principles of our governmental institutions. The sole object of this paper is to prove that the proposed remedy is fraught with evils vastly greater and more serious than those which it is intended to correct. The nature of the proposed change of national policy is clearly indicated by the history of the administration of the “Act to Regulate Commerce,” approved February 4, 1887. The Interstate Commerce Commission was organized in the month of March, 1887, under the guidance of that emi- nent jurist, Judge Cooley, its first chairman. In an elabo- rate opinion, written by the chairman three months later, the Commission held that it was not invested with any power to prescribe, in advance, the rates which should be charged on any railroad, declaring that “a construction of the statute which should require its performance would ren- der the due administration of the law altogether impractica- ble.” (Decision rendered in Louisville & Nashville Rail- road Case, May I 5, 1887.) In the same case Judge Cooley declared, in regard to the rates charged, by the carrier, that “no tribunal is empowered to judge for it until after the carrier has acted and then only for the purpose of determin- ſing whether its action constitutes a zizolation of Zaze.” The correctness of this view was subsequently affirmed by the Supreme Court of the United States, 167 U. S., 479. It repels any suggestion as to the creation of a dispensing power. The Commission repudiated the idea that it had any au- thority to apply the law by preliminary judgment. (De- cided April 16, 1887.) Judge Cooley also stated in an or- 5 der of April 18, 1887, in the matter of the Iowa Barb Steel Company, that “the Commission has not been given a general dispensing power to relieve hardship under the law, but its power in that regard is strictly and carefully limited.” Again he stated in a letter to J. A. Hanley of May 18, 1887, that Congress has not granted to the Com- mission any dispensing power, declaring that this “would not be consistent with sound principles of government.” Besides, with respect to the popular demand for informa- tion in advance as to the application of the law, in the mat- ter of petition of Traders and Travelers' Union, the Com- mission declared that “a moment's reflection will show that no such tribunal could be properly erected.” (Decision rendered April 16, 1887.) In a leading case (Thacher v. Delaware and Hudson Canal Co., decided in 1887) the Commission declared that it has no power to fix rates in advance, but that “its power in respect to rates is to determine whether those which the roads impose are for any reason in conflict with the pro- vision of the statute,” the decisions of the Commission be- ing appealable to and enforcible by the courts when judi- cially sustained. Judge Cooley affirmed, Zn re Chicago, St. Paul and Kan- sas City Railway Company case (decided in 1888), that “holding the railroad companies to strict compliance with all these statutory provisions and enforcing obedience to them tends to both reasonableness and equality of rate as contemplated by the Interstate Commerce Act.” The cor- rectness of that opinion has been fully sustained by the experiences of the Commission during the last sixteen years. 6 Thus did the Commission at the very beginning com- mit itself fully to the doctrine that autocratic governmental rate-making in any form is opposed to the fundamental principles upon which our political institutions are founded, and plant itself firmly upon the solid ground of commer- cial liberty incorporated in the Constitution of the United States. At the same time the Commission announced the important fact that the Act to Regulate Commerce is fully adequate to the correction of existing evils. With its power of regulation clearly defined, its con- clusions made prima facie evidence in the courts and judicial co-operation with respect to both civil and criminal procedure fully provided for, the work of the commission has been eminently successful and in a high degree bene- ficial. But a great change came over the spirit and purposes of the Commission both in regard to its authority under the law and the method of its administration. Step by step it relapsed into the vagaries of autocratic rule involving the exercise of a dispensing power. Having in a certain case assumed that it was invested with a degree of judicial authority, Judge Jackson, of the United States Circuit Court for the District of Kentucky, declared January, 1889, that the Commission is not a court, that it is not invested with any judicial function, and that Congress has no power to invest an administrative body with the judicial func- tions (37 Fed. Rep., 567). This conclusion stands and will stand until the power of the judiciary—the guardian of personal liberty—shall have been overthrown. The Commission revolted at this decision, maintaining that with respect to administrative questions “its conclu- 7 sions should be a finality, even though their enforcement may require judicial aid.” Fourth Annual Report, p. 13. Subsequently, in its Fifth Annual Report submitted Decem- ber 1, 1891, at page 21, it recommended that the court should be confined “strictly to the case made before the Commis- sion.” Thereupon the Commission drew a bill propos- ing that Congress should grant to it the desired judicial authority. This bill (S. Bill 892, 52d. Cong., 1st Session) was introduced December 15, 1891, but was rejected by the Senate Committee to which it was referred in view of Judge Jackson's decision and the inherent absurdity of the proposition to invest an administrative board with the functions of detective, witness, party complainant and judge in the same proceeding. That appeared to savor too much of the Pooh Bah style of government. After the retirement from the Commission of Judge Cooley, and of two other able lawyers—Judge Schoonmaker and Hon. Aldace F. Walker, all now deceased—the Com- mission aspired to autocratic power unfettered by judicial restraint. During the year 1894 (53d Congress) it con- ceived the idea that, by necessary implication of law, it is invested with the power to prescribe, in advance, both the absolute and relative rates which shall be charged on rail- roads throughout the United States. The first conspicuous attempt to set this assumed power in motion was in the case of rates between Chicago, Cincinnati and other points in the Western and Northwestern States and points in the States south of the Ohio River, as such rates are related to corresponding rates between Boston, New York, Philadel- phia and Baltimore at the North and the aforesaid Southern 8 points. The Commission issued an order prescribing both the absolute and relative rates which should prevail in the case stated. This was a manifest usurpation of authority. If such attempted exercise of power had been sustained it would have devolved upon the National Government full responsibility for determining the relative commercial and industrial prosperity of towns, cities, States and sections, throughout the country, and the course of its commercial and industrial development. The exercise of a dispensing power such as this would have gone directly in the face of elementary principles of liberty and have aroused political strife regarding the regulation of commerce which the National Constitution was mainly designed to prevent. The case was carefully considered by the Federal judiciary, being perceived to be of the highest commercial, judicial and political significance. The Commission’s view was rejected in the lower courts and the Supreme Court of the United States in its decision rendered May 24, 1897, em- phatically denied that the Act to Regulate Commerce con- fers upon the Commission any such power as that claimed for it, either in terms or by implication. (Maximum Rate Case, 167 U. S., 479.) At the same time the court announced the following rule of constitutional law : “It is one thing to inquire whether the rates which have been charged and collected are reason- able—that is a judicial act; but an entirely different thing to prescribe rates which shall be charged in the future— that is a legislative act.” The significance of this, as ex- plained, was that if the Commission should be invested with the rate-making power the courts could not review 9. any decision of the Commission unless it should violate the constitutional limit forbidding the taking of private prop- erty for public use without just compensation, or the taking of private property without due process of law. (Articles V and XIV of Amendments to the Constitution of the United States.) But even this limitation would leave abundant room for injustice and the exercise of autocratic power. In the case just mentioned the Commission again asserted its claim to the exercise of the judicial function, but again this was denied by the Supreme Court. This signal defeat was exceedingly distasteful to the Com- mission. Accordingly it decided to join issue with the Supreme Court before Congress. In its next annual report (submitted December 6, 1897) it recommended that Con- gress should confer upon it the absolute power to prescribe rates; authorize it to issue self-executing administrative or- ders, and final administrative orders—a strictly judicial func- tion---and compel the courts to sanction such orders. The Supreme Court, as before stated, had declared the power of rate making to be not a judicial function, and one over which the Federal judiciary could not and would not exer- cise any authority. The views of the Commission were subsequently expressed in a bill introduced in the Senate, January 22, 1898 (S. 3354,55th Cong., 2d Session), which bill provided that the courts shall be required to review the rates, fares, classifications, &c., prescribed by the Commis- sion, and further that “the case as certified from the Com- mission, together with any additional testimony taken by the courts shall be the record upon which it shall be heard,” IO thus, for the third time claiming the right to exercise judicial power. This absurd bill also proposed to confer upon the Commission absolute power to decide cases in- volving long and short haul rates, and to prescribe the rates and the conditions under which transportation shall be conducted throughout the United States. It also pro- vided that the Commission should be authorized to issue administrative orders and final administralize orders. If enacted into law, it would have subjected the commercial, industrial and transportation interests of this country to the absolute control of a bureau through the exercise of a dispensing power. The bill failed to secure serious atten- tion in either branch of Congress, and apparently produced no other effect upon the legislative mind than of aston- ishment. The Commission, however, refused to abandon its purpose to acquire dispensing power. Again in the 56th Congress, March 2, 1899, to March, IQoI, it approached Congress, but this time with a bill intended to evade the rule of govern- mental policy announced by the Supreme Court in the Maximum Rate Case, and thus to circumvent the judiciary. This bill was introduced December 12, 1899, as Senate Bill 1439, 56th Congress, 1st Session. It provided that the companies shall first make their rate sheets, which, having been made, the Commission shall, upon complaint made either by itself or any other competent complaitlant, have power to revise and change the rates which have been made, thus conferring upon the Commission the right to recast every sheet in the country. The fallacy and artifice in- volved in this provision consisted in the pretense that it II avoided the objection of the courts that rates made in ad- vance of being charged and collected, even if authorized by statute, are not reviewable in the courts, as to their reasonableness, from the fact that they are legislative rates. An ingenious argument in favor of just such an arrange- ment had been made in the Maximum Rate Case, but was utterly discarded by the Supreme Court in the following terms: “The vice of this argument is that it is building up indirectly and by implication a power which in terms is not granted.” The Commission ignored that declaration. Rates thus made would be legislative rates, and therefore not reviewable by the courts as to their reasonableness. The reasoning of the Commission in this matter was too inconsequential for serious consideration. Congress also did not fail to see that the real rate maker, in the first Žnstance, is he who finally determines the rates before they have been actually charged and collected. The bill just mentioned also proposed to confer upon the Commission the power “to prepare and publish the rules, regulations and conditions for freight transportation,” a proposition which clearly involved the creation of a dispensing power. See Section 3 of the Bill. Like its predecessors this bill gained no favor with the national legislators. Congress was not prepared to subor- dinate the Federal judiciary to the Interstate Commerce Commission. Nor was it prepared to institute in this country a bureaucratic imperialism endowed with “that great anomaly known as the dispensing power,” which in all ages has been an attribute of tyranny and oppression. Such the proposed expedient was clearly perceived to be at I 2 the beginning by Judge Cooley and his associates, who repudiated it absolutely. During this Congress (56th) the Interstate Commerce Commission engaged in a reprehensible scheme. It allied itself to a propaganda fully committed to the object of in- ducing Congress to grant to it autocratic powers over the internal commerce of this country. That propaganda is still in existence and militant. * At the same time the Commission had recourse to an astounding expedient. On December 8th, 1899, by formal vote it instructed its secre. tary to propagate among the trade organizations of the country its ideas as to Commission rate making “by dis- tributing among them such reports, papers and documents as are designed to accomplish that purpose, and to devote himself assiduously to such duty.” In pursuance of this order the Secretary of the Commission issued to the com- mercial bodies of the country a circular letter dated Feb- ruary 3, 1900, requesting them to urge upon Senators and Members of Congress the importance of passing Senate Bill I439. The glaring impropriety of this movement was evident to the national legislators and was instrumental in preventing any legislative action whatever upon the Com- mission’s anti-American and impracticable bill. During the 57th Congress—March 4, IQOI, to March 4, 1903—the Commission stultified itself glaringly before Congress. Until March, IQO2—fifteen years after its organ- ization—the Commission had neglected to employ the civil remedy provided in Section I6 of the Interstate Commerce * At the present time it is endeavoring to mislead the com- mercial bodies of the country into the folly of endorsing its appeal to Congress to confer upon the Commission autocratic power. I3 Act. Early in that month, however, the Commission had recourse to that provision of the law for the prevention of rate-cutting—a misdemeanor under the Act to Regulate Commerce. On March 24th, at the instance of the Com- mission, Judge Grosscup, of the Northern District of Illi- nois, issued an order granting a temporary injunction in an important case pending at Chicago, and in so doing expressed the opinion that “the expedient might turn out to be the vitalizing of the Act.” That expectation was realized. The injunction proved effectual in greatly abat- ing, if not in entirely arresting, the evil complained of. But the successful application of this provision of the Act to Regulate Commerce ran counter to the scheme of auto- cratic rule which for years the Commission had had in mind. Within one month after Judge Grosscup’s order was issued, the Commission Stultified itself by appearing before the Committees on Interstate Commerce of the Sen- ate and House of Representatives in earnest advocacy of a bill providing for the repeal of so much of Section 16 of the Act to Regulate Commerce as embraces the effectual civil remedy just mentioned, and proposed to substitute in lieu thereof an amendment providing for obedience to the autocratic authority of the Commission. (S. 3575 and H. R. 8337, 57th Congress, 1st Session, the same being identical.) This attempt to emasculate the Interstate Commerce Act was exposed and failed utterly. Thus did the Commission express to Congress and to the country its determined purpose, through a desperate expedient, to expunge from the Interstate Commerce law the power of the judiciary to participate in commercial I4 regulation and to acquire for itself an autocratic dispensing power over the commercial and transportation interests of this country. In this attempt the Commission went so far as to deny the truth of the published record of its own experiences. Four members of the Commission appeared before the Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce of the House of Representatives and declared that Congress ought to grant to it the power of rate making in order to prevent unreasonable rates and unjustly discriminating rates, at the same time asserting that rates were advancing. These state- ments were proved to be absolutely incorrect. It was shown that during the fifteen years of the existence of the Com- mission not a single case of exorbitant rates had been proved in the courts, that on the average only one case of unjust discrimination had been proved in each two and a Half years of the life of the Commission and that rail rates had been constantly falling for thirty-five years. In this connection the following historic facts were adduced : (a) The average rates charged on the railroads of the United States fell from 1.99 cents per ton per mile in 1870 to O.7O cents per ton per mile in 1890. This reduction upon the basis of tons carried in 1890 would have amounted to a saving to the people of the United States of nearly two thousand million dollars a year. (b) Data furnished by the Bureau of Statistics of the Treasury Department, clearly prove that from 1894 to 1901—the latest year of official data—the railroad freight traffic of the country increased 81 per cent, railroad receipts increased 61 per cent, railroad operating expenses increased I5 41 per cent, while the average rate charged decreased II 7% per cent. (c) Forced to concede this record of reduced rates in years past, the Commission sought to show that there is a present tendency toward an undue advancement in rates. But in this, also, it signally failed. The official record of the Interstate Commerce Commission shows that from 1899 to 1901 the railroad freight traffic of the country in- creased 17 per cent, railroad receipts from freight traffic increased 22 per cent, operating expenses increased 20 per cent, while rail rates increased only 4 per cent. This ad- vance in rates was much less than the advance in material required for railroad operation and much less also than the advance in wages of labor employed on railroads during a period of unprecedented prosperity marked generally by advancing wages and prices. The President of the Phila- delphia & Reading Railroad has recently declared that the . increase of wages on that road amounted to $1,2OO,OOO during the preceding year. In various parts of the country recent advances in wages of railroad employes range from 12 to 16 per cent. It is estimated by “The Railway News” that $100,000,000 represents the increase in pay rolls of the railroads of the country for the year 1892. It seems reasonable to admit that the railroads which feel the advance of prices and wages so keenly on the expense side should share at least to a limited extent on the side of receipts. (d) Mr. Knapp, Chairman of the Commission, sought to convince the House Committee on Commerce that the apparent decrease in rail rates since the year 1890 I6 was caused by the inordinate increase in the tonnage of low- priced freights such as coal and ores, but official data of the Government were adduced showing that the reverse was true, the tonnage of coal and ores having increased only 74 per cent while that of other freights increased about 86 per cent. (e) The Commission then had recourse to a misleading and fallacious statement. In order to inculcate the grossly er- roneous idea that the railroads of the country are habitually violating the provisions of the Act to Regulate Commerce, certain of its members declared that during the three pre- ceding years, 807 complaints of all sorts, or 269 a year, had been made to the Commission. This num- ber of complaints, however, was utterly insig- nificant in comparison with the total number of freight transactions, amounting to many millions a year. Besides, it was shown from the records of the Commission that 784, or 97 per cent, of the 807 complaints were dis- posed of by the Commission informally and without a Hearing, the complaints having been withdrawn, or the matters complained of having been corrected by the companies without subjecting the Commission to the trouble of a trial and the issuance of formal orders. Of the 23 cases heard and decided, or only 3 per cent of the complaints instituted, not a single case of unreasonable rates or of unjustly discriminating rates has been proved in the courts. This clearly demonstrated the correctness of Judge Cooley's declaration that the “Act to Regulate Commerce” tends to both reasonableness and equality of rate.” Thus instead of proving to the House Committee I7 that the present law is inadequate, Mr. Knapp's statement was the means of bringing to the attention of that Com- mittee the undeniable truth that the railroad companies are, in a remarkable degree, conforming to the require- ments of the Act to Regulate Commerce, and that the ad- ministration of the law, even in the hands of a commission bitterly opposed to its vital provisions, has proved to be not only adequate, but highly successful and beneficial. Furthermore, autocratic rate making, as advocated by the Commission, has been shown to be inapplicable to the cure of the evil of rate cutting; and therefore misdi- rected. With all its statements fatally wounded as to facts the Commission utterly failed to impress the 57th Congress with the correctness of its assertions or the soundness of its arguments. The bill which it advocated did not reach the first stage of legislation in the House of Representa- tives or in the Senate, and the status of the Commission before Congress was impaired. At various times the Commission has recommended that it be endowed with the power to order an increase of rates in order to maintain what it may regard as the proper re- lation of competition rates. No argument is needed in order to prove that such an exercise of the rate-making power would be exceedingly obnoxious to the people of this country. In another particular the Commission has repeatedly attempted to usurp authority and to override the law. The Act to Regulate Commerce declares that its provisions shall apply only to connected lines of railway “under a I8 common control, management or arrangement for a con- tinuous carriage or shipment.” But in defiance of this plain limitation of law, in the Maximum Rate Case, and in other cases, the Commission has attempted to adjust the rates on one line with reference to the rates on other lines in other parts of the country. This shallow attempt to exercise a dispensing power has been sternly repelled by the courts. An order of the Interstate Commerce Commission 111 regard to rates from Chicago and St. Louis to Wilmington, North Carolina, as compared with rates to other points in other States, has recently been reversed by Judge Thomas R. Purnell in the U. S. District Court at Raleigh, N. C. Any attempt to set in Inotion this attempted assertion of power would inevitably clash with the constitutional provision that “No prefer- ence shall be given by any regulation of commerce to the ports of one State over those of another.” Since January 1, 1892, when Judge Cooley retired from office, the Commission has neglected to avail itself of the powers of regulation conferred upon it by the Act to Regu- late Commerce, and as hereinafter shown has sought to gain autocratic power. It has denied that it is in any special manner responsible for the prevention of rate cutting ; it has opposed an amendment designed to strengthen the penal provisions of the act, and it has been derelict in the discharge of its duties with respect to rate cutting. All this was fully set forth in an argument which I had the honor to make before the Senate Committee on Interstate Commerce on June 6, 1902. In a word, during the last twelve years the Commission has persistently op- I9 posed the method of regulation prescribed in the Act to Regulate Commerce, and has as persistently advocated the adoption of an autocratic method of regulation through the exercise of a dispensing power. Thus far the Commission has signally failed before the courts and before Congress to secure the power to prescribe rates, to exercise a general dispensing power over the conduct of railroad transportation, to secure a part of the judicial function and to circumvent the judiciary. It has also completely failed to prove that the experiences of the country with respect to railroad rates justify its preten- sions. On the other hand, its own record proves beyond question that the regulation of the railroads provided in the Act to Regulate Commerce has been highly beneficent and successful. The Commission seems to have been misled by the mere frictional resistances and incidental evils of the grandest and most beneficent system of trans- portation that the world ever saw. THE FUTURE POLICY OF THE INTERSTATE COMMERCE COMMISSION. Notwithstanding its repeated failures to acquire auto- cratic power, the Interstate Commerce Commission is ap- parently as determined as ever to prosecute its claim before the 58th Congress when it shall convene in December next. This purpose was clearly indicated by Hon. Charles A. Prouty, Interstate Commerce Commissioner, in an address delivered before The American Economic Association at its last annual meeting. On that occasion Mr. Prouty declared in favor of a scheme, the effect of which would be to create a fourth branch of the National Government—“A Dispens- 2O ing Power in the United States.” This power, as he clearly indicated, would be as independent of the legislative, exe- cutive and judicial departments of the Government as those departments are of each other. His argument is based upon the following attempted syllogism—There is no negulation of raž/roads in the Onited States, since regula- tion 7mplies contro/, there 2s no control of raz/roads— hence there is no regulation. The infirmity of Mr. Prouty's syllogism lies in his prem- ises. The American Railroad System is thoroughly regu- lated and controlled by an all-pervading and effective system of self-government, which is amply supplemented by strenuous and effective State and National governmental regulation. There is no business in this country which is more completely the subject of legal restraint than is that of railroad transportation. “The railroads are regulated by States, by cities, counties, towns, village boards of trus- tees, school districts, and by almost every other political sub- division of the State.” The law of the common carrier and of the public highway and the decisions of the courts embrace volumes of regulation applicable to the conduct of railroad transportation, while the Act to Regulate Com- merce amplifies, extends and particularizes the regulative principles of the common law in its application to the rail- roads. It has been asserted by an eminent lawyer that “the railroad is held to a more rigid responsibility in the courts than any other litigant.” The judicial records of the country afford abundant proof of the correctness of this assertion. Besides, the published reports of the Government afford abundant evidence of the fact that the American 2I Railroad System is a most admirably regulated system of transportation. In the light of these facts the assertion of Mr. Prouty that there is no regulation or control of the railroads in this country is manifestly absurd. Mr. Prouty exposed his deep-seated aversion to any interference in the work of railroad regulation by the judicial authority—at once the protection of civil rights, the defense of public order and the palladium of liberty. He declared with re- spect to governmental regulation generally that “it cannot be done through the courts,” and expressed the belief that “any system of regulation—which give the Federal courts power to suspend and finally set aside the Orders of a com- mission must be of doubtful value.” So he proposed to eliminate the Federal judiciary from any participation what- ever in the work of regulation. Furthermore, Mr. Prouty would eliminate the legislative and present executive powers of government from any actual participation in the work of railroad regulation and assign the function exclusively to his proposed Dispensing Power in the United States. This he states as follows: “It is earnestly insisted that the freight rate is a com- mercial proposition which must be left to the laws of com- merce, with which the Gozerzzment cannot safely meddle.” In this he seems to have distinctly in mind a scheme which, in effect, would supersede the present powers of government. He recommends, therefore, that “the 1aws of commerce’” shall be administered by means of a duplex autocratic dispensing power completely outside of our present system of government. - Mr. Prouty then proceeds to explain the organic features of his plan as follows: It is to embrace first—the Com- 22 mission endowed with the autocratic power of prescribing all the interstate rates in the country. Referring to the “suggestion, to permit the Federal courts to review and set aside, if found unreasonable, the orders of the Com- mission ” he says, “it is very doubtful whether any such system can ever give satisfactory results,” and adds, “these questions are not of a judicial nature and cannot be intel- ligently passed upon by courts.” In this connection he says: “A court administers the law as it is laid down in statute or in precedent, the jury decides the fact upon the testi- mony of witnesses. Not so the Commission. Here is no precedent to be administered. No dispute generally arises as to the facts. The question is, what under these ad- mitted conditions shall be done? and this question is largely one of judgment.” And again : “Such a commission is an expert body, * * * its con- clusion must still rest in the good judgment of its mem- bers. Its decision is the act of an expert body.” He labors to prove that the work of the Commission should be purely that of a body endowed with dispensing power and not subject to the restraint of statute or pre- cedent or court. In all this he clearly begs the whole question. Having excluded any sort of judicial interference with the work of the Commission, Mr. Prouty proceeds to ex- plain the second part of his dual scheme of regulation. Conceding that the conclusions of the Commission ought to be subjected to some sort of review, he proposes a tri- bunal “in the nature of a commerce court” a tribunal 23 fully endowed with judicial attributes:–namely, the power “to make decrees and execute process,” to “hold office for life and to possess all the independence of judges.” Besides, its decisions are to be final. Mr. Prouty earnestly protests that his proposed commerce court shall not be in any manner subject to or related to the Federal judiciary, for he maintains that the matters to be reviewed by the proposed court are “not properly law questions,” but “the judgment of a quasi legislative body,” and, therefore, that “the review of such a judgment is not a judicial func- tion” and its proceedings “are not lawsuits,” the question to be decided in each case being “largely one of judg- ment.” Thus he proposes to create an administrative board, bear- ing the name of a court, and fully endowed with judicial attributes in the face of the constitutional provision that “the judicial power of the United States shall be vested in one Supreme Court, and in such inferior courts as the Congress may from time to time ordain and establish.” It goes without saying, that Mr. Prouty's proposed “Com- merce Court” would be simply an administrative bureau endowed with an autocratic dispensing power, and there- fore similar in character to his proposed commission. It is difficult to imagine a more glaring political solecism than the proposed commerce court endowed with judicial attributes, but without a judicial function or a legal duty to perform. Besides, as hereinafter indicated, the whole scheme is in a political sense revolutionary. Referring particularly to the questions which will come before this non-judicial court, Mr. Prouty says: “These 24 questions are not of a judicial nature and cannot be intelli- gently passed upon by courts”—meaning the Federal courts. He adds: “Federal judges are not selected for that purpose. Most of them have absolutely no experience in such matters. Their time is fully occupied with their proper duties, and the very nature of those duties in a measure unfits them to appreciate these questions.” The absurdity of this assumption is apparent. Commer- cial law—especially the law of the common carrier—has for many centuries engaged the studious thought of the judicial mind. Andyetitisgravely proposed by Mr. Prouty that all this knowledge which by a process of evolution has been incorporated into the very fibre of our civilization shall be set aside in favor of the emanations of the inner consciousness of a set of commissioners and of judges with- out judicial function, guided solely by their own introspec- tions as to the fitness of things. The peculiar misfortune of Mr. Prouty's reasoning, in this regard, consists in the historic fact that so many of the decisions of the Commission Have been overruled by the courts for manifest error in re- gard to commercial and economic considerations, which mark the particular function of the Commission. In defense of his theory Mr. Prouty says: “As well might it be provided that (the Federal) courts shall enforce the laws enacted by Congress, if such laws are in their judgment reasonable and just,” as “to permit the Federal courts to review and set aside, if found unreason- able, the orders of the Commission.” In this he clearly suggests that the orders of the Com- mission should have the same authority and dignity as the laws of Congress. The Supreme Court has declared that 25 public policy in certain cases is what the law directs, but presumably, it will be a long time before the people of this country will consent that public policy shall be what the Interstate Commerce Commission directs. - In a word, the dual organization which Mr. Prouty recommends consists of an autocratic administrative board supplemented by an autocratic reviewing board forming a duplex bureaucratic attachment to our present form of government and constituting a full blown DISPENSING Power. IN THE UNITED STATES. All that Congress and the Chief Executive would have to do with this new branch of the National Government would be to create it and grant it plenary power. According to Mr. Prouty's own description of his scheme it would scorn both the substantive and adjective provisions of the science of law and of government and convert this country into a vast commercial and industrial autocracy. Such a scheme would have as its most strik- ing historic parallel the form of government proposed by Jack Cade—“My mouth shall be the Parliament of Eng- 1and.” The substantial agreement between the views expressed by Commissioner Prouty and the official utterances of the Interstate Commerce Commission as hereinbefore noted, raises the presumption that the Commission fully approves the views expressed by him. As the proposition to create a dispensing power on the lines suggested by Mr. Prouty and according to ideas urged by the Commission during the last ten years will probably command the attention of the Chief Executive 26 and of Congress at its next session, it seems proper to con- sider the subject somewhat carefully upon its merits. WHAT IS INVOLVED IN THE PROPOSITION TO CREATE A DISPENSING POWER IN THE UNITED STATES. The nature and effects of a dispensing power, such as that proposed by the Interstate Commerce Commission, is not conjectural. It is historical. In all ages such power has been the antithesis of judicial authority and a concom- itant of tyranny and oppression. The exercise of the dis- pensing power through a bureaucratic despotism, in the age of Justinian, was an effective cause of the downfall of the Roman Empire. The political struggle in England over what Macaulay styles “that great anomaly known as the dispensing power” began with Magna Charta in 1215 and continued four hundred and seventy-three years. Dur- ing that period the people of England were divided upon the vital question which it involved. The idea of a dispens- ing power of government was finally blotted out for the English-speaking people by the “Declaration of Right” which terminated the British Revolution of 1688. In that document it was declared “that the dispensing power lately assumed and exercised had no legal existence.” (Macaulay's History of England, Vol. 2, p. 525.) This declaration constitutes a fundamental feature of the British constitution and is deeply engraven in the hearts and con- sciences of the people of England. The beheading of Charles I was an incident of the po- litical struggle just mentioned. Lord Coke, taking the extreme monarchical view declared that “absolute despotic 27 power in all governments must reside somewhere.” A hundred years later, however, Montesquieu clearly proved that such power is utterly incompatible with personal liberty. De Toqueville, in speaking of the administrative despot- ism involved in bureaucratic government says: “Such a power compresses, enervates, extinguishes and stupefies a people’” (American Democracy, Vol. 2, p. 333). A recent writer of ability in describing the evils of bureaucratic rule in the nations of continental Europe declares that “Re- publicanism and bureaucracy are incompatible existences.” (Greg, Miss., Essays, 2d Series, p. 55.) The idea of creating any sort of a governmental dispens- ing power in the United States was spurned by the men who formed the Constitution of 1787. In speaking of the disposition of the people of this country at the time of the framing of the National Constitution, Hon. Joseph H. Choate, our Ambassador to Great Britain has recently said : “But all agreed in a supreme dread of arbitrary power, whether it should be exercised by the executive, the legis- lative or the judiciary.” The framers of the Constitution were greatly influenced in their opposition to any sort of despotic exercise of govern- mental power by the utterances of Montesquieu in “Esprit des Lois” which Mr. Justice Holmes has characterized as “an epoch-making book.” Therein the vital importance of an independent judiciary was clearly explained. This view was highly commended by Hamilton and also by Judge Story. By way of illustration, Montesquieu pointed to the fact that certain monarchical countries of 28 Europe which respected the independent judicial authority were conservators of personal liberty, whereas the republics of Italy which governed through a body of magis- trates unrestrained by an independent judicial power were cruel despotisms. This is the particular type of dispensing power which Mr. Prouty proposes to have established in this country. Our own political history is full of instruction upon this subject. Under the Confederacy which existed prior to the year 1789 the power exercised by the States over the the internal commerce of the country embraced not only the power to regulate, but even the power to interdict inter- state trade. This led to commercial disorder and was fast tending to disunion. Hence there arose a coercive public sentiment in favor of depriving the States of that power. This sentiment, in turn, created a demand that the internal commerce of the country should be absolutely free, and that its foreign commerce should be impartially administered. Hence strenuous objection arose in the Constitutional Con- vention of 1787 to granting to the Congress of the United States any power whatever for the regulation of the internal commerce of the country. In the course of debate this ob- jection was modified by a proposition to grant such power by a two-third vote of both branches of Congress. But at last the limitation to the power of Congress to regulate commerce as expressed in the fifth clause of Section 9 of Article I of the Constitution was agreed to. That limita- tion reads as follows: “No preference shall be given by any regulation of commerce or revenue to the ports of one State over those of another.” It then became possible for 29 the convention to agree that Congress shall have power to pass laws regulative of commerce by a majority vote. And thus it stands in the Constitution. (Madison’s Journal of the Constitutional Convention). Besides there was at that time a prevalent and control- ling political sentiment in opposition to any attempt to de- volve upon a National Government any sort of responsibility for the commercial prosperity of the country or for deter- mining the course of its development. In the competitive struggles of life men submit to the results of their own interaction as to the inevitable, even unto death, but when the Government becomes openly and unmistakably the arbi- ter of their destinies and the author of their misfortunes, then murmurs of discontent will be heard, and unless the cause of discontent is removed will inevitably culminate in public disorder. This was clear to the men who founded our governmental institutions. The founders of the Republic also clearly saw that the attempt to control and direct the course of the development of the commerce of the country would fatally overload the National Government with jurisdiction. Besides, their oppo- sition to any form of autocratic authority over the business affairs of the people was supplemented by an abiding faith in the conservatism which inheres in the untrammelled interaction of forces. That faith, in connection with the constitutional provision and limitations just mentioned de- fines the policy of commercial liberty which has escorted this nation from the beginning and ever since has consti- tuted a muniment of our national character. Mr. Jefferson was the most conspicuous apostle of that faith and policy. 3O In his first message to Congress as President, transmitted December 8, 1801, he said: “Agriculture, manufactures, commerce and navigation, the four pillars of our prosperity, are the most thriving when left most free to individual enterprise.” If Mr. Jefferson could return to the scenes of this world he would undoubtedly add to the above enumeration RAIL- ROAD TRANSPORTATION as being by far the most con- spicuous exemplification of his noble faith in the con- servatism which inheres in the untrammelled interaction of commercial and industrial forces. From the foregoing, it clearly appears that the founders of our Government were radically opposed to anything in tle 11ature of a dispensing power or arbitrary power of any sort over the commerce of the country, and that the policy of free internal commerce which they established on this continent and which has ever since been firmly maintained repels any such scheme as that proposed by Mr. Prouty and his associates. Undoubtedly the people of this country, if again brought to the test, would as decidedly pronounce against any form of despotic rule as they did in 1787. As before stated, recourse to anything in the nature of a dispensing power was distinctly repudiated by Judge Cooley and his able colleagues who constituted the first In- terstate Commerce Commission. In the spirit of the founders they declared it to be “not consistent with sound principles of government,” and that such power has not been given to the Commission. Manifestly it conflicts with elementary principles of our civilization. But in the face of the world's experiences and especially 3I of our own history the Interstate Commerce Commission proposes to establish in this country a dispensing power under bureaucratic rule, its most objectionable form. Certain general observations suggest themselves in this connection : (a) Opposition to adherence to the fixed policy of the country, frequently finds expression in the declaration that new conditions demand new governmental expedients. This is freely admitted. That constitutions and laws and public policies should respond to the evolution of society may be regarded as an axiom of our aggressive civilization. But the admission does not justify the adoption of anti- quated bureaucratic methods, involving a dispensing power, which belongs to the dead past, which more than two- hundred years ago became archaic under constitutional government in Great Britain, which for more than a thous- and years has been the political antithesis of the judicial function, and which in every age has been a concomitant of tyranny and oppression. The use of the word dispensing, as here employed in its political sense, like the words /orestalling, regretting and engrossing, has so fallen into disuse that its original sig- nificance in that sense is almost forgotten. The revival of the expedient as an expression of the spirit of populism and of state-socialism justifies the revival of the designa- tion. (b) The idea is advanced by advocates of Commission rate making, that in addition to the power to condemn a particular rate on the ground of unreasonableness (which power the Commission now possesses) it should also be 32 authorized to declare what that rate shall be, or its maxi- mum limit, in the future. Whether the Commission does or does not now possess that power or may or may not constitutionally be endowed with that power, subject to judicial approval, need not here be discussed. But the advocates of Commission rate making go further and as- sume that such judicial sanction of a particle/ar rate ordered by the Commission would carry with it the de- termination of all other like charges—in a word that it would, or that by some statutory provision or legal pro- cess, not yet fully explained, it might be made to pro- ject that rate to the entire schedule of which it is a part. The assumption is clearly hypothetical. A fatal objection to such exercise of the judicial power arises. A particu- lar rate prescribed by a railroad company in a schedule applies to commodities and localities under a great variety of circumstances and conditions. Such application is dis- cretionary with the company. It is in the nature of a levelling process, not only justified, but enforced by com- mercial and economic conditions, and is highly promotive of the material interests of the country. But considera- tions of this sort cannot possibly control judicial procedure, for that would involve the exercise of the legislative func- tion by the courts, which is inadmissible under our form of government. Any unjust discrimination which might arise from the discretion exercised by the railroad com- panies can be corrected readily under provisions of the Act to Regulate Commerce which are strictly in accord with the rules of the common law. 33 THE MAGNITUDE OF THE WORK WHICH WOULD BE INVOLVED IN THE EXERCISE OF THE PROPOSED DISPENSING POWER IN THE UNITED STATES. The magnitude of the work which would devolve upon the proposed dispensing power in the United States is a consideration of the highest importance. It would be enormous. In its seventh annual report (1893) the Com- mission declared at pages IO and II, that it Ought to be in- vested not only with the power to determine rates, but also with the power to determine the relative commercial status of the various towns, cities, sections and industries of this vast country. This was expressed as follows: “To give each community the rightful benefit of location, to keep different commodities on an equal footing, so that each shall circulate freely and in natural volume, and to prescribe schedule rates which shall be reasonably just to both shipper and carrier is a task of vast magnitude and importance.” This evidently would be an enormous power. In its eleventh annual report (1897) the Commision de- clared that it ought to possess the power “to determine” rates, fares, charges and classifications, privileges, facilities or regulations,” and to “order schedules in accordance with the decision of the Commission.” In the same report (1897) at page 26, the Commission said in regard to the magnitude of the proposed work: “The amount of money involved would be much greater than that involved in the decision of any trial court in the United States. The results would usually be of more con- sequence to the litigants than those of any such court.” 34 There can be no doubt as to the correctness of this state- ment. The value of the property thus exposed to auto- cratic appraisement and determination in one year, might exceed the total value of all the property rights adjudi- cated by the Federal courts since the adoption of the Con- stitution. In the Maximum Rate Case the Supreme Court of the United States characterized the single proposition of Com- mission rate making as “a power so vast and comprehen- sive, so largely affecting the rights of carrier and shipper, as well as indirectly all commercial transactions.” The court also spoke of it as “the difficult problem of just and reasonable rates for all the various roads of the country.” In his recent address before the American Economic Association, Mr. Prouty stated that the organization in- vested with the dispensing power “would necessarily ren- der very many decisions.” This is undoubtedly true. He also proposed that it shall “deal with monopoly in other branches of interstate commerce,” which signifies that it should have control of the general anti-monopoly movement which now engages the attention of the country. Mr. Prouty also clearly indicated that the exercise of the proposed power would exclude the legislative, ex- ecutive and judicial branches of the Government of the United States from any actual participation in the work of regulation, and that it would admit no limitation upon the exercise of its authority except the personal judgment of the men; composing the two proposed “expert bodies' as to “conditions,” unfettered by court or law or precedent. In a word, his proposed method of regulation would con- 35 stitute an exclusive and inclusive autocratic dispensing power. A dispensing power in the United States which should embrace the functions and the scope of authority already indicated would manifestly carry with it the enormous task of supervising and directing the entire internal commerce, the transportation interests and indirectly the industrial in- terests of the country. The magnitude of the work of regulation thus involved would not be entirely discretionary with the exercise of the proposed dispensing power, but to a degree would be inaudatory upon it; for the existence of the power would carry with it an inevitable duty. The correctness of this assumption is clearly indicated by the experience of the Interstate Commerce Commission during the first two months of its existence. The Commission was then for a brief period led to admit tacitly that it was invested with the power to determine, in advance, under what circum- stances and conditions the right to charge more for the shorter than for the longer haul could be admitted. The demands upon the Commission for the determination of such questions proceeded alumost entirely from railroad companies. It was assumed by certain attorneys that me. glect to secure in advance the permission of the Commis- sion to make such changes would subject the companies to heavy penalties. These demands upon the time and attention of the Commission became exceedingly onerous. In denying the authority of the Commission to exercise such power, Chairman Cooley, speaking for the Commis- sion, declared on Julie, 15, 1887, that the assumed duty 36 was “superhuman,” adding that “a construction of the statute which should require its performance would render the due administration of the law altogether impracticable”; a conclusion which led that eminent lawyer and jurist, and his able coadjutors, to declare that “such a construction of the statute could not have been intended by the law-maker.” Therefore all thought of exercising any sort of dispensing power was utterly repudiated. Beyond all question, the sort of governmental regulation now urged for this country by Mr. Prouty and the Inter- state Commerce Commission would exert over its commer- cial, industrial and transportation interests an authority vastly greater than that ever exercised by Congress, by the President of the United States, by the Federal judiciary, or by all combined. It would, besides, reverse the commer- cial policy of non-interference with the interaction of com- mercial and industrial forces which was established at the beginning, which was strenuously upheld by Thomas Jeff- erson and his compatriots and which has safeguarded the material interests of this country ever since. As remarked in the beginning and as indicated by his- toric facts, the political evils which would result from the establishment of a dispensing power in this country would vastly outweigh all economic and commercial causes of complaint which now exist or which could be expected to arise as the result of a policy so impracticable and revolu- tionary. It is believed that if the office of the Commission in Washington were so enlarged as to enable it to perform all the functions which would devolve upon it under the pro- 37 posed dispensing power, it would be equal in magnitude to all the other offices of the present administrative gov- ernment of the United States. THE RIGHTS OF PROPERTY VIOLATED. In order to defend his scheme against the charge of vio- lating established principles of civilization in regard to the rights of property, Mr. Prouty was impelled to make the following admission: - “The railway rate is private property. Any unjust re- duction of that rate is an unjust taking of private pro- perty.” And again : “Such a commission should not make interstate railway rates. So long as railways are private property they should have the right to name their rates in the first in- stance, to determine what competitive conditions they will meet, what industries they will foster, what will be, in general, the policy of the road.” But immediately he proceeded to deny all this by declar- ing that the Commission and the proposed non-judicial court should be invested with plenary power to change all rates at will before they haze been charged and collected, thus making the Commission the actual rate maker and the dictator of the policy of the road in the first instance, through the exercise of a dispensing power which has no place in our governmental system, which, as before shown, excludes the Federal judiciary and which has no semblance of “due process of law,” thus violating a clearly expressed provision of the Constitution of the United States, and running counter to established principles of our civiliza- 38 tion regarding the rights of property. This monstrous proposition was emphatically negatived by the Supreme Court in the Maximum Rate Case, and has repeatedly been repelled by Congress. And yet this is precisely the power which the Commission, and the propaganda acting in its interest, now asks Congress to confer upon it. The glaring solecism involved in Mr. Prouty's professed respect for the rights of property and his concurrent proposi- tion to violate the rights of property suggests the importance of noting the broad line of distinction between regulation by preliminary judgment, involving the exercise of a dis- pensing power and regulation by an administrative board subject to proper judicial review. REGULATION BY PRELIMINARY JUDGMENT. At the beginning, the Commission, speaking by Judge Cooley, declared that it is not endowed with the power to administer the law “by preliminary judgment,” but now it asks Congress to grant to it the power to prescribe rates and to exercise certain administrative functions in regard to railroad transportation upon the ground of Inere appre- hended evils, and for the prevention of what it regards as dangers threatened by changes in economic and commercial conditions assumed to justify such action, but which, as hereinbefore demonstrated, have exhibited no tendency towards such dire results. In a word, the Interstate Com- merce Commission proposes to apply a hypothetical remedy to the cure of prospective evils revealed by its own intro- spection, but not verified by any actual result of experience. While it is a beneficent and necessary function of the 39 judicial power to enjoin threatened violations of positive law, the judiciary can never acquire the right to adjudicate prospectively upon what it may regard as probable economic results of commercial or industrial interaction. That would be undisguised judicial legislation which is not per- missible under our form of government. Time and again the lessons of experience have proved that such action would be unwise and grossly repressive of the ever chang- ing demands of a progressive age. In a word the evolution of economic and political conditions has not proceeded far enough in this world for judicial decisions based upon ap- prehended commercial and economic evils. Such power could not be entrusted to the courts without imminent danger of trespassing upon the fundamental principles of personal liberty; much less can an administrative board be allowed to project the adjustment of personal rights by pre- liminary judgment involving the exercise of a dispensing power. That also would conflict with fundamental princi- ples of our Government. The power exercised by administrative authority in the case of fire, famine, pestilence and war, the pardoning of criminal offenses, the deportation of objectionable immi- grants, also the prevention of the transportation of diseased animals and infected goods in obedience to the provisions of the police power of government is responsive to estab- lished rules of public policy. Such exceptional exercise of administrative authority bears no semblance whatever to the exercise of a discretionary power which would em- brace the essential attributes of legislation and expel the exercise of the judicial function with respect to the direc- 4O tion and control of the peaceful and lawful industrial oc- cupations of mankind amid the conflict of commercial, in- dustrial and financial forces, whose interaction involves those conservative elements of regulation, which for lack of more definite knowledge we designate as the law of supply and demand and of competition. This marks the substantial delimitation between the commercial power and the police power of government, however perplexing to the courts the distinction between the operation of these powers may be in concrete cases. Onited States z. A. C. Knight Co., I56 U. S., 13. The difference between prescribing rates in advance and correcting unreasonable charges after they have been charged and collected is the difference between attempting to direct men how to proceed aright in the conduct of their business affairs and punishing them after they have vio- lated express provisions of law. The former is paternal- ism—the latter is the administration of justice. The former is governmental imperialism—the latter is liberty regulated by law. This distinction is vital to our system of free government, for it discriminates between judicial authority and delegated legislative authority. As such it sharply defines the line of cleavage between ordered liberty and despotic rule. There is One Above who prejudges and predetermines, but that attribute does not pertain to mortal man. These elementary propositions appear to have been disregarded by the Interstate Commerce Com- mission in its struggle for autocratic power. 4 I A JUDICIAL OPINION QUOTED. Mr. Prouty attempts to defend his theory by quoting Mr. Justice Bradley who in speaking of the right to control railroad charges said: “But a superintending power over the highways and the charges imposed upon the public for their use always remains in the Government.” To assume for a moment that Mr. Justice Bradley enter- tained the idea that the governmental power of regulating commerce should be exercised as a dispensing power or in any manner not subject to judicial review as to the justice and reasonableness of rates charged would be to impeach the common sense of that eminent jurist, and to cast a blight upon his memory. Moreover it appears safe to say that it would be difficult to find a railroad manager in the United States who does not cheerfully admit the correctness of the above declara- tion of Mr. Justice Bradley. The “Artificial Man,” as the corporation is sometimes styled, is always subject to the law of his creator; and must humbly submit to the guid- ance and to the restraining and protecting care which such control implies. The fundamental question at issue is shall that control be exercised by virtue of a dispensing Aozo'er, or in accordance with the principles of our estab- lished system of triune government, which makes the ques- tion of right or wrong, of justice or injustice, of reason- ableness or unreasonableness depend at last upon the determination of “The Judicial Power of the United States,” that branch of the National Government which in point of wisdom is pre-eminently “Heir of all the ages, in the foremost files of time.” 42 THE BRITISH RAILWAY COMMISSION. Mr. Prouty declares that his proposed scheme is similar in character to the British Railway Commission. In this he is wide of the mark. The British Railroad Commission is a branch of the national judiciary, and its conclusions are strictly judicial decisions, such as the Interstate Com- merce Commission persistently repels and diligently seeks to avoid, in favor of the exercise of a dispensing power. Besides, the delimitation of legislative, administrative and judicial powers is not so closely drawn under the unwritten British Constitution as it is under the Constitution of the United States. The assumed analogy is without force. COMMISSIONER PROUTY'S AT TITUDE TOWARD THE RAILROADS. Mr. Prouty's attitude toward the railroads of the coun- try is hostile. In his address before mentioned he disre- garded all facts as to the enormous growth of the Ameri- can Railroad System—from 70,000 miles in 1873 to about 200,000 miles in 1893—its greatly increased efficiency, the reduction in the average charge to nearly one-third the average charge imposed thirty years ago, involving a total reduction in freight charges of nearly two thousand million dollars a year, the fact that in the sixteen years of the life of the Commission it has not been able to prove in the courts the existence of a single exorbitant rate and only one case of unjustly discriminating rates in each two and a half years, and that of the complaints made to the Com- mission 97 per cent are settled through its mediatorial offices, whereas only 3 per cent come to a formal hearing before the Commission. Ignoring all these guiding facts, Mr. Prouty adopted the expedient of referring to certain 43 particular rates which , appear to him to be unreasonable, because they have been advanced in a constant readjustment of rates throughout the country, ignoring concurrent re- ductions in rates. From the exceptional cases which he Selects he predicts danger. He declares that combination has destroyed competition, and that therefore rates must become exorbitant, whereas it has been demonstrated time and again that the restraints which have been placed upon competition during the last thirty years, by association, by compact, and by actual combination or merger of interests have been compelled by the necessity of maintaining order in the conduct of the internal commerce of this country. Besides, such restraints have secured efficiency in railroad transportation and just and reasonable rates. These re- straints upon destructive competition have almost invariably been accompanied by a fall in rates. Not satisfied with the foregoing statements Mr. Prouty expresses himself in the following outburst of feeling : “The railroad, the railroad combination is one of the most subtle and dangerous instrumentalities in effecting an unjust distribution of wealth by taking from the poor man wrongfully and giving to the rich ; ” “railway trans- portation is to-day a monopoly ;” “with respect to inter- state transportation the public has no safeguard against railroad monopoly;” the country is confronted by “the danger which always attends monopoly, the exaction of an unreasonable rate;” the only way to control monopoly is to “control the charge which it exacts.” This is hysteria. It exhibits a spirit which expels the semblance of fair dealing. Such language is without the shadow of excuse in actual experience and is utterly 44 repudiated by facts patent to the general observation, Some of the more important of which have herein been noticed. The railroads of the country from the beginning have been to the shipper and the traveler, as free as are the natural highways of commerce. The common law, the laws of every State, the laws of the United States and the usages of railroad transportation maintain that freedom. The pretense of Mr. Prouty that the railroads are able to defy the law and the public sentiment of the country re- garding established principles of right and justice is with- out afly foundation in fact. Time and again the allegations of Commissioner Prouty and his colleagues as to unreason- able rates, or the apprehension of unreasonable rates, have been absolutely refuted. During its existence the Com- mission has been unable to sustain its declarations in this regard before the courts or before the committees of Con- gress. There is also on all sides abundant proof that the railroads have been forceful and efficient agencies in the development of the natural resources of the country, in the creation of new and far-reaching elements of competition in industry, in trade and in transportation ; in the distribu- tion of wealth ; in furnishing occupation to labor; in the enhancement of wages, and in promoting the general wel fare. THE INTERSTATE COMMERCE COMMISSION ANTAGONIZES THE FEDERAL JUDICIARY. In its various attempts during the last ten years to ac- quire dispensing power the Interstate Commerce Com- mission has persistently antagonized the Federal judiciary. Notwithstanding the fact that the law creating it does not 45 require that any one of its members shall be a lawyer, the Commission has not hesitated to assert its opinions as against that of the great lawyers of the Supreme Court, both in regard to questions of fact, and to legal and con- stitutional questions, as well as in regard to questions of public policy which especially concern “The Judicial Power of the United States.” In twenty cases adjudicated since it was organized the Commission has resorted to the courts for judicial aid in the enforcement of its autocratic and un-American pretentions and in such instances it has been overruled not only on legal and constitutional grounds, but also on commercial and economic considerations. The orders of the Commission which have failed to secure the approval of the courts have been clearly proved to be illegal orders—completely outside the powers conferred upon it by law. It is for this reason mainly that its various appeals to Congress for additional powers have been dis- regarded. The Commission has also strenuously attempted to usurp the powers of the judiciary, to override the judiciary and to circumvent the judiciary. On the other hand the courts have patiently pointed out the excellent and benefi- cent features of the Act to Regulate Commerce and the powers of the Commission for good, and have manifested an earnest desire to co-operate with the Commission in effectuating the exercise of its undoubted authority in the direction of beneficent regulation. But the Commission has been persistent in its efforts to secure autocratic dis- pensing power and to free itself from judicial restraint. In reply to a resolution of the Senate dated April 23, 1900, 46 the Commission explained that the principal cause of its ill-success in the courts had arisen from the difference of views entertained by the Commission and by the Supreme Court of the United States on a fundamental principle of government. (Senate Document No. 319, 56th Congress, Ist session). The charge of undue modesty, as against the Commission, has never been sustained in the courts or elsewhere. CONCLUSION. It was stated at the beginning that the proposition to invest the Interstate Commerce Commission with the auto- cratic power to prescribe rates for transportation services in this country, is an expression of current populistic thought, fraught with danger to the commercial interests and the political integrity of this country. It was also premised that the evils which would thus be incurred would greatly exceed in magnitude any real or imaginary evils which the proposed expedient is intended to remove. An attempt has been made to prove the correctness of these statements. At first the Commission, guided by Judge Cooley, de- clared that the creation of a dispensing power “would not be consistent with sound principles of government.” Sub- sequently the Commission repudiated that doctrine, and has repeatedly asked Congress to confer upon it such power. This proposition has been steadily refused. The history and present status of the American Railroad Sys- tem as a public utility constitutes the most striking refuta- tion of this conception whether it be called populism, 47 paternalism, anti-trust, anti-monopoly or state-socialism. With its 200,000 miles in length, a traffic of over one thousand million tons and over six hundred million pas- sengers carried annually, there has not been proved in the courts a single case of exorbitant rates during the sixteen years of the existence of the Commission, and only one case of unjust discrimination in each two and a half years. At the same time the facilities for transportation have been wonderfully improved and rates have been greatly reduced. This indisputable record affords a splen- did vindication of the faith of the fathers in the conserv- atism which inheres in the untrammelled interaction of forces. It is a faith which may appear shadowy to the populistic mind, beguiled by the idea of governmental omniscience, but it is conformable to the unalterable and potential laws of trade which governments must protect, and with which they cannot safely interfere without tres- passing upon human rights. The subject of governmental rate making involves im- portant constitutional questions, which cannot here be dis- cussed, but may be mentioned : I. It is inconceivable that a power of government so enormous that it could eliminate the “Judicial Power of the United States” and practically supersede any actual participation by the legislative and executive departments of the Government in the work of regulating the internal commerce of the country, as has been seriously proposed, could possibly be brought into being except through a radical change in the Constitution of the United States. 2. It is inconceivable that the delegation of legislative 48 power, so extensive as that proposed by the Interstate Commerce Commission, could possibly be conferred except by constitutional amendment. The rule of constitutional law that Congress has no power to delegate its legislative authority is a recognized political axiom. This was clearly enunciated by Mr. Chief Justice Marshall in Weyman vs. Southard, Io Wheaton, p. 42. In the face of the outcry against monopoly the fact stands that we live in an age of unparalleled material prosperity due to the accomplishment of great things through great agencies. The most marked success of the National Government has been achieved through its com- mercial policy. In the light of these irrefutable facts, the representations of populistic advocates of reform in this regard are a jeremiad on prosperity, and a satire on benefi- cent results. They tend to disturb a faith in the be- neficence of our political institutions which should be as an anchor to every patriotic soul. It is not denied, but is strenuously maintained, that evils affecting our transportation system should be arrested by means of wholesome and efficient governmental regulation. As stated in the beginning, the main object of this paper is to oppose asserted remedies which are deemed to be revolutionary, grossly excessive and prejudicial to the public interests. Ample power exists under our present form of government for the correction of evils incident to our transportation system, which may be properly the sub- ject of governmental concernment. This has been proved by the experiences of seventy years. The wild theory of conferring autocratic power upon 49 an administrative board, and the affiliated idea of confer- ring judicial authority upon administrative bodies, sets at defiance the fundamental principle of democratic govern- ment. Such propositions, as a rule, involve the expedient of depriving the judiciary of the power to determine the reasonableness of contracts in restraint of, or regulative of, trade, a power which lies at the basis of all commercial law, and is essential to the maintenance of the orderly conduct of the business interests of the country. A11 schemes of this sort involve the creation of a dispensing power of government which is antagonistic to our political system. This would constitute a recrudescence of the impracticable. As already shown, a dispensing power, not only vitiates, but extinguishes the very essence of free government. It has been repeatedly tried, and in all ages has been proved to be incompatible with the exigencies of liberty, and the protection of human rights. And yet the spirit of populism and of state-socialism is abroad in the land and finds expression in favor of govern- mental supervision of the commercial and industrial affairs of the country. Such un-American and revolutionary ideas constitute an assault not only upon the structural features, but upon the very genius of our governmental institutions. To a greater or less extent they pervade all parties and all classes of our citizens, and apparently for the reason that the antiquated character of the expedients proposed and their proven impracticability have not been properly con- sidered. The revolutionary idea of governmental supervision and administration of the commercial and industrial affairs of 5O the country involving the creation of a Dispensing Power pervades the entire anti-trust and anti-monopoly pro- gramme of the present day, in the face of the fact that the country has enjoyed an unprecedented degree of prosperity under the government as now constituted. The people who advocate such impractical theories seem to lose sight of Hamilton’s exalted conception of human government, namely, that it should not only be able to govern the people beneficially, but also that it should be able to govern itself. This was a problem of the ages, to the solution of which the men of 1787 added the finest contribution. Their conclusion was firmly based upon the incontrovertible fact that human law and human govern- ment is essentially a science of adaptations, wrought out by human experiences, and not the product of any assumed eternal fitness of things. In treating of the important questions to which this paper relates, attention has been directed particularly to their political aspects as indicated by commercial and eco- nomic conditions. Such considerations naturally precede the legislative and judicial questions involved. As re- cently remarked by Judge Coit of the Federal judiciary before the American Bar Association, “society in progress- ive nations is always in advance of the law. The evolu- tion of law follows and never precedes the evolution of society.” In this view the consideration of the political effects of the revolutionary proposition to establish a dis- pensing power in the United States is of vastly greater importance than any or all of the political issues upon 5T which the people of this country are now divided. It overshadows all other political questions which agitate the public mind. Hence it appears that in a country like ours, where great questioning is determined in the light of reflective judgment, the first step toward the philosophical consideration of the proposition to establish a dispensing power in the United States is to make the whole matter the subject of a thorough and impartial congressional in- vestigation, having regard particularly to the commercial, economic and political questions involved. This article has been prepared for the purpose of indicat- ing certain questions involved in the broad field of inquiry to which it relates, with special reference to the American Railroad System and our internal commerce. If it shall in any degree tend to promote such investigation as that sug- gested the object had in view will have been fully accom- plished: No. 1831 F St. N. W., Washington, D. C., October 17, 1903. ist, 1831 F ST RE ET N. W. W. As H ! N. GTO N, D. C. d Econorrh IC 1&l Iſl alſh. lATE PRESIDENT OF T H E N AT ON AL STAT I STICAL association.) Statist (FoRMER CH EP OF BURE AU OF STAT ISTICS N THE TREASURY DEPART ME NT AND $ PEC E A L A TT E R T o N G IV E N TO Q U E STI O W, is N. W. E. G. & A D T © JOSEPH NIMMO, JR., LONG IS LAN D, N. Y. C O M M ER CE, TRAN SPC RTA Ti O N, NAV 1 GATE O N A N D : N D USTRY. H U NT IN GTO N, 3 9015 O7375 8131 2 Li- O >- H- (UD CD LLI > 2 D ------***===|- ---!~ ~ ~ * *. ---- ſaeſae#!!!!!ſaeſae!!!!!!!!!! №;∞ √∞;¿№ſſae ±,±,±,±,±,±,±),saeaetae, , , , * ±,±,±,±,±,±,±,±§§§)ſaeae ·ſae +(№º!!!!!!!!!!! !!!!!!!!£ - aewºº, ***-ae zºſsae≡≡:::::::::::sae ſ!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!, :) ~~---- |-±,±,±,±,±,±,±: ±,±,±,±,±,±,± •••• •* -----•، ، ، ،q. . . . .ae …!!!!!!!!--~~~~، ، ،--. . . . . . ………..……* „…aeĒĖĘ~ !··m.·, !!!!!!±* (~~~~ ~~~~!!!!!::::::::::::№tae ---- · ، ،æ*** ae - wae,ſae º ſ = º; - ae•·,· ·، ∞№ º- ~ ſ- ►►- ±±,±,±,±,±,±),ºlae si►,…,-••gºs:(±±• Zºe, №iſaesaevae- Æ!!!!!!!!!! ---- £№±,±,±,±,±,±,±),- ----Ź№∞∞∞|- ſae ae§§ºº:::-!!!!!seºſaeſº№ſae №№№:№i: №!!!!,,,*!***!**= -~~~~,ſae№ae,∞- ſ !!!!!!!!!!!!!±:!-!!!!■■■■ae-•••ae (~~~~ae£×*±,±,±,±,±),± -----C№Ēſae!!!!!!!!!!!!!№zī£№ſſºſ|- №ae,º:■■■■*******): - -¿№.3,ſae*****