-^ ^ VO, VI AUG 14 1979 <2 «-, A* 2 Regulatory Reform Seminar PROCEEDINGS AND BACKGROUND PAPERS ^r ES O* •" / U.S. DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE Office of the Secretary , ■ ■ Regulatory Reform Seminar PROCEEDINGS AND BACKGROUND PAPERS Host: Juanita M. Kreps, Secretary Chairman: Jerry J. Jasinowski, Assistant Secretary for Policy Sponsor: Lucy Falcone, Deputy Assistant Secretary for Policy Coordination: Office of Regulatory Economics and Policy Robert T. Miki, Director, Marian L. Forbes, Editor of Papers and Proceedings, William B. Sullivan, Bruce G. Humphrey, Roger J. Mallet, Mark S. Reinsberg Anna Maria Kinser and Kelly L. Dawson 0* ° F *o, o o & o *«n o c a a to * 9 IE, % J U.S. DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE Office of the Secretary October 17, 1978 - 1 INTRODUCTION I am pleased to make available the proceedings and background papers of the Regulatory Reform Seminar hosted by the Department of Commerce on October 17, 1978. The purpose of the seminar was to obtain the views of a diverse group on the subject of regulatory reform in order to determine major areas of consensus and disagreement, and to identify those areas where additional research would be helpful. The seminar covered three broad areas: the costs and benefits of regulation; institutional mechanisms for improving the regulatory system; and alternative regulatory techniques and alter- natives to regulation. The participants included corporate executives, senior government officials, academic scholars, and representatives of public interest organizations . Our discussion was marked by greater consensus than might be expected from a group reflecting such diverse backgrounds, perspectives, and positions. Clearly, there was willingness among business, government, and other participants to find a common ground for cooperation. There was a general appreciation of the enormity of the problem and the need for a better understanding of the nature, scope, magnitude, and effects of the present regulatory system. At best, there are indicators of the magnitude of the cost of regulations — in the neighborhood of $100 billion — but little perspective on what the ramifications are of such a magnitude relative to benefits. There is sketchy perspective also on the widely varying processes that make up the regulatory system. The discussion of costs and benefits reached a consensus that the assessment of costs and benefits should be an integral part of the regu- latory process. It was recognized that there are difficult measurement problems. Data inadequacies and biases in estimates were frequently cited as two of the major problems. There were divergent views on the appropriate weighing of health vs economic considerations. Some parti- cipants emphasized that attainment of the health protection goal is the overriding consideration. Others contended that even in such cases, regulation could be framed so that more people are protected for the same (or less) expenditure of resources. This polarization of views was not reconciled. The discussion of costs and benefits highlighted a very important point — the need to distinguish between "cost" and "economic impact." Cost generally refers to the cost of compliance and, in a complete accounting, would include administrative, legal, information, compliance, and other costs resulting from regulations. Economic impact, on the other hand, includes a consideration of the direct and indirect effects of regulation (the effect of regulation of one industry on a related industry, for example) and the incidence of a regulation (who benefits i 11 and who bears the cost) . Economic impact also includes consideration of positive or negative effects on technological change, economic growth, industry structure and performance, and international trade. How clearly we make the distinction between costs and economic impact can significantly affect perceived choices and priorities in regulation. There was general agreement on the need to improve regulatory processes at the agency level. Although processes vary by agency and are extremely complex, several common regulatory weaknesses were highlighted in the seminar. These were: unnecessary burdens associated with paperwork, inadequate consideration of cost-effective alternatives, and the lack of procedures to eliminate or modify outdated regulations. In these regards, Executive Order 12044, "Improving Government Regulations," was considered to be a good basis for improvement. Many participants felt that the provisions of the Executive Order should be extended to cover the inde- pendent regulatory agencies, many of whom are voluntarily complying with the Executive Order. The Regulatory Analysis Review Group (a senior level interagency group composed of Executive Branch representatives) was mentioned as an important element in improving analyses of regulations. The Regulatory Analysis Review Group analyzes specific regulations, thereby encouraging agencies to improve their own analyses. It was also noted that we should not overlook the work that agencies themselves have advanced: to eliminate unnecessary regulations, such as the Occupational Safety and Health Administration's elimination of nearly 1,000 outdated rules; to develop innovative alternative methods of regulation, such as the Environmental Protection Agency's offset policy to improve the Nation's air quality; and to coordinate, on an interagency basis, the control of toxic substances. The participants endorsed efforts to seek regulatory measures that are less disruptive in their effects and are more incentive oriented. It was generally recognized that: incentive measures should be considered on a case-by-case basis; criteria should be developed to determine con- ditions under which specific forms of alternatives to regulations are appropriate; and alternative methods may increase the government's administrative costs but lead to lower social costs attributable to a particular regulation. Alternative approaches include deregulation. Within the area of economic regulations, the participants agreed on the merits of deregula- tion, as has been accomplished, for example, in air transportation. Although specific measures were not discussed in depth, it was noted that further opportunities for deregulation exist in surface freight trans- portation (trucking and rail) and communication. The participants felt that much more work needs to be done to assess more adequately regulations in a context broader than that of a single agency. Regulations frequently interact and the tradeoffs and cumulative effect must be more fully taken into account in establishing priorities. Ill There was general endorsement of the "sunset review" of regulations, perhaps because it represents a good balancing of the views and prerogatives of competing power centers. Such a periodic review was considered appropriate for both economic and social regulations. In the discussion of institutional mechanisms for better management, it was recognized that congressional mandates vary markedly — in some cases specifying in great detail the nature, form, and timing of regulations; in other cases, providing broad guidelines under which regulatory agencies are to formulate regulations. As a result, there are marked differences in the ways regulatory agencies operate and respond to economic and social problems. Some participants felt that regulatory objectives are met effectively by decentralized management, i.e., by the agency authorized to implement the congressional mandate. Others felt the regulatory system has become so large and complex that more centralized Executive Branch oversight is necessary to reduce the overlaps and conflicts created by each regulatory agency going its own way. There was considerable diver- sity of opinion on the appropriate roles of the Congress, the Executive Office of the President, and the Executive Branch in the management of the regulatory system, [shortly after the seminar, the President established the U.S. Regulatory Council, which is assigned the role of providing an overview of the regulatory system and examining issues that cut across agency lines. The Regulatory Council has issued a "Calendar" of forth- coming regulations and will continue to do so on a semiannual basis.] A new institutional means to gain greater overview and management — a "regulatory budget" — was discussed by the participants. Regulatory agency and public interest participants expressed concerns about the uses of a regulatory budget. Business, academic, and nonregulatory Federal repre- sentatives felt that the concept has merit but further exploratory work is necessary. They emphasized, as we recognize, that a full-blown regulatory budget is many steps away. Aside from legal, organizational, and adminis- trative issues, initial conceptual problems, such as the development of acceptable documentation of costs and the appropriate consideration of benefits, need to be resolved. A pilot project, which is an appropriate next step, is underway within the Department of Commerce. We expect it to show the difficulties that are involved and provide more documentation on the feasibility of a regulatory budget. I have sketched above what I consider to be the major points of the seminar discussion. The reader will find a greater discussion of the issues and problems in the proceedings and background papers . From the Department's standpoint, the seminar was very productive. Perhaps our only regret was that time did not permit us to push further into these and other areas of regulatory concerns. We will try to do so in subsequent seminars. liowski retary for Policy Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2012 with funding from LYRASIS Members and Sloan Foundation http://archive.org/details/regulatoryreformOOregu V REGULATORY REFORM SEMINAR Contents Page PROCEEDINGS OF THE SEMINAR 1 PARTICIPANTS 3 Impacts of Regulations 8 Management of Regulatory Policy 27 Alternative Techniques for Achieving Regulatory Goals. ... 48 Wrapup 64 BACKGROUND PAPERS 75 PREFACE TO BACKGROUND PAPERS 77 Costs and Benefits of Regulation : A Survey of Studies A-l Summary A-3 Table of Contents A-5 Synopsis A- 7 Summary Tables on Costs of Government Regulation A-13 Annotations of Studies on the Impact of Government Regulation A-29 Extensive Bibliography on Regulatory Impact Studies A-125 Data Sources on the Costs of Government Regulation A-139 Index A-149 The Regulatory Budget : Concepts and Information Requirements B-l Summary B-3 Table of Contents B-ll Introduction B-13 The Conceptual Framework B-14 Budget Presentation B-31 Information Requirements B-49 Alternatives to Regulation : Possibilities; Experience; Prospects C-l Summary C-3 Table of Contents C-ll Introduction C-13 Alternative Approaches C-17 Criteria C-23 Use of Alternatives C-28 VI BACKGROUND PAPERS (cont'd.) Page Synopsis C-42 Annotated Bibliography C-44 Bibliography C-55 Impact of Regulation on Industrial Location Decisions . . . . D-l Summary D-3 Table of Contents D-9 Scope and Objectives of Report D-ll Potential Impacts of Clean Air Acts on Industrial Location . D-21 Use of Analytic Decisionmaking Locational Models D-37 Predicting the Importance of Federal Regulations in Specific Location Decisions D-55 Concluding Remarks D-64 Appendix: Annotated Bibliography D-67 Index D-175 V1X Charts , Tables, and Figures Page PROCEEDINGS OF THE SEMINAR Chart 1 Impacts of Regulation 9 Chart 2 Possible Actions to Improve the Regulatory- System 28 Chart 3 Alternative Approaches and Their Major Variants 50 BACKGROUND PAPERS Costs and Benefits of Regulation : A Survey of Studies Table 1 Impact of All Regulations on the National Economy A-15 Table 2 Impact of Multiple Regulations on the National Economy A-16 Table 3 Impact of Multiple Regulations on a Specific Group or Industry A-18 Table 4 Impact of a Single Regulation on the National Economy A-20 Table 5 Impact of Single Regulations on a Specific Group or Industry A-25 Table 6 Data Sources A-26 Table 7 Economic Loss from Regulation of Surface Freight, 1960s A-38 Table 8 A Comparison of Effects of Selected Environ- mental Programs on Macroeconomic Variables A-48 Table 9 Summary of Estimated Costs of Regulations Considered A-61 Table 10 Summary Distribution of Pollution Control Costs as a Percent of Family Income (1972) A-68 Table 11 Summary Distribution of Pollution Control Costs as a Percent of Family Income (1976) A-69 van Costs and Benefits of Regulation (continued) Page Table 12 Summary Distribution of Pollution Control Costs as a Percent of Family Income (1980) A-70 Table 13 Distribution of Capital Requirements for Environmental Control of the Steel Industry of the United States by Type of Pollution A-75 Table 14 Steel Industry Operating Costs Associated With Achieving Compliance With Long-Term Environmental Control Regulations, by Type of Pollution A-75 Table 15 Summary of Iron and Steel Industry Capital Requirements A-76 Table 16 Projected Steel Industry Capital Costs of Environmental Control , By Type A-76 Table 17 Major Features of the Health Care Insurance Plan Supported by the American Medical Association, 1974 A-91 Table 18 Major Features of the Long-Ribicof f Catastrophic Health Insurance and Medical Assistance Reform Plan, 1974 A-92 Table 19 Major Features of the National Health Insurance Plan Supported by the Administration, 1974 A-93 Table 20 Major Features of the National Health Care Services Plan Supported by the American Hospital Association, 1974 A-94 Table 21 Major Features of the National Health Insurance Plan Supported by the Health Insurance Association of America, 1974 A-95 Table 22 Major Features of the Kennedy-Mills National Health Insurance Plan, 1974 A-96 Table 23 Major Features of the Health Security Plan Supported by the AFL-CIO ( Kennedy -Gr if f iths Bill), 1974 A-98 Table 24 Federal, State, and Private Expenditures for Alternative National Health Insurance Plans, Based on Prices and Population Projected for 1975 A-100 IX Costs and Benefits of Regulation (continued) Page Table 25 Federal Tax Subsidies under Alternative National Health Insurance Plans, 1975 A-101 Table 26 Increases in Federal Costs under Alternative National Health Insurance Plans, by Source of Increase, 1975 A-102 Table 27 Employer Contributions and Subsidies, Enrollment, and Premiums for Alternative National Health Insurance Plans, 1975 A-103 The Regulatory Budget : Concepts and Information Requirements Fig. 1-A Economic Policy and the Budget: Current Process B-21 Fig. 1-B Economic Policy, the Budget and Regulatory Policy: Proposed Integration B-22 Table 1 Hypothetical Government Cost Account for a Mine Safety Program B-32 Table 2 Object Classification: Mine Safety Program B-34 Table 3 Private Sector Costs of Mine Safety Regulations B=-35 Table 4 Private Sector Costs of Mine Safety Regulations by Object Classification B-36 Table 5 Coal Mine Safety Regulation Program Effects B-38 Table 6 Costs Imposed by Mine Safety Requirements on Other Program Activities B-39 Table 7 Mine Safety Budget Authority B-41 Table 8 Mine Safety Regulatory Authority B-42 Table 9 Aggregate Mine Safety Costs - B-43 Table 10 Format for Summary of Costs of Mine Safety Regulation B-44 Table 11 Prospective Methods for Collecting Cost Information B-55 Alternatives to Regulation : Page Possibilities; Experience; Prospects Table 1 Alternative Approaches and Their Major Variants C-18 Fig. 1 Criteria for Evaluating Alternatives to Regulation C-27 Table 2 Nationwide N0 X Emission Estimates, 1976 C-30 Table 3 Summary of Evaluation Criteria C-37 Impact of Regulation on Industrial Location Decisions , , Relative Importance of Factors in Industrial Location D-6 Table 1 Air Quality Control Regions Expected to Exceed the National Standards for Total Suspended Particulates by the Statutory Deadline D-23 Table 2 Significant Deterioration and Classes of Areas D-25 Table 3 Clean Air Act Actions, Responsible Agency, and Some Possible Impacts D-33 Table 4 1976 Needs Survey Forecasts for Municipal Wastewater Treatment Facilities D-39 Table 5 States Where State and Local Average Annual Share of Capital Expenditure Exceeds Ten Percent of Total State and Local Borrowing (Categories I Through V) D-40 Table 6 Analytic Model for Estimating Interregional Effects of Air Pollution Legislation D-45 Table 7 Control System Direct and Looped Relation- ships Between Decisionmakers of Various Hierarchical Levels and Each of the Elements of the Decision Environment D-49 Table 8 Flow Diagram of Analytical Approach to Assessment of Environmental -Economic Relationships D-53 Table 9 Allowable Air Quality Increments Under Alternative Significant Deterioration Proposals D-58 XI Impact of Regulation on Industrial Location Decisions Page (continued) Table 10 Proposed Best Available Control Technology (BACT) Definitions (House) D-59 Table 11 Proposed BACT Definitions (Senate) D-60 Table 12 Facility Closings Involving Pollution Abatement Requirements D-62 PROCEEDINGS OF THE SEMINAR U. S. Department of Commerce Regulatory Reform Seminar Participants EULA BINGHAM, ASSlSta.nl Secretary ior Occupational Safety and Health Li. S. Ve.pasitme.nt oi labor BARRY P. BOSWORTH, ViXCCtor Council on Wage and VhA.ce Stability FLETCHER L. BYROM, Chairman Koppesis Company, Inc. and Committee ftost Economic Vevelopment FRANK T. CARY, Chairman Jnternatlonal Business Machines Costp. edwin t. clark, ii, Special Assistant to the Administrator Environmental Protection Agency ion. Barbara blum, Veputy Admlnls tstato r allen r. Ferguson, President Public Interest Economics Center. mark green, Vlrector Congress Watch thomas d. hopkins, Assistant Vlrector Council on Wage and Price Stability hendrik s. houthakker, Proiessor oi Economic* Harvard University MARVIN H. KOSTERS, VlTCCtor Center ior the Study oi Government Regulation American Enterprise Institute ior Public Policy Research Richard l. lesher, President The Chamber oi Commerce oi the United States Keith r. mckennon, Vlrector oi Public Aiialsis The Vow Chemical Company ior paul f. oreffice, President john r. meyer, 7 907 Foundation Proiessor oi Transportation, Logistics and Vlstrlbution Harvard Business School WILLIAM D. NORDHAUS, Mmb&l CounelZ o{ Economic kdvlAenA ALICE M. RIVLIN, VlAeeton. Congnet>i> tonal Budget 0{{lee CHARLES L. SCHULTZE, CkaJJimCLVl CounelZ o{ Economic kdvti>enj> v. kerry smith, ToJULow, Quality o{ the Environment division Renounce* {on. the Vutuxe albert t. sommers , Senlon Ulee Vnehldent and Chle{ Economist The Con{enenee Bo and W. HARRISON WELLFORD, Executive ki,i>Oclate VVtldtOH. {on. Reon.ganlzatU.on and Management 0{{lee o{ Management and Budget U. S. DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE JUANITA M. KREPS SecAetany SIDNEY HARMAN linden. Seen.etan.ij JERRY J. JASINOWSKI A&ilAtant SeenetaAy {on. Policy C. L. HASLAM General Counsel COURTENAY M. SLATER Chle{ Economist LUCY FALCONE deputy ki>t>u>tant Seenetany {on Volley PROCEEDINGS OF THE SEMINAR October 17, 1978 SECRETARY KREPS : Good morning. I want to welcome all of you to this, what we consider very important, meeting. It is on a subject that is very much in our minds as your attendance indicates it is in yours. Since the Nation first embraced regulation as a solution to economic problems with the formation of the Interstate Commerce Commission in 1877, we have turned increasingly to regulation as a way of achieving social ends. These regulatory efforts have borne a great deal of fruit. Regulation has insured the availability of goods and services. It has given us a cleaner environment, safer and healthier work places, safer food and drugs, more fuel efficient automobiles. We tend to take for granted the benefits of regulation, although in many cases, we don't know precisely how to quantify the benefits that are forthcoming. But we are becoming increasingly aware that regulation also affects particular sectors and economic growth overall. Moreover, public concern about inflation coupled with a seemingly popular anti- ' government sentiment is being translated now into a call for less regulation and less interference by the government across-the-board. It is important that we respond seriously to the public's concern if we are to avoid a reversal of these improvements in the quality of life — improvements that we have gained largely through regulation. The question before us is how can we best assess the many regulatory objectives . and programs, given their cost and the alternative demands on resources? Interest in regulation is heightened further by the fact that the costs in total are growing rapidly. We read reports that regulations add costs of at least $100 billion a year, that regulation adds to the rate of inflation, that regulation has reduced productivity. It is argued that some regulations have adverse effects on our rate of technological innovation, on our ability to compete in international markets and that generally, regulation has perpetuated inefficiency in the economy . In response, several steps have been taken. The President's Executive Order on Improving Government Regulations attempts to improve the clarity, the simplicity and the overall effectiveness of the regulations. A Regulatory Analysis Review Group is now in place. Agencies have taken significant steps to improve their procedures. The interagency regulatory liaison group formed by the Environmental Protection Agency, the Food and Drug Administration, the Occupational Safety and Health Administration, and the Consumer Product Safety Commission is an example. The elimination of many unnecessary regulations by OSHA is another example. These efforts deal for the most part with individual regulations and the performance of specific programs. But I would suggest that today we concentrate on the aggregate regulatory picture. For in the President's words, "We need to find a way to set priori- ties among regulatory objectives and understand more fully the combined effects of our regulatory actions on the private economy." Thus, we should like to pool our ideas on ways to improve the management and control of the regulatory process, on ways to integrate regulatory policy into overall economic policy and ways to serve the priorities of the economy and the American society. To do this, it seems to me we need at least three things. First, we need better data on the impact of regulation on the economy as measured by costs and benefits. Second, we need to improve management to assure that regulatory priorities and goals are pursued in the least costly manner. And third, we need regulatory alternatives and a consideration of the mechanisms through which to pursue these regulatory objectives. Clearly, regulatory policy is not something we can fully explore in a one-day seminar. What we hope to accomplish instead in this short time is to bring a better perspective reflecting our varied backgrounds and experiences. We are pleased to have as participants around the table persons from the regulatory agencies, from the executive branch, from the Congress, private industry, public interest groups, from academia and from other research organizations . Some of you have spent years and years struggling with these questions. Yet, I hope you will welcome this day's discussion as a means of bridging some gaps in our common knowledge. Since it is a seminar with a very broad agenda, I will ask each of you as participants to make each comment in the briefest possible fashion. Jerry Jasinowski, who is chairing today's meeting will first indicate the order in which we will proceed through the agenda which you have and then he will invite your participation. It is my understanding that there will be a wrapup session this afternoon and that questions and comments from the audience can be taken at that time. We would also be pleased to have written statements from any of you, the audience or the participants, for inclusion in the record. I hope you will find this as important a day as we in the Commerce Department think it will be. I hope we all conclude with a better understanding of the problems that face us and perhaps some insights as to what the next steps might be. I will now turn the program over to Jerry Jasinowski. MR . JAS INOWS KI : Thank you very much, Madam Secretary. Let me briefly lay out the agenda and introduce the first topic. As the Secretary has indicated, the purpose of this seminar is to see where we can push forward the state of knowledge in two or three major areas of the regulatory debate and how this relates to broader questions of economic policy. We are not here to advocate because we are humble about what we know. We want to pursue this as a genuine seminar where there is debate and exchange of ideas. We hope we can focus primarily on the questions of how we achieve many of our regulatory goals because we think there is a broad consensus about the goals themselves. The agenda for today has four parts. First, an assessment of the impacts of regulations on the economy in terms of costs and benefits. But beyond that, in terms of the impacts on the firm, the worker in such areas as jobs and inflation. We want to discuss the gaps in our knowledge as well as what the present state of knowledge tells us. We hope to focus on this for the first hour. The second major item on the agenda is how to improve the management of regulatory policy, particularly as it relates to general economic policy. We want to examine a broad range of proposals that have been suggested, including a regulatory budget. This will complete the morning discussion. In the afternoon, we will begin by discussing alternative techniques for achieving regulatory goals. This can mean alternative ways to achieve a regulatory goal through conventional performance or specification standards or the broader alternatives of such things as tax incentives and fees or mixed approaches that use both. We will end the afternoon session with a wrapup for suggested areas of additional research and recommended actions. I might add that several parti- cipants will be leaving early or coming late because they are working on regulatory policy issues this morning in the context of the Administration's review of those areas . We will modify the agenda somewhat to take into account people who will have to come and go because of their own schedules. Background papers have been prepared and distributed to each participant and these papers are fair game for discussion. We would expect and welcome a discussion that is broader, however, given the range of expertise we have with us today . The Secretary has indicated the desire for us to move promptly through each section, asking each of you to limit your comments to three or four minutes on an individual subject. There will be a complete transcript, prepared state- ments will be accepted and each participant will have an opportunity to modify his or her comments in the prepared transcript which we expect to publish. Let me turn very briefly to the first subject which is the question of the impacts of regulation. We have a chart at the back of the room and each of you have charts at your table. This is only a very crude view of the impacts of regulation. In the first instance, although we have not mentioned benefits and costs on the chart, regulation will have the kind of impacts shown. One of the major items of inquiry will be the extent to which we have good or bad estimates of costs and benefits. As those of you who have reviewed the paper have seen, the paper shows a mix of apples and oranges in terms of how costs and benefits are measured. I think we want to push ahead and see what are the areas we ought to set as priorities in improving these estimates. In addition, beyond the direct estimates of costs and benefits, we want to turn to the other impacts that regulations can have on the economy. We want to look at impacts on productivity, on economic growth, on inflation, etc., and the chart lists some of these. With respect to productivity, Edward Denison in a recent study has concluded that growth of productivity has been reduced by one-fourth as a result of environmental, health, and safety regulations. On the other hand, workplace safety and health regulations have improved worker productivity and we need to understand better how these improvements occur. To highlight another, there are arguments about economic growth on both sides, that it has an adverse effect on economic growth and it has a positive effect. On the positive side, new industries are created and the quality of life is improved in ways not presently measured by the Gross National Product. Yet, Paul MacAvoy estimates GNP has been reduced by one-fourth to one-half a percentage point per year. Finally, we have inflation which is on everyone's mind and we have estimates indicating that regulations add significantly to inflation although there is controversy about how significantly. We would hope to discuss that. With that brief introduction, we would like to open it up to comments from the group-at-large in terms of the impacts of regulations, in terms of costs and benefits and beyond that, in terms of these other economic variables. Marv, you have done a good bit of work on cost estimates. Perhaps you could summarize for us your review of the paper and the literature in this area, and what directions seem most useful for us to pursue in terms of future research and actions. MR . KOSTERS : Commenting on cost of regulation issues in light of the material prepared for this seminar is not an easy task, because the material is an extensive compilation of many studies. It is a very useful compilation, CHART 1 IMPACTS OF REGULATION ON • Paperwork • Productivity • Growth • Industry Structure • Inflation • Capital Formation • Technology 10 of course, of the kind of cost information that there is available on the basis of these studies. As I read this material, and as I thought about the subject, it seemed to me that some kind of taxonomy or classification scheme can be useful because of the diversity of areas of regulation. The discussion in this material is based on a classification in terms of the scope of regulations covered in the various studies. It seemed to me that another kind of classification that would be useful for this discussion is one based on the kinds of costs that are associated with regulations. The first kind of cost I would single out is what I would call "administrative costs." Costs in this category would include not only the costs to government agencies of developing and publishing regulations and monitoring compliance and so on, but also costs of the same general kind that are incurred by private firms. These costs are relatively straightforward in principle to measure, and indeed on the government's side, much of the data are readily available. A second kind of cost I would call "compliance costs." In their simplest form, they involve things like the costs of installation, operation, and maintenance of an additional piece of equipment to abate pollution, to improve safety, or for some other public purpose. In the simplest cases, costs of this kind are also reasonably straightforward to measure. However, measurement of costs of this kind becomes far more complicated when modifications of production processes are involved, so that all costs become joint costs of producing products and reducing adverse side effects. This is the kind of problem, of course, that we are familiar with in other regulatory contexts, but where we do make estimates under those circumstances. The third kind of costs I would call "transfers." They are, in a sense, not economic costs at all, but they are instead transfers of income of one group to another, often overlapping, group. They may occur, for example, with regulations like the minimum wage, where some group of employed persons receives higher wages while consumers of the products and services these workers produce pay higher costs . This is not a "net" cost to the economy, and in that sense it's different from some of the other kinds of costs — although transfers associated with regulation can also be expected to be accompanied by "net" costs. The fourth category of costs, I would call "efficiency costs" or "inefficiency costs," and this category includes not only deadweight losses, but effects on innovation, long-term effects of various sorts, dissipation of rents, and the like. I think one reason why this kind of classification is useful is that different methods are required for estimating these various components of costs. The 11 first two components, what I have called "administrative costs" and "compliance costs" are the kind of costs that can be estimated by firms examining their records, tabulating cost information, and analyzing the data along the lines, for example, of the study now underway by Arthur Andersen for The Business Roundtable. The other two kinds of costs — "transfers" and "inefficiencies" — need to be estimated with reference to an economic model of some sort, and an estimating technique needs to be applied to relevant data. These costs arise because of responses to incentives and because of responses to constraints, and they are in that respect somewhat more subtle costs than the costs, for example, of installing and operating an additional piece of equipment. As I look through the cost estimates that are summarized in the material for this seminar — to be brief about this — it seems to me that something on the order of a third of the costs seem to be administrative costs incurred by the firms involved, incurred by agencies in promulgating regulations, incurred by the court system in resolving disputes, and so on. Another major component seems to be concentrated in the area of pollution abatement regulation. A major share of those costs are probably in a category called "compliance costs," which are incurred for things like catalytic converters for automobiles, stack gas scrubbers to electrical generator facilities, and so on. Another major component of costs seems to be in the area of transportation regulation. I suspect that some of those cost estimates are probably over- estimates but in any event, these costs seem mainly to involve some combination of transfers and efficiency losses in the transportation sector. Finally, among the other costs that account for the remaining part of costs "that" have been estimated to mount up to something on the order of $75 to $100 billion, most are in two general areas. Health and safety regulation is a significant component, involving to some extent at least "compliance costs," costs that are incurred for special equipment, special processes, and so on. The other component arises from policies such as trade restrictions and farm price support policies, which again involve some mix of transfer-type costs and what I have called inefficiency losses. MR. JASINOWSKI : That's very helpful for us, Marv. One of the questions that falls out of your review is the extent to which our future focus — staying on costs just a minute more — ought to be on total costs, on costs to the firm or on costs associated with particular regulations. We are fortunate to have Frank Cary here from The Business Roundtable who has been overseeing a study by Arthur Andersen on the direct costs to the firm. It would be useful, Frank, if you could summarize a little bit about where you are in that study and the kind of progress that can be made in terms of estimating costs at the firm level. 12 MR . CARY ; Fine, Jerry. The Business Roundtable was very much aware of the kinds of studies that are in that background paper, the studies that individual firms had made like Dow and GM, and the macro studies that people like Murray Weidenbaum had made. We felt an additional area that needed to be studied was the effect of specific regulations on more than one firm so we could aggregate the cost of particular regulations across many firms, industries and agencies. The purpose of our study, frankly, is to shed some light on the cost effective- ness of regulations. I want to note the study was begun with the understanding that much regulation is necessary, important, and stems from genuine concerns and problems . Let me spend a moment on what the study does not measure. It does not attempt to collect data on all regulation and it doesn't collect most secondary effects of regulation. That is, it primarily deals with direct costs of regulation on firms and not many of the secondary effects like opportunity costs or the costs of delay which could be, in some cases, larger than the direct costs. It does not measure benefits, not because benefits aren't important but because in business records, there is very little basis for estimating benefits and it would require judgments that are really beyond the business community. What we did was select several agencies whose regulations were particularly costly to business and developed a methodology which measured incremental costs for each agency's specified regulations for the year 1977. Arthur Andersen developed the methodology for us and I think a number of people in this room were consulted on it. Some of the suggestions were incorporated into it. A pilot test was conducted at the General Electric Company in the spring and then 48 firms, members of The Business Roundtable, agreed to parti- cipate in the study. Arthur Andersen trained people from each company in the methodology so that the results would be consistent. The agencies or programs that were selected were the EPA, OSHA, Employee Retirement and Income Security Act, Federal Trade Commission, Department of Energy, and Equal Employment Opportunity Commission. We are at the point now where a good many of the firms have completed their data collection and are reporting to Arthur Andersen. I think all the data will be submitted by December and we will prepare a report which will be made public in the first quarter of 1979. Many of you have received copies of a report describing the methodology that Arthur Andersen developed and if you haven't, we will be glad to furnish it to you. We expect that this study will not be the last study that is made on regulatory costs, but it will give us an understanding of the incremental costs, that is the costs over and above what the firms would have done in the absence of regulation, on a cross-industry, aggregate basis. Our results will be very useful in giving government agencies a good idea of what the costs of their regulations are across industry lines. 13 MR . J AS I NOWS KI : Frank, could you summarize the industries that will be reviewed as part of the study? MR. CARY : The 48 firms represent almost every industry. They represent the utilities, the petroleum industry, the data processing industry, the steel industry, the banking industry. Almost every industry is represented. MR. JASINOWSKI : That will be useful and we may want to return to the study or some of you may have comments on it. We all know that as important as it is to improve our estimates of costs, it is easy to overstate those costs, either because there is a net cost associated with these which has to take into account the benefits and then there are problems in terms of the technical means by which you do this. I do think the movement toward gathering costs on the firm level are real numbers and assuming the process is done correctly, it ought to yield us some good numbers. I wonder, Eula Bingham, if you would like to caution us with respect to moving ahead in this cost area and give us some suggestions about the directions in which we might go? MS. BINGHAM : Of course, we have been talking about regulations as regulations. I come from a very biased perspective and I freely admit it. That is, I think that when we talk about social regulations of the type that deal with safety and health, whether it is in the workplace or the ambient environment, we have to be very careful that counting up the costs, and a failure to talk about benefits, a failure to talk about hidden costs, deludes us into thinking that we cannot afford to pay to save a life, that it just costs too much. I am not certain that the economists are prepared to deal with some of these social benefits just yet. First of all, I would like to point out that Mr. Costle and I and some of the other regulators deal in areas where the benefits have to do with actually reducing diseases that may be associated with toxic substances. First of all, OSHA protects workers: We're not just talking about workers though, we are talking about consumers also because it is a well-known fact that what occurs in the plant may also occur outside the plant or be carried home by workers . I think we also have to talk about some benefits that have to do with developing more efficacious and useful products. We have to talk about the benefits of innovative technology. We do redesign products because they may create a hazard in their present form, and frequently redesigning products results in very innovative kinds of technology. I can recall being in the academic community and listening to the debate in 1974 on vinyl chloride and how it was going to shut down the whole industry if a standard was put into place. I believe as a result of the standard, the 14 industry was actually forced to be more efficient and somehow or other, these benefits are never really talked about when we do a study such as you described. I think we have to think about institutional changes in industry and labor unions and the government in general that occur as a result of some regulations. The cost of not regulating is of concern to me and I don't know whether we want to call that a benefit, or maybe we ought to subtract it from the cost side. But if one does not regulate, particularly in the area that I deal with, we probably are facing lower productivity as a result of not regulating. For example, I think it is very clear that excessive noise leads to lower produc- tivity. There are certain kinds of job stress that obviously lead to lower productivity and absenteeism. There is no doubt that the turnover rate is very great in industries where there is, let's say, excessive heat; a foundry always has an enormous turnover rate because of the heat stress. Theoretically, people only stay on who can adapt. I suspect people stay on in some foundries because they are poor, they are not well-trained and they need a job. Now, I think of the hidden costs there are, once again, in terms of the early deaths of workers and disability of workers and perhaps even workers who are highly trained by the industry and all that training is lost because the worker has died. So I think it is very difficult to quantify the benefits and I think there was a meeting last week down in Virginia where this particular item was commented upon. Our data base is poor; it is very difficult to estimate the benefits of regulation, even those that deal with the safety and health of workers. MR . J AS INOWS KI : Let me say that with your comments and some of the other comments on costs, part of the issue we face is joined. One is a question of data. We lack sufficient data on both benefits and costs, although it is more difficult on the benefits side. The other is the degree to which it is appropriate to trade off costs and benefits. Economists find that easy to do, but it is not necessarily the right thing to do and we would want to get comments from the rest of you with respect to both of those or any other aspects of this question. SECRETARY KREPS : I would like to stay with the benefits side just a moment longer and take the liberty of asking Alice Rivlin if she wants to comment on this. She did some of the early thinking on the subject of costs and benefits. I wonder if you have a background statement you would like to make on the difficulties that Eula Bingham has laid out, Alice? MS. RIVLIN : I think Ms. Bingham has laid out the difficulties very well; the question is, what does one do in the face of these difficulties? One does not give up, one simply recognizes the fact that it is difficult to measure both 15 the costs and the benefits and that, even though certain kinds of benefits probably cannot be put in monetary terms, they should not be forgotten. One of the papers, not on this subject, struck me as having a good example. It was the question of whether you could compensate workers in asbestos plants for the risk they run of incurring cancer. I don't think anybody could com- pensate me enough to get me to undergo that risk willingly. That is the kind of example Ms. Bingham may have had in mind. I am not sure it is useful in that case to attach an exact dollar figure to the value of a human life; one has to recognize that lives are at stake. On the other hand, many benefits presumably can be quantified in monetary terms. MR. JASINOWSKI : Do we have anyone else who wants to pursue either the benefits question or the question of the priorities we ought to pursue with respect to costs? Yes, Prof. Houthakker. PROF . HOUTHAKKER : I would like to make two remarks on this issue of data and tradeoff. In the first place as regards data, I believe that within its own boundaries, the Commerce Department has very important sources of informa- tion that are not being fully used as far as I can tell. I am thinking particularly of data on individual industries and the two sources I have in mind, of course, are the Census Bureau and the Bureau of Economic Analysis. I believe that both of these have the potential of doing much more to give solid facts on productivity by industry than has so far been done . I am aware that the Labor Department publishes some data on productivity by industry but these data cover only a few industries, whereas BEA has the potential to cover the entire American economy, not limited to manufacturing. It's often the only source for certain industries. I would encourage the Commerce Department to do more along those lines in those two agencies. On the question of tradeoff, this is in part a somewhat theoretical issue which is nevertheless very important. There is a tendency to say that saving a human life is worth almost any amount of money. It is probably true that in any particular situation, the amounts of money one is willing to give up to save one particular life is very, very large. However, we have to be aware that there is often a choice of where to save lives or to improve health and then the question of tradeoff does become real . I would say that a tradeoff of some kind is absolutely essential to the evaluation of benefits . We cannot go around saying that certain things are so important that it is demeaning or indecent to put a money figure on it. Every year, about 50,000 lives are lost in automobile accidents. Presumably, something could be done to reduce this number. We are not doing it for various reasons, good or bad. 16 However, we should not get into the position of saving a few lives in any particular industry while not doing anything at all in another industry unless there are clear calculations as to the relative importance for doing those things. I would say that, despite the many difficulties involved in calculating such a tradeoff and despite the risk of antagonizing people who believe lives are worth infinite amounts, the notion of a tradeoff should not be abandoned and that calculations should be directed particularly at those. The question of the valuation of a life is a particularly difficult one. The question of health is somewhat less difficult. There, too, is a danger of saying that certain actions will improve health. Well, if they do, that's fine. There are data on morbidity and the cost of hospital care and so on which are very relevant to this and again, they are not always taken adequately into account. My plea here is for more quantitative research using concepts that may not be perfect but nevertheless are necessary to get to any degree of clarity at all. Perhaps I might make some final remark concerning what Eula Bingham has just said. When she talks about foundries and the fact that they have such a high turnover, I can't help but raise a question, why don't the foundries do some- thing about this without regulation? What exactly are the obstacles? Presumably, the high turnover is a cost to these foundries, too, and why does the government have to intervene? I'm raising this purely as a question and not as something to which I necessarily have the answer. There may be good reasons why foundries don't do it themselves. Nevertheless, the possibility of action by these firms in their own interests should not be overlooked. MS. BINGHAM : I would like to say that I think that has been the push behind regulations; I don't know why but I think that failure of industry to act of its own volition has been the reason that we have had to have the Clean Air Act, the Occupational Safety and Health Act, and the Toxic Substances Control Act. Failure to recognize the health costs and the absenteeism is apparently there. Maybe there are poor economists in those industries, I don't know. P ROF . HOUTHAKKE R : If I may reply to that, I don't think that is quite the question I was asking. We all agree that in the case of pollution of the environment, there may be externalities. But the example you gave of occupa- tional safety and health is not a question of externalities. You yourself said the foundries will achieve higher productivity if they are more careful about the environment in which the workers operate. MR. JASINOWSKI : Let me ask Fletcher Byrom to respond to that. I don't want to put the issue of foundries on him specifically but, in general terms, Fletch, you might want to respond. 17 MR. BY ROM : I am not about to respond to the question of foundries. I do want to try to respond to Dr. Bingham's question about why industry may not have done what it should have done earlier by perceptions of appropriate social concern. I think it was Tillich who said we have to learn to become comfortable with ambiguities and I think we have to recognize that we live in a society that is replete with ambiguities and very often we end up in a situation where we really get lost in the semantics of the situation because we have not all established what we are really taking about. Now in response to Dr. Bingham's concern, I think it is very appropriate that we should recognize that for a long period of time, we felt that in a market system there would be some degree of altruism on the part of economic institu- tions which would produce additional value in the system that we have. I submit to you that improving the quality of the environment, improving the safety of the workplace is in fact not an economic kind of thing. It is an increase in the quality of the human condition. As far as I am concerned, even though I am very much a private enterprise thinker and a market oriented guy, I believe there must of necessity be intervention by society when they wish to establish something which improves value. I think the market system does extremely well with economic things but the things we're talking about here are not really economic. I think one of the things that has happened here is that there was a necessity for change. Our political institution is not very well adapted to the nature of our society today and it is very difficult to arrive at any change through consensus. So we have had a lot of confrontation. I think that in our society change probably does not occur without confrontation. I am satisfied that it was necessary. My feeling is that we have it now. I believe the climate for change is here and is readily acceptable. I would be the first to agree with you, Doctor, that there are probably some reactionaries among my peers who are not going to be all that anxious to make corrections, but I think for the most part that industrial society today is attuned to the concepts you are concerned with. My problem is, how do we move from here? My biggest concern is that we are here to talk about regulations. My biggest concern is the means by which we choose to implement these changes in society and I do not consider regulation to be one of the desirable alternatives available to us. I guess this is where you and I would fall apart. I find that those people who are concerned about what they perceive to be a failure of the system in the past are too anxious to correct for it today by imposing rules, methods, compliance reviews. I happen to have two favorite authors on this subject, one, William Lowrance, who I think does an excellent 18 piece of work in trying to get the semantics of the word "risk" out of the picture and who then moves on to the question of how you determine what is an acceptable risk level. I recognize that you, Dr. Bingham, probably are in a position where you perceive a representation requirement which says there is no acceptable risk, that we have to move to zero risk. I think here again is a place I fall apart from you. One other thing and then I'll stop. The other is Charlie Schultze's ideas. As far as I am concerned, we need to internalize the costs of these things. I think that we can in fact use economic methods to accomplish this. I just want to throw out the fact that before we get too deeply embroiled in the concept of how do you regulate and how do you not regulate, I would like to see how do we put it into a means whereby we actually put it back on an economic incentive basis. It seems to me that an alternative to regulation is a mechanism by which we put it back to the point where the economics of the thing will actually be the measure by which people move towards the social goals we have all agreed to. MR. JASINOWSKI ; Mark. MR. GREEN : I would like to second the thrust of Eula Bingham's remarks. The phrase "cost-benefit analysis" reminds me of "pro life," "truth in lending." Taken alone, it seems irrefutable, until you examine its basis. It seems to me there are two fundamental structural defects of the approach to date which really make it not only ineffective but perhaps pernicious until these flaws can be corrected. Its viability turns on data. Point one is business firms largely control the data about the cost of regulations imposed on them. They are obviously not unbiased in this debate. Images of foxes and chicken coops come to mind. They have in the past and one can expect them in the future to perhaps overstate the cost of regulations since they want to be free of it. Second, the documentation of benefits can often be ephemeral or impossible to document. The generational impacts of DES in the daughters of pregnant women, the cost of asbestos three decades hence is extraordinarily difficult if not possible for current regulators to estimate. The conclusion then is that as currently described, cost-benefit analysis inherently overstates the costs and understates the benefits. Until that is overcome, the debate will be one-sided, especially because I don't think we can ignore that this approach fits in with a current fad. I am not against fads, I tried to start some myself unsuccessfully. But the current fad is that government is lousy, government can't do anything compe- tently and it has some recent irrational manifestations in public policy. We have to be careful that this Department or government is not propelled by the popularity of the anti-government movement without a sound data base , without an independently derived data base which is not now in place . 19 One minor point, the discussion so far has been about regulation in general and I would like to make a sharp distinction between what I call cartel regu- lation (the ICC and the Civil Aeronautics Board, the Maritime Commission) where the government substitutes for a workable marketplace by setting the price, entry, or other intervention levels, and health and safety regulations where the government supplements a marketplace which cannot work to protect consumers because of invisible harms or externalities which a consumer cannot by himself comprehend. MR. JASINOWSKI : Thank you very much, Mark. Harrison Wellford. MR. WELLFORD : I want to make one comment on what Mark was saying about data. I think everybody agrees that the question of the adequacy of data is essential to this discussion, but by focusing just on health and safety regu- lation, the discussion gets a little unbalanced. Reading through the paper prepared for this meeting, I think you have to conclude that methodology in the safety and health area is in its primitive stages by and large. For example, the concept of cost differs widely among the studies. Some assess primary and secondary costs, others incremental costs, direct and indirect costs, and so forth. There is a different approach taken in almost every study. When you add the methodological uncertainty to the fact that there is very little data on benefits at all, the result is that there is not very much practical guidance for policymakers in the real world. There is an exception to all of this though and this is also revealed in part by the summary paper. That is in the area of economic regulation. We have just seen the successful completion of the first major deregulation initiative in a very long time with the passage of the airline deregulation bill. That bill was cooking on Capitol Hill for five years or more. I am convinced that one of the reasons it finally won approval was that the economic analysis of costs in this area had become mature enough for a fairly widespread con- sensus to develop about the impact of the CAB regulatory apparatus on airlines and passenger costs. The work of Steve Breyer and others and the hearings by the Kennedy Committee over the years has built up an enormous amount of data for people who tried to make decisions about the appropriate scope of regulations in this area. I hope we will be doing the same thing in the trucking area, for example, next year. I think when we reach that point, in health and safety cost analysis, we can think more productively about alternatives to regulations, and other kinds of approaches such as the regulatory budget. MR. JASINOWSKI : Let me seize on your comments, Harrison, to seek a point of consensus with the group. Obviously, we have many differences. Would it be the consensus of the group that economic regulations have been examined well enough over a period of time and deal with questions of analysis which 20 are perhaps somewhat less difficult, so that we are on firmer ground moving ahead in the area of economic regulation than we are in the area of social regulation? MR. CARY : I would certainly agree with that. MR. JASINOWSKI : Dick. MR. LESHER : Jerry, I suggest you have two more questions where you might have consensus so that we can put those things aside and move on to the places where you have the debate. First of all, I think most of us would agree that the data in all areas of regulation are incomplete , whether it is economic regulation or social regula- tion. Second, I think most of us would agree we can do a better job of gathering that data. It's at a very primitive state but the task is long overdue because we have been making judgments and decisions in the absence of data. If we have con- sensus on those things, then the next question is the one that has been raised here, the debate that once you do improve you data base, are you willing to make rational decisions and are you willing to come in to some consideration of cost-benefit regardless of how difficult it is? There seems to be some people arguing that that sort of rationality should not be endured. They feel that we should continue to make those decisions on an emotional basis rather than a rational cost-benefit tradeoff. I think that is one of the central questions before you go on to those other questions of alternative means of regulation. MR. JASINOWSKI : Again, let me take the privilege of the chair to pursue that question of consensus and then we will turn to Kerry Smith. Is there a consensus that, even though there are difficulties with both costs and benefits, we ought to put a very high priority on each and do the best we can on both sides to improve that data or is there any difference of view on that? There is some question about benefits, it's more difficult, but if you can't do it in dollar terms, there are other ways to estimate it. Do we have an agreement on that? Kerry. MR. SMITH : Actually, my comment is related to this. The history of benefit-cost analysis is replete with examples of moving from the intangible category of benefits into the tangible category. Outdoor recreation, one near to my own heart, is an example of that. The papers we have seen here has a decided emphasis on cost and not on benefits and that has come out in some of the discussion this morning. The question I would like to raise is to followup on something Prof. Houthakker raised. We have an institutional mechanism available to us for the estimation of cost, be it in BEA or someplace else. It is available to us with some modification. 21 My own question relates to what is the institutional mechanism available for the estimation of benefits? From what I know, and it is limited I will admit, of the regulatory agencies themselves, they are involved with a very heavy burden of rulemaking activity to translate from legislative mandates into specific regulations. The way in which they have to proceed through that process is not entirely suitable for a long-term effort in the evaluation of benefits. One of the reasons we have a paucity of information in this area is that we really don't have, in my judgment at least, an institutional mechanism available for providing this information and I wonder if others agree with that comment? MR. JASINOWSKI : I see a number of heads shaking yes around the room and Courtenay wanted to comment. MS. SLATER : Just for the sake of argument, I will try saying no. I don't think that lack of an institutional mechanism is necessarily a big problem. It is the conceptual difficulties and the lack of theoretical foundation for measuring certain types of benefits. BEA has developed procedures for the measurement of certain types of costs, particularly expenditures on pollution abatement and things of that sort. That is a relatively new effort. It's been done within this decade. So it seems to me the institutional mechanism was there for this kind of measurement to be developed, and I think there is a general feeling that quite a good job has been done. We do have underway some very infant efforts in BEA, largely as a result of Secretary Kreps * initiative and determination to get funding for these things, to try to get some handle on some of the benefits, not just benefits of regulation but some of the benefits of various aspects of economic activity which presently do not enter into the GNP accounts. We also have underway some very specific efforts to measure, not the benefits of regulation at this point because I don't want to oversell what we are doing, but to measure the specific quantitative impacts of certain types of pollution control activity; that is, the amount of physical pollutant removed per dollar expenditure of certain types. This is only a first step to comprehensive benefit measurement, but it is the first step you have to take before you take the next step. It is also valuable information for analyzing various approaches to regulation where one kind of investment can be shown to be more efficient than another, and that's a valuable piece of information. So we do have some institutional mechanisms. It will take a long time to develop the kind of data on which we will make firm decisions that we can measure the costs and benefits well enough to know how they balance out in some areas. MR. JASINOWSKI : It would be useful to take the question raised by Kerry a step further and ask Eula Bingham her views on where she thinks, in an 22 institutional sense, we might be best served for improving the estimate of benefits. It seems to me many of these regulations are highly technical and I find it difficult to see how in the first instance those questions could be better answered than at the agency level, but it is a question of resources, how many people you've got, and also some question about how objective each agency would be. What are your views? MS. BINGHAM : I think in the safety and health fields, it is particularly difficult. We can look at the data from the National Safety Council. We, of course, have institutionalized in the government the Bureau of Labor Statistics which distributes a log that businesses are required to fill out that requires certain types of information. Now, it is a fact that if a worker loses a finger or a leg or suffers some traumatic injury on the job, that will usually be entered on the log and will come into the BLS data system. But we have really a very difficult time with that because the data covers injuries over large segments of industry. It does not select a particular type of workplace where they have a certain punch press. It is not specific enough and there are difficulties with that data system. But the real crunch is in the disease area. I tell you, you just rarely get anyone who reports a disease on those forms. A dermatitis is rarely, although sometimes, reported on the forms. I have yet to see, and I am sure we could go there and find a few, any occupationally induced cancers that has ever been reported on one of those forms. In the first place, there is a very long latent period so where you start out working and receive the exposure may not be where you are working when you develop the disease. Secondly, in the case where workers do stay employed in the (same) place — a good example would be the bis-chlormethyl ether episode which was in a factory in Philadelphia — the hazard may still go unrecognized. Still, those disease are just not recorded. We do have, of course, some information available through workers' compensation but once again, without a national system of workers' compensation, it is very difficult to get that information from the states. For political reasons, for example, the State of Ohio chooses not to give any information on workers' compensation disease data. In addition to that, even if we had all of those things institutionalized, we do not have a very good system of workers' compensation in terms of actually admitting that a certain chemical will induce a certain disease or a certain type of tumor. For example, as recently as 1972, the State of Ohio refused workers' compensa- tion to an individual who had been working with benzidene and half of that individual ' s coworkers in the particular plant had developed bladder cancer 23 but that individual had been off the job site for two or three years and that is not considered a compensable disease in the State of Ohio. That's not at all unusual. Insurance companies do have data but apparently that is in a worse state than one would care to admit. I have the impression that insurance carriers are not very good when it comes to keeping the appropriate records, although certainly we have developed some information from them. I think that a wave of the future may be the increased interest among labor unions to keep data on their own workers and I think the best example of what this can really mean comes from the work of Seolikoff who was actually able to go back and take the records from the asbestos workers and do a great deal in determining the epidemiology from asbestos-induced disease of various kinds. We do not have good data sources, I readily admit it. We could perhaps encourage the Department of Health, Education, and Welfare to help us out in this area. MR . JAS INOWSKI : In addition to that, we would like very much in the Department of Commerce, through Courtenay's shop and other places, to assist you on benefit estimates. Allen. MR. FERGUSON : I would like to keep on Kerry's point about institutional- izing benefit information. I think it might be helpful to break down, so to speak, the benefit side a little bit more into three or four categories and try to determine the benefit, that is what hazard is being removed. We need, first of all, some kind of dose response construct. We need to know the impact of asbestos on people or the impact of nitrogen oxide on people. Second, we need to know something about the exposure to that hazard. The first is maybe a toxicological, epidemiological kind of question in many areas and the second is some kind of — let me use the word loosely — demographic informa- tion, who is exposed, what is their age and their other characteristics? Those two aspects of the benefit side I think might be institutionalized in an entirely different way from some of the other aspects. The first, epidemiology is clearly a health problem, for example. Then, third, there is the link between regulation or contemplated regulation and the exposure. Does whatever action is undertaken, in fact, reduce the health or safety hazard? That seems to me to be peculiarly the responsibility of the agency in question. I don't think there is any substantial relationship between what EPA does and what OSHA does in many areas at least with regard to the effectiveness of regulations. The final category I would specify is what one might call the nature or measure- ment of benefits. This gets down to such questions as, can you put a dollar value on health or mortality or the risk of mortality? If you can't put a 24 dollar value on it, what else can you do? This is the kind of thing that cut across agencies and one of the gross inefficiencies in the present regulatory policy derives from the fact that the Federal Aviation Agency seems to put an entirely different value on the probability of a life saved than do some other agencies. That part, it seems to me, is analogous to the kinds of things being done centrally in this Department on some of the cost questions. MR . JAS INOWSKI : That's very, very useful, Allen Ferguson. Marvin Kosters. MR. KOSTERS : I would like to make a couple of comments about benefits. First of all, I would like to say that I think we should have better benefit measurement information and I would like to say that unequivocally because of what I am going to say next. The measure of benefits, it seems to me, is a problem — a difficult problem — that is not at all unique to regulation. It is pervasive for almost everything that we spend resources on. I know from my experience in evaluating the benefits and costs of military spending that it's much easier to measure its costs, and that's true about most all federal spending programs. I don't think that anyone would argue though, that because benefits are difficult to measure, we ought not to collect budget cost information the way we do both in the executive branch and in the Congressional Budget Office. I think we need to recognize, as we address regulation, that it will remain quite difficult to measure benefits. We will only have limited and incomplete information on benefits, but this should not impede us from at least trying to measure costs where they are incurred. MR. JAS INOWSKI : John Meyer. PROF. MEYER : Let me say a few things about benefit-costs. First of all, is benefit-cost measurement a good idea? I did not disagree when you asked for that consensus, mainly because I think it is better than what we are doing. I also happen to think it is not very good for reasons I will go into. For example, I really don't think a benefit-cost analysis finally got us some deregulation of the airlines and railroads. I think it was a growing awareness that the benefits of regulation in these two cases were probably near zero and that the two industries were in very serious trouble. Any regulations that obviously cost money, didn't matter how much, but were not returning much of any benefits to anybody was dispensable. Politically this also meant that deregulation had important industry support, in one case almost unanimous and in the other case 50 percent, for the movement towards deregula- tion and that surely helped. Having said that, I would also point out that benefits can be overestimated as well as underestimated. One of the easiest ways of illustrating that is to 25 simply think of the fact that so often we get into regulation by someone saying: "Look, there's a problem. We must do something about it." So we go out and do it, implicity and strongly overestimating benefits without taking the trouble to investigate. Similarly, costs can be underestimated as well as overestimated, as for example, the direct costs of economic regulation of railroads and airlines. I think some important cost components have been omitted. Other components may have been overestimated as Marvin suggested but a lot of the dynamic costs — bad management, adverse selection of personnel, poor investment decisions over time — are omitted and those can easily outweigh many of the deadweight or static losses we tend to measure. As a mere mechanical detail, the fact that you have a benefit-cost ratio greater than one is not necessarily sufficient. You have to know what you are excluding as well. That leads me to another suggestion. Before we rush too wholeheartedly into a benefit-cost approach, perhaps we ought to think about one of the well-known alternatives which is cost effec- tiveness. I am not necessarily recommending this but it has at least as many merits and is worthy of consideration before we say we want a benefit-cost approach . I'm worried that in a benefit-cost approach we would say the ratio is greater than unity and therefore it's good. But that does not take the budget problem into account. In the cost effectiveness alternative, you try to define a mission — you want to save so many lives or keep people out of hospitals for so many months or some other goal — and then try to find the lowest cost way of achieving that. That might really be more efficient and more effective and more amenable to data capabilities. MR. JASINOWSKI : Again, that is a very helpful set of comments. We will break in a few minutes and have some coffee and then come back. Let me just risk my luck and raise one other potential area of consensus. Assuming that we improve the data as best we can, both in terms of benefits and costs, and assuming we make the modification that John Meyer has suggested (that we look at cost-effectiveness analysis as a way to evaluate some of the decisions we face in the regulatory area) , I think there is some greater consensus from the business side and the regulator side and others. Eula Bingham, would you comment on what degree of consensus you see us having in this area? As you get into noise and a number of other important regulations, there has to be some consideration of both sides of this. Or do you take the position which is that there's just no middle ground? MS. BINGHAM : I don't know why, I guess I am the extremist in this group. I think that's very difficult. We could collect benefits so that we can demonstrate to the world that what we want to do is worthwhile. Those trade- offs, I have difficulty with some bureaucrats making the tradeoff with the worker out there who does not understand, and it is usually a very poor worker, frequently a black or Hispanic, who cannot understand the tradeoffs you are making . 26 There is difficulty with some of these tradeoffs — for a just society, a civilized Nation, and in this Administration for us tempting to make those tradeoffs. I am willing to delineate the benefits. I would agree that it is very important to talk about cost-effective means of achieving a regulation. My own point of view is that, within certain limits, one does let an industry, for example, decide how to achieve a level of protection, to save so many lives or solve the problem. I think one has to be somewhat careful of that because, while it is very easy for a major corporation to come up with that innovative way of doing the job, it's very difficult for a small business person in this country to do it . I do come from the Labor Department and if you look at the figures, you will find that most of the jobs are coming from small business these days. So I have some ambivalence about the way you let people decide on doing things and I can tell you in our hearings, it is interesting that sometimes a small business person would like for you to say, "How do you want me to achieve this, don't just put me out there on my own?" MR. JASINOWSKI : Fletcher. MR . B YROM : I think you just touched on a very important point. That we should recognize that one of the ambiguities I spoke of is that as we perceive the need for improving the quality of the human condition in this way, we move to the point where the cost of accomplishing it requires a concentration of scale in order to make it affordable. That is contrary to the instincts of some of the other agencies in the government. One of the things that is forcing a move towards concentration in many industries is the very action in the OSHA regulations and the EPA regulations. I am not arguing the question one way or the other, I am saying it is one more of the ambiguities. MR . JAS I NOWS KI : It has been a very productive first hour. Madam Secretary, did you want to make any summary comments before we take a ten minute break for coffee? SECRETARY KREPS ; It's just that we are stuck with the question of trade- offs willy-nilly. Given a society in which resources are limited, tradeoffs will be made. Someone will decide which life to save, if you will. Being disturbed by having that decision made by the bureaucracy is again disturbing to all of us. We have to recognize, however, that the tradeoffs will occur. What we are discussing here is finding the most equitable way to achieve these tradeoffs, in the most democratic way and within our limited resources. MR. JASINOWSKI : Thank you very much. Coffee will be served. (Whereupon, a break was taken.) 27 MR. JASINOWSKI ; Toby Clark has joined us from EPA. Barbara Blum will not be able to join us. And we have Tom Hopkins from the Council on Wage and Price Stability and we are hopeful that Charlie Schultze will join us very shortly. The second item on the agenda is the area of improved regulatory management. We have a chart in the front of the room and you each have a copy . There has been a large number of suggestions on how to improve the regulatory system as a whole given its alleged or real impacts. We began to get into that in the last hour with discussions of improved cost-benefit analysis and very importantly, John Meyer's point that we look for cost-effectiveness analysis which in many cases is a much more practical way to address these questions. The chart should be viewed as a menu of alternatives. Again, we are not suggesting that a particular action is an answer. Many of them relate as a system and what we would like to do now is to focus on ways in which we can improve the system. Let me just suggest, as you look at these recommendations, that there are three broad thrusts that we should consider focusing on. Expanding the Presi- dent's Executive Order, applying it to independent regulatory agencies and streamlining the regulatory process all address primarily improvement of the management of regulations at the agency level. The President's Executive Order is an effort to improve the control of each agency head over the regulations the agency promulgates. Secondly, strength- ening the Regulatory Analysis Review Group chaired by the Council of Economic Advisers and/or establishing a regulatory ombudsman which would be an alterna- tive way to provide some central oversight. This might be done at the Office of Management and Budget, it could be done elsewhere in the Executive Office of the President. These suggestions go to the merits of providing some central oversight for the review and implementa- tion of regulations. Finally, a third thrust goes to what you might call a regulatory agenda or regulatory calendar. Even the regulatory budget and sunset review all go to the question of central oversight in a more formal, institutionalized basis, be it either in the Congress, in OMB or through other mechanisms. So you can really look at this menu of alternatives in terms of three central focuses for improving the management of regulations. The question we are faced with is the degree to which there is a balance between agency control and a more central control and to the extent you do that, what then are the mechanisms for each? With those broad introductory comments, the discussion is open. We would be happy for any of you to pick up on this part of the discussion. Let me ask you to get it going, Harrison, by reviewing a little bit about the President's Executive Order which is not as well-known and understood as it 28 CHART 2 POSSIBLE ACTIONS TO IMPROVE THE REGULATORY SYSTEM • EXPAND THE EXECUTIVE ORDER, "IMPROVING GOVERNMENT REGULATIONS" • APPLY THE EXECUTIVE ORDER TO INDEPENDENT REGULATORY AGENCIES • INCREASE THE ROLE OF THE REGULATORY ANALYSIS REVIEW GROUP • IMPROVE IMPACT AND COST/EENEFIT ANALYSES • STREAMLINE THE REGULATORY PROCESS • ELIMINATE INEFFICIENT REGULATIONS • SUNSET - ABOLISH UNNECESSARY REGULATIONS • ESTABLISH AN OMBUDSMAN FOR REGULATORY ANALYSIS • REGULATORY CALENDAR - ZERO-BASED BUDGET RANKING OF REGULATIONS • REGULATORY BUDGET 29 ought to be and is one way by which we try to improve the management of regulations at the agency level. MR. WELLFORD : Well, the Executive Order on regulatory management was promulgated in the spring of 1978 and is just now being fully implemented. Let me go over its main points. It has three purposes. The first purpose is to increase the agency heads' accountability and participation in the development of regulations and to improve the knowledge in the Executive Office and hopefully, the President about the aggregate impacts of regulation on the private sector. The second purpose is to improve the cost analysis that is done in the agencies and the third is to require a systematic review of existing regula- tions so that the agencies will come forward with suggestions on how ineffective or outmoded regulations might be eliminated. Within those three general goals, let me provide some details. Under the first, accountability and information to the Executive Office and the President, the Executive Office requires an agenda of upcoming regulations to be developed by each of the executive regulatory agencies. This agenda comes into OMB and 0MB then makes use of it with CEA in developing policy advice for the President. The agenda also serves the purpose of alerting regulatory agency heads to what is going on within their own agency and the need for coordination with other regulatory agencies. The agency is also required to develop internal work plans to be sure that there is effective public participation in the development of regulatory decisions, to reduce regulatory overlap and duplication and to improve the clarity of regulations as they are written and presented to the public. The last point I would make is that the Executive Order requires that a regu- latory analysis of major regulations be rigorously developed to be sure that all feasible alternatives to a particular regulatory approach have been considered. That is the general objective of the Executive Order and as I said, I should caution you that it really is just in place and we have not yet had time to see how useful it is going to be. MR. JASINOWSKI : As I indicated in my opening remarks, the way in which we can move in terms of improved management is at the agency level or in a more centralized form. One of the suggestions that has been made, which in part has been widely discussed in the last several days in the press, is the idea of expanding the requirements of the Executive Order to the independent regulatory agencies. Let us address this proposal. I wonder, Eula Bingham, if you would give us your wise counsel on expanding the Executive Order beyond where it is right now? 30 MS. BINGHAM : Oh, I thought you were going to ask me another question. Well, I am in the throes of trying to make some arguments about that. I personally feel that the Executive Order as it stands now, if it is adhered to, if it is taken seriously by those of us who are regulators, can accomplish a great deal. I do not think we have had an opportunity to see how well it works. Perhaps in our thrashing around to do something about inflation, we are seizing upon doing something more with the Executive Order just because we don't know what else to do. Let me tell you that I took it seriously before it ever happened. We, a year ago, put a proposal on the streets to eliminate a number of standards, which is an unheard of thing and we quit enforcing those standards, issuing de minimis citations. We are in the last agonizing days of finalizing the final regulations to eliminate the standards where attorneys are arguing over whether it is "shall" or "should" — you know how that is. It is every bit as difficult to eliminate regulations as it is to promulgate . Perhaps it is even more difficult because people do have pride of authorship in these. We are making an attempt. Another thing is to consolidate and coordinate regulations that are on the books. We are verticalizing, for example, construction standards so that the construction industry will know what is required of it from the construction list and the general industry list of standards. I think this is a worthwhile kind of activity. The other thing we did was eliminate paperwork and have reduced, I think, considerably the paperwork burden. I was shocked by the dollar amount the Paperwork Commission put on what we did, which seemed to be a relatively simple thing. We have actually reduced the reporting burden on those establishments which have ten or fewer employees. We have also taken four pieces of paper and consolidated them into a couple of pieces of paper. I think it does not take very much imagination to do that sort of thing. I guess I would say that it is possible to do some of the things in the Executive Order if we try to be open-minded and set our mind to do it. It is very difficult though. There are a lot of interests out there. In the whole area of dropping regulations, you might think that the dissent were to come from perhaps the labor unions but we had some comments to deal with from industries, from old line safety managers perhaps who had helped put those in place originally. There are many interests that you do have to deal with and I guess I would like to see what we can do with what we have available before we rush on because I think our motives in rushing on will be" misinterpreted and perhaps the motivations of this Administration will be misinterpreted. 31 MR. JASINOWSKI : That's very helpful, Eula. We are fortunate to have Charlie Schultze join us in the last few minutes. Mr. Schultze has done a great deal of work in the regulatory area prior to his becoming Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers. Our discussion, Charlie, has been in terms of the different thrusts that one might take at the agency level, at a central level, or in other ways to improve the management of the regulatory system. I wonder if you wanted to make some general comments on the principles or thrusts that you think are important for us to consider? MR. SCHULTZE : That's a tall order. I am not sure how prepared I am to follow it. There are really two different sorts of things involved and one does not preclude the other. One is the line to which the Executive Order is directed — to improve and to broaden the analysis and discussion of particular regulations. This has been facilitated, for example, by the regulatory analysis program which is an attempt in an organized way to work cooperatively with the regulatory agencies on the one hand and on the other to centralize analysis with the help of the economic agencies like CEA, CWPS, and OMB. The program is designed to increase the dialogue over time between the various regulatory actors and to do what all of us want — improve our economic analytic capability and the economic content of the regulatory process . The Executive Order's agenda requirement supports this effort and promotes coordination among individual agencies by providing advanced knowledge of what is about to be done. There are a whole host of things which can be done. There is a major addi- tional set of issues to which I don't have any ready answers but should never- theless be discussed. The issues revolve around the relative roles of the dependent regulatory agencies on the one hand and the Executive Office of the President on the other. There is no question but that the whole thrust of congressional legislation and establishment of regulatory agencies puts them in a position somewhat different from other executive agencies when it comes to making policy deter- minations. There is a major legal, philosophical and other argument, however, over what one means by "somewhat?" At one pole, there is the view that regulatory agencies are generally faced with fairly specific statutes which in some sense direct ones outcome. Under this view, though the public is involved during the comment period, it is a technical job to get from the statute to the regulation. That's one view of how one interprets somewhat. The other view is that there are major policy issues involved in the inter- pretations that flow from the statute to regulations, that these policy issues have major economic and social impacts, and that regulation is more than a technical exercise. On this view, the regulatory process is analogous to other executive functions and is therefore a part of the President's and the Administration's overall program. I think it is obvious to those of us, both in the Executive Office and the regulatory agencies that this is an area of discussion and disagreement which 32 has not been settled and which at the present time is open both on legal, policy, philosophical and other grounds. At this stage, I am not prepared to lay out what I might believe my own particular view of it is. But I think it is clear that it is quite impor- tant as to how this develops over the years — both in terms of administrative practice and probably ultimately congressional legislation. MR. JASINOWSKI : Thank you very much, Charlie. Prof. Houthakker. PROF. HOUTHAKKER : I would like to point out that the question of emphasis on the agency versus emphasis on the centralized parts of the bureaucracy is really a personnel problem. The answer depends primarily on what kinds of people are actually in charge of regulation, whether an inde- pendent or executive branch agency. Ideally, the President should be able to appoint people to regulatory agencies who will fulfill his legislative goals without the need for detailed supervision by centralized offices. In actual fact, although the President may want to do so, his ability to do so is severely circumscribed by Congress in particular, and possibly also by other political considerations. Now, if presidents put more weight on the careful selection of regulators, then I think the issue will not be as severe as it otherwise is. This, however, does run into another problem, namely that the independent regula- tory agencies in particular do have a tradition of continuity. They are not meant to reflect just one particular president but generally speaking, terms overlap different administrations. I believe that Congress is to some extent at fault in this process in that the regulatory agencies, particularly the independent ones, are still viewed as a way of graceful retirement for staff members who for one reason or another, say the defeat of their congressmen, need a well-paying job somewhere. I think if this particular management personnel problem could be overcome, then the management problem would be also much easier. MR. JASINOWSKI : John Meyer. PROF. MEYER : Henk, it is more than a personnel problem. It is clear that very often the mandates given to the various agencies lead them to a particular perspective, usually a fairly narrow one that can conflict with larger goals. The regulators may have no real way of knowing even if you can have very able people sometimes. The foreign policy problem on civil aviation is one of the most glaring examples. An inflation role in so many of the safety and environmental issues is another example. I think it's a lot more than personnel, although I think that better people would help a lot. 33 MS. BINGHAM : May I make a comment about this, just an observation. I am sure it is the same in the Environmental Protection Act, but in the Occupational Safety and Health Act, three things are literally mandated. First of all, that regulations be developed; secondly, that enforcement of these regulations occur; and thirdly, that employers -employees be informed of hazards in the workplace. If you go out to the field and talk about us being a regulatory agency, our field personnel would say, "oh, yeah, we think we are an enforcement agency." What you are talking about is politicizing these agencies and of course, they are politicized because we are political appointees. But I would bring to your attention something that happened in the previous administration, how political these things can be and how one does tend to want to be somewhat withdrawn from it. I will give you an example. There was a memo written by the then Assistant Secretary of Labor to a committee that had as its mission the reelection of the President and said what can we do to help, how can we not enforce this or not issue that regulation? That is a difficult situation. I throw it out there because it has occurred and it's a difficult one to deal with. MR. JASINOWSKI : Charlie. MR. SCHULTZE : One comment. I have no direct knowledge of this but I suspect to the extent such a regulation was written, a letter was also written to the regulatory agency. MS. BINGHAM : It's a letter that came out during Watergate. MR. SCHULTZE : My point is that it is a danger, it is a problem. But the fact that the politicizing of a regulatory agency can occur seems to be not an argument per se. There may be many other legitimate arguments for its relationship to the Executive Office and the Presidency. The same sorts of things occur presumably and have occurred in other agencies where I don't think you would use that as an argument. MS. BINGHAM : That does not make it fair and equitable to the industries that are being regulated, does it, or to the workers who are not being pro- tected or consumers? MR. JASINOWSKI : Allen Ferguson. MR. FERGUSON : I would like to make comments on two main points. One, drawing from the paper on alternatives, one of the interesting conclusions in there, although it is not emphasized, is that in order to reduce the private or economic costs of regulation, it is necessary to increase the government costs of regulation. 34 There is a great deal of emphasis put in the paper on the proposition that the introduction of incentives or mixed strategies places a much heavier burden on the government than the use of what are considered there to be cruder and more costly across-the-board standards. I think this is a difficult tradeoff that sort of runs across the grain as far as the ideological lineup of people on various sides. This paper suggests that more efficient regulation is achievable only at the expense of much more elaborate bureaucracy. The second thing is that in terms of improving regulation within its present structure , I would urge very strongly that a key problem is the bias in information with which the regulators are presented. The industry typically does control the bulk of the data, even the benefit data in lots of cases. We had occasion to work in a very small way with the National Highway Traffic Safety Administration on automotive fuel efficiency requirements. The data submitted by the industry were just abominable. In order to get the costs that they were predicting, one had to assume a price elasticity of demand of something like three for automobiles . So any major reform in the regulatory process within the present broad frame- work of regulations in my judgment has to include a systematic way of getting unbiased information into the process. Also, I think that we cannot define "unbiased" so that information provided by the staff proposing the regulation is automatically considered to be unbiased. That is clearly better than industry information but, after all, there is pride of authorship. MR. JASINOWSKI : Let me suggest that the problem of data from the indus- try is a problem that goes beyond that faced by particular agencies to all the agencies of government. It is a technical problem in the first sense and then there are biases that inevitably creep into institutional arrangements. It would seem for that reason that efforts to improve the analysis at the agency level would have to be balanced by efforts in the private sector and in some central office, be it the Regulatory Analysis Review Group or through a regulatory ombudsman in OMB, in order to have a balance between these various sources of data. This leads to the conclusion that we really ought not debate about one or the other but accept the existence of both. I wonder if there is a consensus that we really need both, some central approach and some agency approach to improve the analysis of these regulatory decisions? I wonder, Toby, if you might want to comment on that? MR. CLARK : Thank you. I would like to first to agree with Allen Ferguson when he commented on the cost of doing these analyses. One of the big problems we face is in getting sufficient resources within the agencies to do the type of analysis that EPA certainly wants to do and is required to do by the Executive Order. I have been puzzled for several years by the 35 existing budget process which tries to minimize federal expenditures, because in many ways this conflicts with the goals of implementing better regulatory processes. As a second point, I would like to comment on something Eula said. She expressed concern about politicization of the regulators. Were I she, I would be perhaps even more concerned with the possibility that this process would end up with me in jail. After all, the flexibility that the regulatory agencies have is severely limited by the initial legislation and by how the courts interpret that legislation. The courts certainly have had a major role in determining EPA's actions, and I think this has to be taken into account when you start talking about centralized regulatory processes and review processes. A third concern I have with the appropriate balance between the individual agencies and a centralized control relates again to budgetary issues. Good regulatory analysis requires a thorough insight and knowledge of the indus- tries being regulated and of the problems they face. Presumably the indus- tries themselves already have this information. The question is (and I don't really know the answer) whether you are going to duplicate all this knowledge, perhaps in cases try to exceed the knowledge the industry has about itself, within the regulatory agencies. The more information we have, the better job we can do, and we have to know incredibly detailed information about these industries in order to do good regulatory analyses. If you then talk about having a central regulatory group which will review what the agencies do, it sounds as if you are talking about duplicating that knowledge a third time, and I am not sure that this is either possible or desirable. I am, however, sure that it is expensive. MR . JAS INOWS KI : Toby, I think those are very helpful comments. Harrison Wellford is here and I notice he is taking notes with respect to the budget resource question so that's very useful. MR. SCHULTZE : He can't afford anymore resources under their guidelines. (Laughter. ) MR . JAS INOWSKI : Harrison, I wonder if you might comment on the question of central versus agency analysis and the way in which we should try to find a balance or not to do so, if that's the consensus of the group? MR. WELLFORD ; In part, it is a resource question. The amount of techni- cal expertise — specific industry expertise, engineering and medical science expertise, etc. — necessary to really get into the substance of many of these regulations cannot be easily met by the resources we presently have in the Executive Office. In fact, to allow for major substantive review of individual regulations you would have to change the present concept of the Executive Office as it has been defined at least in this Administration. But I think lack of resources 36 is only part of the problem. The absence of reliable and uniform methodology for risk and cost analysis is more important. If the methodology were more uniform, the review task would be considerably easier. We have to consider both these problems in trying to assess whether or not the Executive Office role in reviewing regulation should be expanded or altered. MR. JASINOWSKI : Let me ask, Charlie, if you want to tell us anything about the future activity of the Regulatory Analysis Review Group, not in terms of specific cases necessarily, but its continued role in reviewing these questions and if you feel that perhaps that ought to be altered over the longer run toward a different institutional mechanism? MR. SCHULTZE : The second question I can't answer. The attempt to combine analysis with discussion among the several agencies has only been underway for a short period of time. The number of regulations on which formal reviews have been completed under this arrangement is so small that it is very difficult to make a judgment. I think you can be sure that anything like this which is new will not stay the same way. It would be premature, therefore, to say that we know enough now that we want to change it in a particular direction. There is plenty of work ahead just with the existing program as we begin to look at the regulatory calendars over the next six to 12 months. MR. JASINOWSKI : Mark Green was trying to make a point. MR. GREEN : On the point of whether there is consensus for some kind of centralized oversight, I would like to mildly register dissent, given the current state of the art and the politics. Right now, the to-be -regulated business community has three cracks at influencing regulation. Initially, they appear in Congress when the mandating statute is discussed and enacted. Industry makes its viewpoint well-known. The second is during formal hearings at agencies where they have fleets of economists and lawyers make their case over extended periods of time on the merits. The third is at the court stage. One aphorism has it that when an agency issues standards, the Japanese hire engineers and Detroit hires lawyers. We are talking now about a fourth stage, a "new layer of bureaucracy" as applied to consumer offices. I am troubled with the regulatory budget concept as I read about it in the Secretary's business article in the paper here for reasons that have been alluded to. Given the state of data today, it would not work. It would be so inherently biased because the people who control the data have a heavy self-interest to shape the data, if not to not disclose the data. In one of the papers distributed today, there was an estimate that passenger constraints called 37 airbags would impose a $300 to $400 cost on consumers. That's the automobile industry data. The Department of Transportation data was in the low hundreds of dollars, like $110. You would think that Commerce would have respect for a sister agency like the Department of Transportation, and use their figure. Second, on access, while one would want everyone who is here to stay here, but where is the labor representative who has a lot of interest on the issues raised today? Eula Bingham cannot speak on behalf of her agency and the broader labor community. Third, who are the people who would be making this judgment and to whom are they emotionally and politically responsible? The Secretary of the Treasury, Ambassador Strauss, the Secretary of Commerce? Look at their calendars of meetings. Also, part of their motivation is what Business Week or The Wall Street Journal says . I think there is a political link between the business community's complaints about government and its ability to shape this fourth level of review which I think raises serious problems. This Department began by examining the social audit of corporations and today we have somehow evolved into a social audit of government. MR . JAS INOWSKI : Mark, those comments on the budget and Congress are both useful and we want to turn to the political and technical questions associated with the budget in just a moment. We are fortunate to have Bill Nordhaus from the CEA join us. I wanted to take Mark's comments one step further though because they are related to a number of other points made by John Meyer and others. There is the overall question of the congressional role in this process. I think you mentioned oversight, Mark. In addition, there are a number of proposals for sunset provisions or other kinds of analysis on the Hill. I wondered if people wanted to carry the discussion about the major role of Congress in this area a step further? C. L. Haslam. MR. HASLAM : Jerry, it's fair to say that Congress has addressed many of the questions we're looking at today. There are any number of bills pending, and a few passed in this session, which deal with the issues raised today . The basic common threads which run through these are that they talk about cost-benefit analysis, mandating regulatory reviews associated with regula- tion, and the need for efficiency. A number of the proposed bills would substantially increase congressional review and oversight, and include "sunset laws." We will probably get to these this afternoon. 38 There is some emphasis on increased economic impact analysis and public par- ticipation, the whole potpourri, of what we're looking at. The Administration generally has been receptive, but has yet to propose legislation that would deal with the problems that we have addressed: technical feasibility; the question of practicability of administration and separation of the powers, and congressional veto. I think that the common thread of issues that have been raised indicates that we may well be reaching some maturity of the issues, in terms of public discus- sion. Regarding the American Bar Association, Jerry, its Committee on Law and the Economy has looked at a number of these questions. Regarding one of the questions which we've discussed, after their analysis they came down clearly in favor of substantially enhanced Presidential authority. There is a view that the regulatory process is literally beyond control, incapable of being molded towards any consistent public policy. The ABA Committee strongly favors increased Presidential authority, even to the point of modifying or suspending regulations from independent regulatory agencies, after some review. They fully recognize, as do most people, that when you deal with changes in the structure of the regulatory process, such as these, congressional action is clearly required. MR . JAS INOWSKI : Are there any other comments to pursue that line of inquiry? I recognize that at least in the case of the President's authority, it is a legal question and that none of us can answer that question in any legal sense. Dick, did you want to make any further comments on the role of Congress in this? MR. LESHER : I guess I have difficulty being too confused over it. I think the laws are fairly clear and I do think the executive does have responsibility for carrying out the mandates passed by Congress, either in the straight-line agencies or regulatory agencies. We are really talking about improving the process and we're talking about management efficiency. It is very clear that the executive does have responsi- bility for those two things. We are not talking about changing the regulations at the executive side, that is done basically by the Congress. Many of these regulations and many of these agencies and departments have been hastily put into place. A lot of error has been made along the way and I think there is a meeting of the minds that we should get on with cleaning up the act the best we can without quarreling too much over the basic long-term objectives. MR. J AS INOWSKI : Kerry Smith. MR. SMITH : It may be important to distinguish between existing legisla- tive mandates and proposed new regulations. As I read the regulatory budget proposal, it was directed in large part to new regulations rather than impos- ing upon regulatory administrators some possibility of violating the law. 39 It seems to me we want to distinguish two possible roles that budget might play. There is an increasing recognition it seems to me in the construction of regulatory measures that, aside from micro efficiency and equity considera- tions, we also have to think about macro efficiency considerations. Somehow the package of regulations or any single regulation itself may inter- fere with stabilization policy or the broader goals of a given administration. Here again, just as at the micro level, we have tradeoffs that must be recognized. The question I want to raise is: Is the regulatory budget intended to expose the nature of these tradeoffs for public debate and review, or is it to be an instrument of quite important centralized control? If it is an instrument of centralized control, then we have to think carefully about the interaction of who gets involved in that control. MR. JASINOWSKI : That's a very good introduction into a more detailed discussion on the regulatory budget. Just to lay out the Department of Commerce's position on it, it is something we have been working on and which we are anxious to advance . We see it as a reasonably long-term proposition, although we see steps all along the way which will move us in that direction. We are optimistic but realistic about the kinds of data and other problems that are involved and we would be happy, after some discussion, to indicate a little more about the next steps we see in that process. I would like to ask Lucy Falcone from the Department of Commerce to summarize briefly the paper on the regulatory budget so that we can move on with addi- tional discussion on that, as well as the regulatory agenda and other central, formal means for management of regulations. Lucy. MS . FALCONE : Let me start by saying we saw two needs in the regulatory area — the need for an overview which doesn't currently exist and the need for better management of the regulatory process. We focused on the regulatory budget although, as Jerry indicated, it is still in an embryonic stage. We are now at the point where we are trying to answer the conceptual questions that one faces in trying to set up a regulatory budget. In terms of how the budget might be used, there is a whole range of possibili- ties. One alternative is to develop a budget as a listing of regulations and their costs. This is essentially what was done by Stanley Surrey in the early '60*s when he developed the tax expenditure budget. That tax expenditure budget is now published as a special analysis in the federal government's annual budget. A listing of regulations and their costs in and of itself would, as I think the tax expenditure budget has done, stimu- late the study of benefits and how to deliver benefits in a cost effective way, 40 Alternatively, we could use the budget in a way very similar to the federal budget where each year government would set cost ceilings on new regulations and within that cost ceiling, make priority choices. For example, the President may set a ceiling of $535 billion for next year's budget and within that, we will trade off defense against social security benefits. However, our position at the Commerce Department is that we don't yet know enough about the regulatory budget to settle on its ultimate use, but I think it goes all through the range that I mentioned. There are a number of questions we think still need to be answered. First, how would cost information be obtained? One suggestion made in the paper is the use of new accounting measures, new 10K forms that are submitted to the SEC. We frankly are concerned about this approach because computation of the budget might cost more than the private sector would save in terms of cutting regula- tory costs. Secondly, it would also raise the questions which Mark Green and others have raised about who controls the estimation of costs? We would prefer to see more work done in terms of macro models that could estimate costs without imposing a very great reporting burden on either govern- ment agencies or directly on industry and individuals. Alternatively, government could conduct surveys or censuses similar to The Business Roundtable study. Again, I think we will have to face at some point the question of how much additional direct cost the government will be willing to bear to obtain what would be less biased information on costs. Second is the question of the scope of the budget. The budget can include direct costs to the regulatory agency, which I think we would all agree upon. It can also include other costs to the government as a whole. Let me give you one example . In order to implement some water quality regulations, there might be a need for some of our grant-making agencies to make money available to communities. So an agency like the Economic Development Administration or another agency might divert funds that would otherwise be spent to build libraries, to improve sewer systems. That's just an example. The question is, should those kinds of costs be included? The third kind of cost is the direct cost to the private sector. I don't think there is any need to go into those further. Beyond that, there is the question of indirect or opportunity costs. Costs in terms of reduced productivity, costs in terms of a slowdown in technology improvement or the acceleration of technology improvement. Our inclination would be to start modestly at first. We would like to take the direct costs of the regulatory agency and the direct costs to the private sector into account and perhaps leave for later the indirect costs to government, that is, costs borne by other government agencies and the indirect or opportunity costs in the private sector. 41 The third question is should the budget account directly for benefits? Our preliminary view on this, although we are open to suggestions, is that like other budgets, benefits should not be quantified directly. However, they are the raison d'etre for conducting the budget in the first place. When we compute the federal budget, we presume the benefits of national defense spending, we don't try to quantify those benefits in the budget. Therefore, we think that computation of the regulatory budget itself would stimulate more attention to benefits and more conceptual work on calculating benefits. Finally, there is the question of process. We don't think that any agency, be it a regulatory agency or an agency like the Department of Commerce, could have the unbiased reputation for actually computing this budget. If we develop a regulatory budget, there will have to be some central agency that is in a sense a traffic cop, an unbiased arbitrator. It will have to be located some- place in the Executive Office of the President. In addition, we feel there would have to be congressional participation. We have seen some congressional interest in this idea. In fact, Congress might develop a process similar to the Budget Act of 1974 through which it would subject its own regulation writing committees to an overall 'ceiling each year. If something like this were ever to work, it would have to be a joint venture between the executive and legislative branches. Otherwise, given Congress' increasing role in setting regulatory goals — in setting goals and then setting the regulations through which we achieve these goals — I think we would not get very far if we only pursued an executive branch regulatory budget. MR. JASINOWSKI : Thank you very much, Lucy. That is a useful summary of the paper and some of the issues associated with the regulatory budget which have already been raised. I know several of you have questions and suggestions and criticisms about it. Allen Ferguson wanted to make a comment so Allen, why don't you start out. MR. FERGUSON : I had a fairly large number of comments and I will try to hit only the most important ones to begin with. I have great trouble with the concept. I have great trouble with the paper. The paper in the first place deals primarily with process and the real question is not how to do it but whether to do it. This really is not addressed at all in the paper. I think that is probably the question on which this group should focus. The second thing tees off directly from Lucy's last point and that is that any budgetary process as it is practiced and as it is proposed here, is in a sense backwards as a fundamental planning device. You ought to begin with what the object of the game is and then look at how you get there, how you accomplish that object. I could not help thinking as I read through this, the gross sort of analytical inferiority of this to program budgeting . 42 Program budgeting, at least in concept, began at the beginning. I think it is fair to say it was never tried so no one can say that it failed. But this also relates fairly closely to John Meyers' point about the relevance of cost- effective analysis which I always subsume under cost-benefit analysis. It might make sense to begin with some notion of level of effectiveness that is desired. Some kind of general objective, such as in this year or in the next five years reduce expected hazards in various categories by some specified amount . Then deal rather systematically with whether the marginal $10 million is better spent in saving lives by more air traffic control, more occupational health and safety, more environmental protection. Certainly, we ought to begin at the beginning. A closely related thing is — if you begin at the beginning, it becomes obvious that it is closely related — the question of whether a regulatory budget makes sense separated from a tax expenditure budget and so on. Economists are full of theorems about the disadvantages of artificial compartmentalization, and, it seems to me they apply here. If we are interested in some kind of social objective, then there is no particular reason, certainly no particular logical reason, for treating the regulatory methods of moving in that direction separate from the subsidy methods, the tax subsidy methods, loan guarantees and so on. If there were to be a cost oriented budget process, then I would think the best way to obfuscate, and obfuscation is often an important managerial tool, is to deal with net costs so that the benefit calculation is in from the beginning. Another set of comments deals with the way the process might be applied. Going back to the consensus that you achieved some time ago on "economic" regulation, the government ought, in my judgment, begin where we know what we are doing. We know what we are doing in the cartel or economic regulation. I think it is fairly safe to say that the net benefits of those agencies are by and large negative. If one were to begin with a regulatory budget process, that would be the first proposition that would come out of the regulatory budget process in my judgment. MR . J AS INOWSKI : Allen, let me come back to you so some other people can jump in on this. Bill Nordhaus has been doing some thinking on the general question of how you improve the central information gathering and analysis of regulatory policy. Bill, do you want to make some comments? MR . NORDHAUS : I wanted to comment on the regulatory budget proposal, to give two of the reasons why I think it is absolutely critical that you have it and two reasons why I think it won't work. Why is it critically important? There are two kinds of defects that I see around. The first one is that nobody has the slightest idea how much all the regula- tions the federal government produces each year cost? 43 If you go around and ask people, "How much do you think the new regulations we are proposing next year cost?" they will shrug their shoulders and say a billion dollars, couple of million dollars, maybe. Or else they say two trillion dollars, depending on what their point of view is. Usually they don't have the slightest idea. The general populace, the Congress and about 90 percent of the executive branch and regulatory agencies have not the slightest idea what the number is. The second defect in the system is that by internalizing one externality we have created another. The costs that are imposed on the private sector by regulatory agencies are not internalized in any way — that's a little strong but basically true. Regulators look very carefully at their own administrative costs, how much it costs to enforce and so on, but look nowhere near as carefully at the costs they impose on the private sector. It is very important that somehow the costs regulators impose be internalized because that is the only way regulators are going to economize. What is needed is a way to impose budget discipline on regulators. Compare the budget process: on some of the major weapons programs, the Department of Defense is fighting like cats and dogs, but there is an internal discipline in the Department of Defense because they know someone is going to look over their shoulders at the budget totals. Having said why I think it is critically important, let me say two reasons why I think there are serious defects in the regulatory budget. The most critical one is what I call the funny money problem. These regulatory dollars that are being budgeted are dollars that no one can ever find. You can go out and try to measure them, and think you can find them, but I don't see how any process in this government could ever find anything precise enough to use in a quasi-budget process. If you go and look at Moore's cost estimates of the cost of surface transporta- tion, I think it is a factor of three between the high and low estimates of the cost of surface transportation regulations. 0MB cannot go to Eula and say, Eula, I want you to keep your costs down, your regulatory budget this year is $10 to $30 billion. That's not a management tool. Let me further suggest that this is a deep analytical problem. Some people think that if we can get the smartest people working on it, we can find a solution. It's just not there. There is no way you are going to separate out from the joint cost allocation what are regulatory costs and what are non- regulatory costs. Let's say we keep piling on regulations on the coal industry to solve the sulfur emission problem. At some point, people will turn to a completely different technology, say oil or if we rule that out, nuclear. When the pro- cesses change, or someone invents a new process which is a lot more expensive 44 but does not have any pollution control in it because it is inherently clean (say gasification process instead of the coal burning process) , none of it is pollution control in a sense but all of it is in a sense. It is fundamentally impossible to separate out pollution from non-pollution equipment after a couple of years. The fourth point on a regulatory budget. I would endorse what Allen Ferguson said. A budget starts from the top where it should start from the bottom. If we took a poll around this room, what should the regulatory budget be for next year, some people would know it should be zero and some people would know it should be unlimited. But if you seriously sat down and asked should it be $5 billion or $100 billion, I haven't the slightest idea. You would not know until you saw what are the problems, how many benefits are you going to get, what are the costs, what is the time frame over which we are doing this, what are the alternatives? This suggests the regulatory budget is basically a good analogy, but there will be very difficult problems in actually implementing it. MR. JASINOWSKI : Thank you very much, Bill. Your comments and Allen's go to the significant problems we face in this area and we are quite realistic about them ourselves. Let me make two points though that vitiate the extent to which the problems you raise seem so insurmountable. With respect to the regulatory budget, it would be our hope not to try to take into account the efficiency losses that you see in studies by people like Moore on transportation where you do have the "funny money" problem but to try to focus initially on the questions of direct costs of government with respect to regulations and the direct costs associated with private firms. In both of those cases, you can make those measurements. You do have some problems with joint product and you have some problems with indirect costs and those problems are real. You can make estimates there that are not a factor of three in terms of differences. Maybe I'm wrong on that and I think that deserves further review. With respect to the orientation toward the question of what are goals and benefits here, that is useful and one of the things we ought to take into account as we eval- uate this concept. Marvin, you were going to make a point. MR. KOSTERS : First of all, I agree completely with the second part of Bill Nordhaus' remarks on the difficulties in measuring costs of regulation. But despite that, I would myself think it highly desirable to try to work toward some sort of regulatory budget, one that concentrates on costs initially as distinct, for example, from net costs that take into account benefits. 45 In regard to computing costs, there will always be problems in developing estimates with any precision, and the cost estimates can never be a very sharp tool it seems to me. One problem is that there are ambiguities about what is the baseline from which costs should be measured, in addition to joint cost problems and so on. Contrary to what some people might believe, business firms would normally spend something, for example, to improve worker safety because it would be a good business practice; as economists say, it would be consistent with "profit maximizing" on their part. I am sensitive to the point expressed by Mark Green that costs are likely to be overestimated. I think that's probably right, but one reason for that is when business firms are in a regulatory environment, they tend to lose sight of why they are doing what they are doing , and to attribute to regulations not only the cost of the regulations but what they might also do to some extent in any event. There is an irony here, that for those who would think that business would do very little, the cost estimates might be about right. For those who recognize that business would in any event spend something, for example, on better worker safety, the costs would be overestimated. I think even though there will be lots of difficulties, there will be consid- erable crudeness in the process, it would at least be useful to get some notion of the order of magnitude of regulatory costs and I think we ought to start there. I think we ought to start systematically developing cost of regulation measures, probably even on some kind of experimental basis, taking only a few agencies where cost estimates are best evaluated. I would also prefer to see us start at an earlier date rather than a later date. MR. JASINOWSKI ; Toby Clark. MR . CLARK : I would like to comment on some of the points that have been made and reemphasize those I agree with. I disagree with Bill Nordhaus' first two points but agree with the second two. With respect to his first point, we do have the "slightest idea" of the costs of environmental regulations, at least in the pollution area. We have spent a good deal of effort on estimating — and publicizing — them. They remain, of course, quite imprecise. But these problems of accurately estimating costs show the problem of doing a regulatory budget. They are the same thing. The reason we can't estimate costs accurately now is the same reason why a regula- tory budget in fact probably won't work. Personally, before I continue, I should probably come out of the closet and admit that I am interested in and support the concept of a regulatory budget. But it is because I support the idea that I am concerned that the history of the federal government is spewed with the debris of good ideas over the last 46 ten years — ideas like program budgeting, management by objective, etc. — that have been pushed too far, too fast and have become useless or at least unused. I see all the potential for that happening in this case, too. I have been painfully involved for the last five years in trying to make these cost estimates and in trying to figure out how much firms would be spending in the absence of pollution control laws. It is very, very difficult, often being more of a philosophical question than an estimation problem. And there is no way to measure these costs. The Bureau of the Census conducts pollution expenditure surveys every year and they are not even sure what they are measuring even after the expenditures have been made. If you cannot even measure total expenditures, you certainly can't observe how much of the cost result from federal regulations. MR. JASINOWSKI : Are there any other comments on the regulatory budget? Al Sommers. MR. SOMMERS : Mr. Haslam mentioned that the ABA report took a strong position on the expansion of centralization relative to expertise in the management of our regulatory effort. I think one of the reasons that the ABA took such a position was that it was impressed by the fact that there is a commonality within the parts of the regulatory effort and a higher degree of oversight, even granting the politicization possibilities. The ABA report points to problems of conflicts of objectives, problems of allocation of effort across the whole regulatory front and problems of con- straint on the aggregate outlay. Now there is a reason to wonder about the proposal to constrain the aggregate since as someone else mentioned, regulation is part of an economic universe. Why is this aggregate among all of them to be constrained? My own impression is that the effort is warranted, as it is with the budget, year by year we attempt now to constrain the aggregate leaving the future free. That is, we can elevate the aggregate where our indications seem to warrant. My own impression is that an effort at the regulatory budget, granting the incredible problems of measuring even the direct costs, is a step toward a rational view of the degree of regulation to which we are subjected, i. e., the costs and the alternative benefits. As in so many other areas of economic development, it is an initial determina- tion that starts the swelling of the resources into the measurement problem. If the regulatory budget would provide that, groping though it would be at first, I think it is an element perhaps in education and self-realization of the dimensions of the problems of regulation. MR. JASINOWSKI : Toby wanted to make another comment. MR. CLARK : I do want to make one final comment about the problem of going too far too fast with this idea. That is really my main concern. I 47 see another major problem with the implementation of the concept which has to be carefully thought through. That is, that the idea of a regulatory budget apparently presumes that if you saw costs getting too great, you could do something about it. In fact, a regulation we pass this year is not going to influence costs this year. It will influence expenditures two, three, four, up to ten years in the future. The degree to which we can accurately estimate what these expenditures are that far in the future is limited. Quite honestly, I would put plus or minus 100 percent on it. If you focus the regulatory budget on this year or next year, there is very little opportunity to affect those budgets. Almost all of the expenditures are made in response to regulations adopted in past years. It would not make much sense for us to run out and raise our arms and say stop building that thermal cooling tower, we don't want you spending more money or we will exceed our budget. That just would not be rational good policy • MR. J7ASINOWSKI : Let me ask Frank Cary or Fletcher Byrom to comment on the question of the acceptability in the business community of a movement toward a regulatory budget, leaving aside many of the technical issues which we regard as valid. There is a political issue even within the business community as to whether or not this is a direction in which to move and I would like one of you to comment if you would. MR . CARY : I will let Fletch comment on his own. I'm sure there are many members of the business community who would look upon this as national planning and would object to it on that basis. I personally don't have any trouble with the concept. I think the concept is all right, but it sounds to me like something that couldn't be done in less than 25 years. My reaction to it is that there are a number of practical steps that should be taken now which are of more immediate concern and also might serve as groundwork for a regulatory budget. We should try to move ahead with implementation of the President's Executive Order and also extend it to the independent agencies. Perhaps we should create an office to oversee the agencies and insure that they do follow the President's Executive Order so as to produce the kind of results that I think we need very badly in the short term. But conceptually to work towards that kind of thing long term, I think you people will need to have a much better idea of all the difficulties described so far. From what I've heard today, I think the regulatory budget is a very, very difficult thing to do. MR. BYROM : To avoid the criticism of being in favor of national planning, I subscribe more to the concept of anticipatory analysis. I think we have a real problem in this study which has been underlined by Bill Nordhaus ' comments that particularly at the micro level of economics, we don't have the data base. 48 One of my real concerns here is that on practically all things, we start to try to do something to improve our society without having any facts on which to base our proposals. I keep finding that regardless of who I am discussing it with, I am in complete agreement with the objectives but constantly in disagreement on the methodology used to accomplish them. I agree with Frank, to have any early hopes that we are going to come up with something that will solve this quandary I have just described is optimistic. I think it's a long, long process. I would like to see us start to get on with it in the hopes that my grandchildren will not have the same frustrations that I have. But I believe that also we can do things bit by bit, as long as we have the humility to recognize that we are probably going to be wrong. MR. JASINOWSKI : Let me suggest in closing the morning session that there are intermediate steps between where we are now and a full-blown regu- latory budget. As Lucy indicated, there are lots of different ways in which you try to prepare a regulatory budget. Some of those intermediate steps have to do with the regulatory agenda or regulatory calendar in which we don't try to do all the things associated with the budget but simply try for those things we can measure, lay out what is associated in terms of costs and if we have benefit information, to do the same on an annual basis. Although there are limitations to the budget concept in its full-blown model, there are alternatives along the way which we will want to consider. In the afternoon we will pick up on those kinds of alternatives. (Whereupon, the meeting was recessed for lunch.) AFTERNOON SESSION MR. JASINOWSKI : This afternoon we would like to focus on two remaining items on the agenda. They don't decrease in terms of difficulty as we move forward. Those two items are first, a discussion on alternatives, both within the context of conventional regulatory approaches such as performance standards and specification standards. That is to say alternative ways to achieve a particular regulatory goal at least cost. The second meaning of the work "alternative" is to look at nonconventional regulatory approaches in the form of tax incentives or user charges or even voluntary techniques by which we might achieve regulatory goals. These have not been used a great deal, but there are examples of where they have been used and we think we ought to pursue those. Related to both of those is the idea which many people have worked on of pursuing multiple strate- gies for achieving regulatory goals. Following that we would like to turn to a summation of the session overall and what the group feels are the future priorities we ought to pursue. 49 In that discussion, we may want to reintroduce some of the issues we have not resolved and may not resolve today but which we might come to some greater agreement on, so that we can continue the kind of research and dialogue that we have had here today. We have a chart on alternative approaches. There are: • conventional regulatory approaches where we mandate what particular firms will do in order to achieve regulatory goals; • tax incentives or user charges which we are now considering with the Resource Recovery Act. We have seen some action with respect to barge traffic in this Congress and there has been a long debate on the extent to which we use market incentives versus mandatory approaches; • informational approaches which are largely voluntary but in some cases may be the correct approach; and finally, • mixed strategies. There are a number of people who want to speak to the first issue so rather than take a great deal of time myself, I will open it up far discussion. Fletcher Byrom began the discussion on alternatives this morning as something he thinks is crucial to the way we approach regulatory issues. I wonder, Fletcher, if you would be willing to start out the discussion by repeating some of what you have said and indicating what further things you believe are important here? MR . BYROM : Maybe the best way, to be as clear as I can let me give an example. Basically, I want to use Dr. Bingham's agency as an example of how I would see one way of doing it. If I sound as though I am idealistic and believe in miracles, maybe that is the case. What I would like would be to see labor and management by different industries sit down and attempt to arrive at acceptable levels of performance. I recog- nize the difficulties of this because labor in effect has a political responsibility . Whether they anymore than Dr. Bingham feel they can accept anything other than perfection, I don't know. But if you could establish frequency and severity rates by industry which were acceptable levels, where OSHA could be a catalyst, a moderator to the labor- management process and you would arrive at performance standards which would be acceptable performance, you would arrive at a mechanism of reporting perfor- mance which would give adequate disclosure of what the actual performance was. This would be certified by the chief executive of the corporation as being a proper statement of what the performance had been. I would suspect that his certification would be subject to the normal punishment if he in any way fraudulently misstated the thing. 50 RT 3 ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES AND THEIR MAJOR VARIANTS • REGULATORY APPROACHES - PERFORMANCE STANDARDS - SPECIFICATION STANDARDS - CASE-BY-CASE STANDARDS OR PERMITS • INCENTIVE APPROACHES - TAXES (USER CHARGES, FEES) - SUBSIDIES - LIABILITY MEASURES t INFORMATION APPROACHES - DISCLOSURE - EDUCATION - JAWBONING • MIXED APPROACHES - MARKETABLE PERMITS - SURCHARGES - COMBINATIONS OF THE ABOVE OR OTHERS 51 What I am advocating is a self-regulating kind of situation which would include economic incentives for improved performance and for poor performance. I, very obviously, feel that this is the way we should be moving, rather than to a methodology that decides not only what the performance should be, but how you intend or how you are supposed to get that performance. The performance standards as far as I am concerned would have to do with an ambience that would be acceptable at a given point in time . MR. JASINOWSKI : Let me ask you for a point of clarification, Fletcher. When you talk about this proposal having incentives tied to it, do you mean there would be natural incentives to achieve the goal? MR. BYROM : No, I think there are natural incentives, and I am not speaking on behalf of all my colleagues and peers who happen to be in industry when I say this. But I for one would accept fees and would hope there might be such things as tax credits or something. But I would also believe that in the case of EPA, for example, there are natural incentives in the chemical processing industry. If instead of treating an effluent, if you can eliminate the discharge, the chances are your recovery yields are up and it may make some money for you. MR. JASINOWSKI : John Meyer. PROF. MEYER ; I want to make sort of a speech, I guess, and I apologize in advance. First of all, a reaction to the budgetary problem. I think as a first cut, the thing to do is to get a feel for the costs. But I am worried about some other things Allen pointed out. I think I have been involved in about as many of these benefit-cost capers as anybody and I would suspect probably the largest scale attempt to estimate the benefits and costs of a particular application, effluent controls for the automobile industry. I have also been involved in several others, water quality commission reviews and so on. I must say that I am struck by one thing which I am afraid that a broad brush budgetary approach would miss and that is essential in about every one of the cases that I have looked at with any depth. You usually find that technology and cost tradeoffs lead you into a few crucial decision points. Generalizing about a "best" solution is therefore very difficult. Let me illustrate. For autos, much clearly depends on the level of the N0 X standards. If you insist on rolling back to .4, the costs go up because you rule out stratified charge and diesel technology to a considerable extent. If you compromise at 1.1 or 1.2, cleaning up may almost be costless because diesel and stratified charge technologies get rid of the hydrocarbons and carbon monoxide problems almost automatically. On the other hand, it is also clear that in certain cities, Los Angeles being a classic case, N0 X from automobiles is a real problem and so maybe you do need a special solution. 52 Another major N0 X impacted city is Chicago but there the majority of the N0 X comes from stationary sources so a solution that is appropriate for Los Angeles * N0 X impact problem is probably not appropriate for Chicago's. I see no easy way of any simple pricing scheme getting at this . The only thing that gets you at it I think is to get into the details of the technology and actual facts and then try to design and negotiate a solution — that is why I like the negotiation session suggestion. You try to design what is sensible in the particular instance. Another example is the paper industry's water pollution problem. Apparently costs depend very heavily on what kind of bleach standards are insisted on for paper. The cheapest way of solving this industry's problems — at least it's a good hypothesis — would be a government regulation saying papers of a certain whiteness can no longer be sold so that such competition is ruled out. Aerosol is another example. There the obvious thing that the industry was waiting for was what amounts to a cartelization activity by government ruling out using high cost aerosol technology, forcing a return to lower cost pumps. As long as the industry knew everyone was not going to use aerosols, they were quite willing because costs went down. If you look at water basis systems, it may be difficult to design a set of prices that take into account all the interactions. It may well be beyond regulatory intelligence. You might be better off in taking a comprehensive planned approach and achieve more for a given outlay of cost. Or take urban highway congestion. Many economists talk about using the price mechanism to solve that. In theory it's excellent and there are a great many cases where you can do something with prices. The truth in most instances, though, is that it's cheaper to shut down some on and off ramps, put on more traffic lights or use a little more paint. In short, I don't think you can generalize about these alternative approaches. I also think any kind of broad brush approach, including a regulatory budget, may divert you from doing what I think is at the heart of trying to solve many of these problems. That is, in each case, you really have to dig into the technologies, the product tradeoffs, the way that people and organizations react. Somehow or other, the program you develop must come to grips with these specifics. Per- haps, at best, we can institutionalize negotiating sessions and hopefully can implement what we discover. End of speech. MR . JAS I NOWS KI : Actually, it was quite a good speech, John. We are coming to realize increasingly that these questions must be handled on a case by case basis to a large extent. But, that does not disagree with Fletcher's point. PROF. MEYER : I think it is Fletcher's point in a way, it's the same point. He is saying not only is it case by case but then you need some sort of institutionalized mechanism to get to the ad hoc solution for each one. 53 MR. JASINOWSKI : I wonder, Eula Bingham, if you would comment on that for us because I think it goes to many of the issues you face in OSHA. MS. BINGHAM : I will comment on that but along with some other things before I do have to leave to go to another meeting. First of all, as I look at this outline you have here before us, in terms of regulatory approaches, I would say that I personally favor performance standards wherever they are feasible. We do have some constituents who have a problem with performance standards since they don't have the wherewithal to go out and judge whether or not the particular specification is acceptable. It is very interesting that they are usually the workers themselves who have no way of understanding whether the solution is adequate or not without having a massive union organization behind them, and most workers are not organized in this country. The other group is the small business community which really cannot afford to go out and come up with the specifications. So time and time again, we are faced with those two groups of people telling us that we would like to have some specifications. Now the way one does that, of course, we perhaps can have a performance standard and then give examples of specifications as they come along. I did want to comment on some other alternatives, one of them that I would like to comment on is education. Certainly, we have begun a large program of education among the labor unions, the trade associations and have asked universities to help out. While I am firmly committed to education, I do have a problem with one of these that was put in a document that talked about the incentive and informational approach to the question of asbestos. Even though you educate workers about the problems, then you cannot say to that worker, well, you know, those are the hazards. I believe the way it was put here was that workers can then decide whether the working conditions and remu- neration levels are sufficient for them to accept the associated health risks. I don't think they are prepared to make that kind of decision because, as I said before, they are poor people and they need a job and we need to help them come to a decision on this. That does not say that I don't think that workers and employers should be well-informed of the hazards of the workplace. As a matter of fact, I think that that may be the way that we will gain the most in the health and safety field in the next five to ten years. Not with any additional standards we put out or enforcement by a puny number of compli- ance officers , but actually having a work force and employers that are knowledgeable about the hazards. While I am for that, some of these decisions you might want to force on a worker who is a captive of that job is very difficult. I think those workers should work with management. Labor/management committees I think are great ways to come up with solutions to problems . 54 I have always said to the people in the labor community , why have you not put anything in your contracts on health and safety when you put it in there for an increase in pay and to pay for health insurance? The other thing I have to say in passing, I see under the incentive approaches you have listed liability measures. I am interested in that because I under- stand that is one of the things the Department of Commerce is doing now. They have a proposal that would spread the cost of product liability over us all, rather than over the industries who make the defective products. I was rather amused when I saw that as an incentive measure when you were talking about doing away with it. I must say some of those incentives I think are good ideas . MR. JASINOWSKI : On the product liability question, I think the issue has been resolved. C.L. is one of our experts in the Department so I will pass that on to him, but the issue has been resolved in a way which is not along the lines you indicated. C.L., do you want to comment? MR. HASLAM : Yes, but I don't think I will take up much time, since that "potato" is not hot. We have not proposed spreading the cost of product liability across society as a whole. We are looking at several tax aspects. We recommended including in the tax bill an extension from three to ten years of the carryback provision for net operating losses due to product liability costs, but I don't think we need to go into that now. MR. JASINOWSKI : Picking up from what Eula Bingham has said, there seems to be some agreement that the notion of looking at these questions on a case by case basis, using multiple approaches including incentives, and attempting to educate and negotiate at the firm level, is a useful idea. Is there anyone who wants to challenge that or modify it? Allen. MR. FERGUSON : I have problems with all of these points. I did not inter- pret John Meyer's statement as meaning case by case in the very small sense. I did not interpret it as meaning that each firm would be handled differently or that we would go the ICC route. MR. JASINOWSKI : I didn't either. MR. FERGUSON : If we are talking in terms of broad categories, I would not have much problem with that. The second point I want to make is this: We, that is the Public Interest Economics Center in a number of cases, have run into the notion that there is something immoral about paying a fine, i.e., that breaking a regulation and incurring a fine of 50C a year or $1,000 a day is a very different thing from paying $1,000 a day for anything else a producer buys. It seems to me that before we can go very far in incentive approaches such as taxes or user fees, there has to be something done to make clear that it is 55 not lying, cheating and stealing to pay the fee or fine involved. It is buying flexibility in a way that is exactly analogous to buying other things. If the "fine," is set appropriately, then eventually that will turn out to have been a good idea. At the same time, I want to make one comment that troubles me. I can show you, if you will accept my assumptions, that fines and incen- tives will bring one close to an economic optimum. But I can show, by exactly the same reasoning, that child labor laws are inefficient. Somewhere there is a kind of division here: Even if it is less efficient, there is a basis for not having child labor and there is a basis for not having grossly substandard housing and so on. This is a kind of boundary that has been widely accepted and it may get at some of the problem of occupational safety , environmental control and things like food safety nutrition. I have some other points, but I have taken enough time. MR. JASINOWSKI : Kerry Smith. MR. SMITH : I would like to followup on Allen's comments and get to the question of operationalizing a problem by problem approach to looking at the regulatory incentives used. In the paper that was distributed as part of this issue, there were a number of criteria identified. What we have to recognize, and I am sure John would agree with this, is that by focusing on a problem by problem approach, we simply economize on the kinds of information we have to bring to each decision. We still have to decide upon a set of criteria for making those decisions about what instruments or combina- tions of instruments will be used for the particular regulation. In the paper that was distributed, four such instruments were identified and since they relate to the comments Allen was talking about in some of the other discussion, I would like to go over them a little bit. One was effectiveness, another efficiency, another equity and the last, politi- cal feasibility. I found the definition of each of these used in the paper to be peculiar. That may be the most understated comment I could make. Effectiveness was stated in a way that would not be consistent say with John's comments this morning in terms of cost effectiveness. Efficiency was not stated in terms of what economists would normally define as allocative effi- ciency but rather what a prudent man would do under certain circumstances and ignored the potential interaction of macro efficiency. Equity was not defined in terms of equity to the affected parties but rather equity to those who we are regulating and I think that is a very unusual distinction. A lot of the concerns we are talking about in terms of the rela- tionship, let's say between certain sets of standards and what we might do with child labor laws, speak to the question of equity and what is a fair and reasonable solution to the problem. The last was the question of political feasibility and it seems to me that the issue we cannot afford to lose touch with is that the rulemaking process in 56 part is a function of what is a politically feasible set of legislation that gets by. In effect, what we do is make the laws a little bit more slippery perhaps because everybody can agree on them and leave to the discretionary authority of the agency the operationalizing of those rules. So there is an important interaction in how we apply these criteria and how we look at the legislation and evaluate it. Let me stop with that. MR. JASINOWSKI : Having said that, Kerry, what does that lead you to in terms of a correction of the meaning of the criteria so that they make more sense in the discussion we are having with respect to fees and incentives? Do you have any comments going beyond what you have said? MR. SMITH : I would say that efficiency ought to be defined in terms of resources being allocated to their highest valued uses. Equity ought to be defined in terms of a criterion that is more conventionally accepted by economists and social scientists and policymakers in terms of not just the parties being regulated but the parties being affected by the actions if there were no regulations . Effectiveness ought to be described in terms of the transaction costs associated with accomplishing a given objective. The cost-effectiveness analysis that John Meyer talked about earlier. Political feasibility it seems to me in part is not trying to second-guess what is acceptable to various interest groups. It is also trying to recognize what are the legitimate functions of a rulemaking body and what are the legitimate functions of a legislature. MR. JASINOWSKI : Making those corrections, does it lead you to any comments on the particular alternative approaches that one can take in this area? MR. SMITH : I guess the comment I would make is that probably mixed approaches are more likely to be the best overall, simply because they provide the most flexibility. If we are going to adopt a problem by problem orienta- tion, then it seems to me the particular characteristics of that problem will mandate a combination of one or more of the instruments. What we want to do is not fix ourselves into a particular set of instruments, but fix ourselves into a particular set of criteria for deciding on what instruments ought to be used. MR. JASINOWSKI : Bill Nordhaus is anxious to make a comment. MR . NORDHAUS : One small comment on negotiation. I think there are some places where negotiations are useful but others where they are not really the heart of the problem. You cannot expect a steel plant in Pittsburgh to get in negotiations with all the citizens of the State of Pennsylvania as to what effluent levels are allowed and what means of compliance should be allowed. 57 In the labor/management area, there's one possibility in safety standards say, but by and large, most of the major regulations involve too many parties. On the question of alternative approaches, there is something misleading about this discussion, saying we should be balanced and have a mixed approach. It might lead you to think that we have a balance already. The fact of the matter is that we have a regulatory system that uses 99.44 percent commands and virtually none of the things called incentive approaches. I think it is important to realize that when you say we ought to be balanced and use a mixture, that that is a radical change in the way this country would do business. Why is it that we do not use incentive approaches? I don't know any good answer to that question except that that is the way we have always done it and, golly, let's not change the way we do things. There is also the fact that Congress grants an authority to regulate, which means to set the regulatory dial according to how many parts per million of this or what exposure level of that. Congress has pretty much gotten out of the business by saying .2 this, or 1.0 that. Once you delegate to the regulatory authority the dial setting power, then you have to ask, would Congress also delegate the power to set taxes or fees? Pundits say of course not, although from time to time they do. In the energy bill they did delegate to the Secretary of Transportation the power to raise the noncompliance fee for the fuel economy standards. But I would like to differ from the audience here and say I think we can make a lot of progress by moving in the incentive approach whether it's by taxes or fees or noncompliance fees or whatever. There's just a lot of room to move and let me give one example. That is, under the '77 Clean Air Act, Congress granted the right in many areas of the country to increase the pollution levels, to have increments to pollu- tion. It's a little like the oil on the outer continental shelf, it is a natural resource we are going to allocate. How do you suppose EPA was going to allocate that? In the traditional way, first come first served. Now why in God's name would you want to do it that way rather than recognize that this is an extremely precious resource in many areas of the country, and it should be treated as one rather than squandered away to the first big utility company who gets to the door. If you really mean we have a mixed approach, we have a long way to go before we get to a real balance. MR. JASINOWSKI : John . PROF. MEYER : That's fair enough, Bill, but it seems to me we should not rush in willy-nilly to an incentive approach. That is really all I was trying 58 to inveigh against by pointing out that these different cases have different circumstances . Let me take a cut at a compromise. Perhaps some kind of standard setting, maybe done better than it is done today, makes sense, for example, when product competition is the basic difficulty, as in bleached paper or the aerosols. By contrast, a case where the incentive system may work very well is where you have some difficult tradeoff problems . Steel is a good illustration. As I understand it, it's basically a tradeoff between air and water pollution. When you get one corrected, you get the other adversely affected to some extent. Apparently some chemicals and some safety standards are of that type too. There the incentive and pricing approach might have a lot to recommend it because it gives people something to work on in making those internal tradeoffs. MR. NORDHAUS : I agree we shouldn't rush into it, but I think there is little danger of that. (Laughter. ) PROF. MEYER : There may be little danger of it, but let's face it, Bill, the economics profession does love to extol the virtues of simply extending the use of the pricing mechanism without recognizing there are some limitations on it as well. MR. NORDHAUS : Let's face it, people don't listen. MR. JASINOWSKI : Let's turn to Toby Clark for a minute and see what comment he might have on this question from the point of view of EPA. Toby, I know you have done some work in this area, and I guess you could say you are taking a gradual approach. MR. CLARK : Here again, I am personally a believer in incentive approaches, and EPA has recently become more interested in looking at incentive type approaches. We are not nearly as interested as Bill Nordhaus would have us be, nor are we proceeding as fast as he would wish, but we are interested. As a strong supporter of such approaches, I have been very frustrated over the years because economists have been doing little since 1972 except declaring that economic incentives are the superior answer. I believe it, I am an economist and it makes sense to me. But since 1972 economists have done little but build theoretical models of hypothetical air basins and things like that. They did very little to answer the nitty-gritty questions of how do you measure these pollutants, for instance, and how do you deal with some of the problems of interfirm equity, and things like that? We have just recently started some studies to answer these nitty-gritty little questions and they are not all that encouraging. In many cases, the more we look at the application of economic incentives, the less they seem to accomplish, 59 The advantages of economic incentives depend apparently on how clean you want things to be. The old Delaware River Basin study, for instance, showed that you got tremendous efficiencies from an incentive system as long as you did not want the water to be too clean. If you wanted the water to be very clean, that study showed there are almost no efficiencies to be gained from the incentive approach. This is the same thing being shown on some of the other studies we have ongoing now. If you are going to choose very rigid ambient standards, you don't get the tremendous efficiencies that you might originally expect. Nevertheless, I think EPA is strongly interested in such approaches and I think we will continue to look for opportunities to apply them. But I have to agree with John Meyer that there isn't any scheme that should be applied in every case. It has to be a mixed system. MR . B YROM : Jerry, to that point, I think it is a very important thing. It may very well be that the reason you don't get those efficiencies as you move closer to perfection is one, the fee you would charge is not high enough but probably more to the point is that the technology is not such that there is a way to efficiently avoid payment of the fee. Then I say to you, who says that regulation is proper when in fact the technology is not there to do it effectively on behalf of society? MR. CLARK : I guess what these studies are showing is that if you went to a high enough fee, you would get the same technology whether you specified the technology to begin with or set a high enough fee to drive everyone to the same technology. That's all these studies are showing. MR. JASINOWSKI ; Kerry Smith. MR. SMITH : I think there is a question here of damages that one might not want to lose track of. Just because the fees don't move us immediately to the idealized technology, that doesn't mean that we would not want to poten- tially use the revenues extracted from those fees to serve some desirable end such as compensating the parties who are damaged. The comments made here simply reinforce the discussion John raised originally. When we think about moving from primary to secondary to tertiary treatment levels with a static technology, we may not always induce an efficient response, in static terms. However, it is important to recognize that there are incentives set up for future technologies that may meet those standards, and I think that lends some support for the arguments Bill was raising. But I believe we have to be clear on what are our short-term goals in terms of meeting specific objectives for environmental quality or safety or whatever, what are our long-term goals and what is the relationship in terms of the time interval between meeting those in the selection of regulatory instruments. 60 MR. BYROM : I am sorry but to your point, that high enough fees do the same thing regulation does, I don't agree with that. I expected Bill to be the guy to step up and argue with you on that because the amount of discharge of effluent in a given water basin is not the same for everybody. If I happen to be guilty of 4 percent of the discharge and you are guilty of 40 percent of the discharge and the fee is high and the technology is costly, you might very well put in the new plant. But I would only proceed to pay the fee and we would end up getting the ambient condition at least cost to the society. MR. JASINOWSKI : I think there are a number of questions with respect to why incentives are not used more broadly. One of them has to do with budget resources. It is not so much the case with fees, but at least it is with incentives. Alice, I wondered if you wanted to comment on that and also, in terms of your broader background, add what you want on this question of alternatives. MS. RIVLIN : I'm not sure that budgetary cost is a reason why incentives are not more widely used. As I look around on Capitol Hill, I think the real answer is that most congressmen are lawyers, not economists. They don't think in terms of incentives. I think we have seen an example of that in the energy legislation. That was an economist's bill. MR. HOUTHAKKER : No. (Laughter. ) MS . RIVLIN : The whole thing originally turned on taxes and incentives, particularly in the parts dealing with coal conversion and the oil price itself. I think congressmen were really mystified by this. What are you doing here, they would ask. You are raising the price of oil through a tax so people will use less oil, and then you are turning around and giving them a tax rebate to maintain their previous purchasing power. This new way of thinking created a lot of genuine confusion. The same problem exists with regulatory incentives. If incentives are indeed the right approach — and I come out of this discipline, too — a long educational process will be needed before people think that way. I don't think the problem is budgetary. MR. JASINOWSKI : Thank you, Alice. Bill. MR. NORDHAUS : One lighthearted thing and one serious point. Alice is absolutely right. I remember the first day the crude oil tax was considered by the Senate Finance Committee. Senator Ribicoff was sitting there and he said, "As I understand this proposal, you raise taxes on oil and you give them away back to the same people." He said, "For the life of me, I can't understand what that's all about, it must be some economist who dreamed this up." 61 But the serious point is one of design of our tax system. We have lots of taxes on lots of different things. Whether it's capital gains taxes or labor taxes or whatever, these are widely acknowledged to be ones in which there is a disincentive to output, to efficient use of resources, to effort and so on. Use charges or whatever you want to call them are about the only example you can think of where, by imposing a tax and collecting revenue, this will move the system towards more efficient utilization of resources rather than less. PROF . MEYER : Bill, that's an empirical question. Take urban highway congestion. I am reasonably convinced in the present state of technology that to use user taxes as the primary means of achieving rationalization there, costs of collection would exceed benefits. And there are lower cost ways of doing it. You have to look at each one and take a very hard look, it just can't be generalized. MR . CLARK : May I add another comment that is that the fastest way to destroy an economic incentive system is to depend on its revenues for income. In an economic incentive system, you actually want to reduce your revenues by getting people to respond efficiently. MR. JASINOWSKI : Allen, you've been trying to make a point. MR. FERGUSON : I want to make a comment on incentives and I want to be sure that before we leave this general topic, I have an opportunity to talk about informational approaches but this might not be the right time to do that. The only thing I want to say on incentives is that the chart and the paper both treat subsidies as if they were in some sense co-equal with taxes. There is an enormous difference between the two and I am not referring primarily to the technical economic differences. But if one were to opt for a policy of subsidizing the removal of hazards and environmental contamination, that has a very different ethical and efficiency base from taxing people who are doing the contaminating. One way to say it is that the idea that a firm should be subsidized for removing a hazard can be turned around the other way and say that those who have been subsidized in the past by being able to use the environment as a free good are now to get a second subsidy to pay it back to the rest of us. I just want to make it clear that these are not symmetric kinds of considera- tions. I want to lay a claim to commenting on information before we leave the whole topic . MR. JASINOWSKI : Allen, let me followup on that. I think that's an important distinction. Are there any cases where the use of subsidies and incentives on the tax side ought to be pursued? You make a case that we ought not to help people who have used our resources badly in the past. Let me raise the question, are there qualifications to that? Fletcher. 62 MR . BYROM : I'm sorry but I disagree with the premise and I think this is one of the unfortunate things in our society, that too many people without thinking, and I suspect you did this without thinking, make that statement. That those who have benefited in the past — the fact is that our life style is based on the economic costs of the material goods we have produced. Unless the particular body, company you are talking about made usurious profits, if their return on investment was merely acceptable without having a charge for pollution, then in fact we were all benefiting, all the users. I think this is one of the mistakes we made and get hung up on emotionally about this whole pollution question. The fact is that it is_ proper to decide now that we want to improve the human condition by improving the quality of the environment. The fact is not that there were greedy, predatory managers and owners of companies which in effect had pilloried the society, that's just not the case and I am sure you know that. MR. FERGUSON ; I feel as if I should make a rebuttal comment. I certainly will not argue that I have thought about any of these problems — (Laughter. ) MR. FERGUSON : However, leaving that aside and emoting for a moment, let me point out that the output of goods and services is not in fact a complete reflection of economic well-being, and decisions as to how much to produce reflect private costs as they have been experienced and much of the question that we are dealing with is the internalization of social costs. Much as you have thought about it, I would suggest that your premise is not flawless. The second thing is thinking in terms of the proposal to subsidize the airline industry to remove the noisy engines. I think that's absolutely a clear case where that industry and the consumers using it and everybody else directly associated with it have in fact historically been subsidized by the people vulnerable to aircraft noise, and it is clearly a very different kind of a question as to whether subsidizing the air carriers is in some sense the mirror image of a tax on them for the noise they produce. MR . BYROM : I agree on subsidy but let's get this straight. The inter- nalization of social costs result in a higher price. You seem to assume that it reduces profits and I am assuming that it cannot. MR. FERGUSON : I certainly do not assume that. MR. JASINOWSKI : There is an in between point which is not going to be resolved today. On the one hand, simply subsidizing firms for the misuse of resources or inefficiency is a mistake. On the other hand, efforts to change that on a broad scale do affect price. Prices which were lower in a previous period are consumer benefits as well. John Meyer. 63 PROF. MEYER : If I understood your question, Jerry, there may be one example I can think of and that is the metal finishing industry and water pollution. The problem in that industry is that if you impose the water pollution controls, you force a whole reorganization of the industry. You would have to have a massive merger movement in order to keep costs within bounds. This is a case where possibly you might say there is some justifica- tion for subsidy or for a tax concession. MR . JAS INOWSKI : Are there any other general comments on the question of alternatives? We have obviously just scratched the surface and it deserves much more attention, but is there anyone who would like to make a final comment be- fore we attempt to cover this material generally? Professor Houthakker. PROF . HOUTHAKKER : A historical point. The case for a tax approach was argued at length in the Economic Report to the President in 1970 and '71 and was the basis for the sulfur tax, a proposal that didn't get anywhere. The main reason for this is that the informational requirements for correct tax levels are higher than for standards . At the same time, I think there is something to be learned from this and this has to do with the example mentioned earlier. If you want really absolutely clean water, then no amount of taxes probably will get you there, but is it ever efficient to want absolutely clean water? I think when we talk about the burden of regulation, then we are talking in part about this, that standards are set that are in some sense unreasonably high in the sense that people don't really want to pay the sacrifices needed to get absolutely clean water. It's obvious that you won't want to have water of suitable quality in all rivers, once you know what the cost of that is. The tax approach, even though it has practical limitations, does still give you a more correct answer. As a related point to this, once a tax has been set, then you don't run into the adversary problem you run into with standards. With standards, people say we can't possibly meet it and they have every interest to lie. I think in taxes that is less true. The correct solution depends on these different informational requirements. I feel there is a limited case for tax in certain instances. MR. JAS INOWSKI : Allen, you wanted to make a comment about informational techniques? MR. FERGUSON : Yes. Providing information is again a very stock kind of thing that seems to make excellent sense. I do not want to suggest in my comments that it doesn't make sense. I just want to emphasize that there are 64 fairly severe limitations, not only in terms of the information that is provided, but in terms of the ability of consumers or whomever to use the information. It doesn't do any good to write on the menu that if you have bacon for break- fast, you run a one-times-ten to the-minus-nine probability of getting cancer. That just doesn't — ten to the-minus-nine — communicate an awful lot. It's not just a matter of disseminating facts. It's a matter of consumers being able to assimilate them. The second thing is that there is a whole array of economic activities or anti- economic activities in the form of persuasion which, if they do anything, and that is clearly a question, undercut the basic premises of market economics by making the response of the consumer a function of the activity of the supplier. Unless some kind of governmental informational strategy gets at that, you are leaving a lot aside. Then there is the more straightforward problems of mis- leading advertising or misleading PR and so on. Those are all a part of the information problem and they are not treated by disclosure kinds of considera- tion, or kinds of action. MR . JAS INOWSKI : Let me now cut off this discussion because it is some- thing we will want to pursue further. We will obviously not resolve it today. What I would like to do in the remaining 45 minutes is to take on the difficult task of trying to see where we have some agreement, if not consensus at least plurality, in terms of what should be the future directions for research in action by this Department and the Administration more broadly. I feel that with your help and your good faith, we will be able to make some progress. Let me try to go over these items one at a time and after each one, have the group correct me or modify it as you will. It seemed to me in the first instance that there was an increased willingness on the part of business, the regulatory groups, the government broadly, and others to find common ground in working on regulatory problems. Given the impacts of regulations and the important goals that we are pursuing, regulation has not received sufficient attention in the context of economic policy. There is a desire to work together — frankly more than I expected — on the question of improving the analysis of benefits and costs and other impacts. We saw it in some of the exchanges between Fletcher Byrom and Eula Bingham and others. Am I overstating that or is that a fair assessment of the sense of the group? Eula will get the transcript so she can modify it to the extent she disagrees. Having said that, and I think that is an important movement in spirit, we then went on to the more difficult question of how to improve cost-benefit estimates and other impact measurements. I thought there was general agreement that the data was inadequate and there were biases in the data as Mark Green pointed out, both from business and as I indicated, from the various agencies of government. 65 I think we did have some important agreement as to how to move forward. There was general agreement in the morning session that we needed to move ahead on both fronts. Further, we ought to get more consistent or compatible cost estimates. Although the difficulties are significant, a consistency across the different kinds of cost studies is one important direction in which to move. I think there was also agreement that we need to improve benefit estimates. As Alice indicated and Eula agreed, if we could not measure benefits in money terms, we ought to try to measure it in some other terms. John Meyer made the important point that we ought to look at cost-effectiveness analysis in many cases because cost-benefit analysis is really too ambitious. Eula Bingham and others made the point that the agencies needed additional resources to work on this and that they needed help from both the private sec- tor and some of the non-regulatory agencies of government. Henk Houthakker pointed out that the Department of Commerce can do a better job on this because we have a lot of the data and statistics here. Finally, I thought Allen Ferguson made an exceptionally good point about distinguishing between different kinds of benefits and accordingly between different levels of benefit estimation. Those are useful directions for us to 'pursue. One of the things we did not do justice to today — it was just a matter of time — was that we did not go beyond the estimates of costs and benefits into the ways in which regulations affect productivity, economic growth, international trade and inflation. That is something that some of us have worked on and an impor- tant subject for future research and a future meeting. There has been some good work on that but there are many unresolved questions. An important priority for the future would be to pursue those areas. Yes, Mark. MR. GREEN : I suspect there was a consensus for a case by case study of trying to perfect the data to make more rational cost-effectiveness judgments at the agency level. Beyond that, to do it generally nationwide or industrywide could lead to the top down problem some of you mentioned. And it could lead to arbitrariness. Imagine the head of an auto safety agency saying — I have a regulation here for better bumper standards, by which consumers save more in the after products market than they would spend in buying the car originally. Then the government would close the door and say, whoops, you are the program over the arbitrary $10 billion limit, even though you can demonstrate that this regulation is efficacious and efficient. Also politically, I can't imagine a president every week desiring to be the final arbiter of the brown lung threshold. It's not something that I think presidents have done, perhaps for rational political reasons. MR. JASINOWSKI : Mark, I agree with you and I was going to take up the question of who does the various analyses under centralization versus 66 decentralization as a second point. I don't think we had quite the same agreement on it. I was just saying that the area in which we had some agree- ment was the ways in which we could try to improve cost-benefit and cost- effectiveness analysis, apart from the institutional arrangements. MR. GREEN : One more point. Lucy mentioned that one approach envisioned is this Department doing a cost aggregation and this might inspire better studies of the benefits. MS . FALCONE : The Commerce Department could not run this budget. I think I said it was clear we couldn't do it. MR. GREEN : The mere compilation of costs could lead to more studies of the benefit side. I think it more likely today for it to entrench the hostility against health-safety regulation. As you see in our bibliography, there is apparently one study in American history of all the costs of regulation, done by Mr. Weidenbaum, and it has been cited and recited and recited. I think any aggregation of pure costs would join that study to be used as a bludgeon against specific regulations. It could be a demogogic tool. MR. JASINOWSKI : Let me take that point one step further. We never did reach a consensus about the appropriate focus for further cost investigations. One alternative posed was to put more emphasis on the impact of costs at the firm and industry level. A second was to go on a case by case basis as Mark has suggested with respect to particular regulations. Finally, there were those who suggested that we needed to try to get a handle on the total cost. Are there any suggestions from the group beyond what Mark has said about future cost priorities? Alice. MS. RIVLIN : I would suggest that the priority should not be the total cost. That is obviously a large number and it doesn't matter very much exactly what it is because decisions are not made about total regulations. In general, I believe — and this applies to several different subjects discussed here — that one should take a manageable set of regulations or a manageable set of problems and look at the alternative ways of going about handling them — getting back to the cost-effectiveness point. Costs are needed at this more disaggregated level and to strive for consistency across large areas does not bear much relevance to the real world. MR. JASINOWSKI : Toby. MR. CLARK : I would agree with that, being a perpetrator of too many cost estimators myself. I find them not all that useful. But you would be surprised when you look into these estimates that one of the big problems is that nobody is using the same definition of what is a cost. We have set up a task force to try to develop consistent definitions of cost so at least we are using the same types of numbers. Even little steps like that are important. 67 MR. JASINOWSKI : Any other suggestions? Kerry Smith. MR. SMITH: I was going to suggest that focusing on costs alone can be misleading. I think we can get some information on priorities if there is an objective that can be articulated in terms of imposing a certain amount of costs on the economy in total as associated with regulations that may differ- entially impact on other aggregate policies. One way of prioritizing regulations is to pay some attention to the benefits associated with those. I don't think they need to be considered in isolation. MR . JAS INOWSKI : I agree with you and I hope to cover that as we move along. The next area in which there was agreement, with some modification from John Meyer to explain why there was so much agreement, is that economic regu- lation is an area where we do know enough to move ahead in most cases. John made the very interesting point that it is not hard to know enough because the benefits in so many cases are near zero and the costs are quite large. I think that was another area of agreement among the group. Having covered a number of areas in which there was agreement, let me move on to some in which we still have resolutions to make. There was considerable differences of opinion about the extent to which tradeoffs between benefits and costs were useful. The point was made by Alice and by Eula Bingham that it is difficult to make a tradeoff between life threatening elements and particular costs. No one had an answer to that which is not surprising because we have not had a good answer in the past, although Prof. Houthakker made the argument on the other side that there are limits even to that. Even though there was not a clear resolution of that issue, some progress was made. From the comments Eula Bingham made, she indicated that there was some need to take benefits and costs into account and that there was a difference between life threatening and other actions. There are other unresolved issues regarding the question of tradeoffs which we are not going to solve today and which deserve further investigation. I have listed two. One is the degree of Presidential authority with respect to making these tradeoffs. There were views on both sides, but I did not sense any clear resolution of that. In part, it is still a legal and political question. The second relates to the mandates of Congress and the way in which the mandates have, at least in an initial sense, resolved these tradeoffs. Beyond that, it is ambiguous as to how much further flexibility there is although in certain regulations, there is a great deal of flexibility. That is my summary of a very difficult area, and I am sure some of you might want to comment or modify what I have said. Toby. 68 MR. CLARK : You touched an issue which has been bothering me, an issue implicit in some of the comments made here and in a lot of other comments I have heard over the last few months . This is the tradeoff between actions which are directed at protecting health and those protecting amenities. EPA, as you probably know, is emphasizing health protection. That seems reasonable and I think most of the people around this table would say that that is a first priority. But I am frankly quite puzzled about what EPA should do about the results of public opinion polls which indicate a very high preference for amenities as well. There is as much support for controlling water pollution, which is primarily an amenity issue, as there is for controlling air pollution, which is primarily a health problem. Many people consider solid waste to be the worst environmental problem and frankly I don't know how to deal with that. How can economists effectively incorporate public opinion into analyses. Economic theory is based on the theory of consumer preference, and yet we don't have any way of incorporating this consumer preference into the calculations. MR . J AS INOWSKI : Let me move on with the summary. We then discussed a series of ways in which we could improve the general management of the regula- tory system. We focused on three areas. The first was improvement at the agency level. The second was general central review and oversight. The third was institutional mechanisms such as the regulatory calendar and regulatory budget. I sensed considerable agreement about the need to improve regulatory management at the agency level. There was acceptance, and you may want to speak to this further, Toby, on the President's Executive Order. Eula Bingham made the point that it can do some good things and we ought to leave it alone and work with it at this point. Others made the argument that maybe it ought to be expanded to independent regulatory agencies. In addition, there are ways to improve the analysis at the agency level and to streamline the process. I did not sense disagreement on that, although narrowing the gap between the promise and the reality will require a considerable amount of work. Moving on to the second area, we ran into a significant degree of tension within the group about the extent to which there ought to be some central oversight with respect to the activities of the regulatory system. The Regulatory Analysis Review Group seemed to be accepted to a considerable degree as a way to improve analysis as long as it did not impose its will with respect to tradeoffs. But as we moved further in terms of questions of the President's rights and the extent to which the Executive Office would impose itself on the process, there was clear tention within the group with Mark Green, Eula Bingham and 69 others saying it would result in duplication; it would politicize the system; and it would have other effects which either were unnecessary or were harmful. Others, including Bill Nordhaus indicated that there was a need to maintain some balance so that the analysis was honest and that control or coordination of the system overall was important. That is as well as I can summarize that discussion. I wondered if you would want to modify the summary in any impor- tant sense? MR . CLARK ; I would like to make a comment about the first part of your statement. EPA thoroughly supports the Executive Order. As a matter of fact, we have claimed it is really modeled after the process we had already instituted internally. I am not sure that our enthusiasm is shared by all the agencies, but I think basically people are in favor of going along the route set by the Executive Order. The Executive Order, of course, set up two processes. One for catching new regulations and one for reviewing old regulations. And this leads me back to the question you asked at the beginning of this session — should economic regulatory agencies be included as well. Setting up the first process — that directed at catching new regulations makes complete sense. You want to stop bad ideas before they catch hold. And this process necessarily will apply primarily to the health and environmental regulations for these are the programs currently being implemented. But when you go back and review old regulations, particularly if you are talking about something like a regulatory budget, I think we would feel very strongly that the economic regulatory agencies ought also to be involved in this effort. The whole price should not be taken out of the social and health regulations. MR. JASINOWSKI : I should add that Henk Houthakker made the point with respect to the whole question of balance in the President's authority that it's really a personnel question and that the President appoints these people and he ought to appoint the right people . Moving on from the question of some general oversight, we then got into the more difficult question of institutionalizing a means to do that. I believe the consensus was that the budget is an interesting idea whose time has not come in terms of immediate implementation. It is a long-term project with a great deal of problems to be resolved, including: who would do it, how adequate cost estimates are obtained, what should be the role of benefits, should the budget be purely an informational system or should it be a control system? Although we shed some light on it, principally the remarks of the group were to instruct the Department of Commerce and others interested in this to look very carefully at the hard questions that still remain and pursue the budget in that light. Any comments on that? Henk Houthakker. 70 PROF . HOUTHAKKER : I would just like to say the budget idea is a very interesting one even though not ready for implementation. It probably should be pursued by the private sector before being pushed by a government agency, as has been done with other statistical and budgetary devices. A lot of research and discussion is needed before the government can commit itself. MR. JASINOWSKI : John Meyer. PROF. MEYER : Picking up on that, if it is to be implemented, I think on the basis of the discussion that I have heard, it ought to be done in a few select areas, referring back to what Alice said, and it ought to be pursued all the way through. Again, I think Mark made some good points and several others here, too, that if you only get part of the costs, it can be very misleading and if you don't do something about properly measuring benefits, it can be misleading. I think it would be far better — even if it is messy and admittedly it probably will be — to try to do as comprehensive a job as you can in a few test areas rather than trying to do only part of it, say only the direct costs, across-the-board. I also think you get information that is potentially more useful in identifying key trouble spots. My hypothesis is that in each one of these, we are usually likely to find a key tradeoff or trouble spot when we get into the details. MR. JASINOWSKI : Alice. MS. RIVLIN : I would like to underline that and make a further point. As I have listened to this discussion all day, I have been struck by the resem- blance to discussions about the expenditure budget 10 or 15 years ago. The issues are the same — value of human life, consistent treatment of costs, and so forth — and I think the dangers are the same . The danger then was that the government would rush into a great comprehensive system of analyzing public expenditures, which indeed it did in the Planning, Programming, and Budgeting System (PPBS) before anyone figured out how to do this. I think that the regulatory budget although it is an interesting idea, has the same danger. It is attractive to create a huge system, put everything in it, and figure that somehow the problems will all shake out. With a compre- hensive system, we would overload ourselves with information and with low- quality analysis. The other danger, if we ever do a regulatory budget, would be to have it done every year. We should learn a lesson from the history of the expenditure budget. For heaven's sake, don't do it every year. It is hard for me to imagine anything sillier than reviewing old regulations every year. MR. JASINOWSKI : Thank you, Alice. We should add the comments of Allen Ferguson with respect to the emphasis on what we really want in terms of goals rather than just the costs as part of the regulatory budget. 71 I should say that with respect to the Department's own activities, we are proceeding on a pilot basis. We expect to pick out two or three areas and to analyze those and to do so in a way that is selective and limited. We hope within the next year to advance that in the context of at least a special analysis to the budget for selected areas. I think that is doable and I would put that positive note on it with respect to the Department's own views. There are other topics which we never had a chance to discuss, and I would like to take these up for a few moments . One is the question of sunset review which goes in part with Alice's point of reviewing regulations at some point over a period of years. There are a number of legislative proposals to attempt sunset review for regulatory action. If a regulatory budget encounters difficulties, what are the advantages of moving ahead with a regulatory calendar, a proposal which is not as broad and all- encompassing as a budget but attempts to find out what proposed regulations are coming forth next year, get the best cost estimates and best benefit or goal view of them, and establish priorities. I wonder if we could speak to those two issues at least briefly to see what guidance you would provide us with in terms of future action. Would anyone like to comment on the sunset review proposals? MS. RIVLIN : I am attracted to sunset review for regulation, but I think it should be viewed simply as a mechanism to force the executive branch and/or the Congress, presumably both, into a periodic review of various areas of regulation. There is a sense of urgency in the warning: if you don't do this, everything will stop; your regulations won't count anymore. If, however, there were any danger of that happening in an area in which regulation is important, the Congress would find quick legislative ways to fix the problem. Sunset review is thus really a gimmick, but it may be a useful gimmick to force some periodic reconsideration of all regulations on a flexible, sensible schedule. MR. JASINOWSKI : Dick, do you have any thoughts on the sunset review proposal? MR. LESHER : I agree pretty much with what Alice just said, but I would go one step further and say I think it is coming regardless of what we decide around this table. It is something whose time has come, both in the regulatory process and in the broader based budget items of the Federal government. The premise that we all begin with is that we are beginning to reach up against limitations to the point where you have to make a tradeoff analysis. Sunset is one way of forcing the issue and I think it's much more than a gimmick. I think it is a concept that forces decisions. MR. JASINOWSKI: Allen. 72 MR. FERGUSON : I would make the comment that a great deal depends upon the definition of regulation. It is clear that the idea of review regulation by regulation is ludicrous. At the same time, I am very concerned about again focusing an attack on quality of life regulations. Clearly, I would be all in favor of a sunset provision on all import quotas and all export subsidies and on the stock cartel regulators. To repeat, those are areas where we know what we are doing, where we know how the market would work if it were left to itself. Quality of life regulation is not an area where we can rely on the market. I would say two things, one if there is to be regulatory sunset provision, it should cover a very wide range and it should do it in a fairly broad way rather than specific regulation by specific regulation. MR. JASINOWSKI : It would seem to me, Allen, that even though we may know what we are doing better in some of these areas, periodic review and evaluation of all regulations is something we all agree ought to be done but it's a ques- tion of doing it correctly. Am I overstating it? MR. FERGUSON : We live in an area of vast uncertainty. If you know there is something you can do with a net payoff, I think one can make a strong argument for doing it. You cannot review all regulations, that is a will-o'- the-wisp. Basically what I'm saying is the obverse of the regulatory calendar. It's a deregulatory calendar and I think it is sensible to begin — I really would argue a little more sophisticatedly than I have. One, begin where you know what you are doing and two, on both sides of this, the regulatory calendar and the deregulatory calendar, look for the big issues, the big benefits, the big costs and don't mess with all the little ones. MR. JASINOWSKI : Dick. MR. LESHER : I think Allen made the case for messing with all regulations. If he said we can't review all regulations and at the same time implies that we must live with all of those, there is a certain contradiction in that statement, I believe OSHA right now, for example, is in the process, a two-year process of reviewing all regulations and I think that's an ongoing responsibility of each agency. If you go to one of these overview organizations, then perhaps I would agree with Allen, you can't mess around in there with each and every detail but you do have to have some universal review of the whole process. MR. JASINOWSKI : Mark Green. MR. GREEN : The goal of sunset is to compel the executive branch and executive oversight committee to review how a program or agency is doing. I support a sunset of congressional committees rather than agencies. That is, the budget of a congressional committee cannot be spent unless that committee has engaged by a date certain in a kind of zero based thorough 73 periodic analysis of an agency program or agency. This would mean that if nothing were done, the committee would expire rather than the agency. There is one version of sunset to permit an especially hostile and powerful committee chairman, suppose Rep. Jamie Whitman, to initially pass on the FTC sunset. I would be pretty nervous if I was the Federal Trade Commission. Such a sunset approach could lead to the demise of agencies simply because the clock has run, rather than due to a thorough analysis. MR. CLARK : I was going to make a comment on the sunset provisions . This again is one of the regulatory reforms EPA has instituted internally already. We have said that we will develop a process for reviewing regulations in effect. I have not observed that process operating. I think the problem is, and this is one we have to keep in mind all the time , that there are substantial oppor- tunity costs in any such effort. The more effort we spend looking at what we have already done, the less effort we can spend looking at what we are doing now and doing it better. That's one opportunity cost. The other opportunity cost is that the more we delay what we are doing now the longer society will suffer from what we are trying to correct. There is a problem in this tradeoff between looking at the past regulations and doing a better job on future ones. The final point I would raise is that I suspect if we seriously talk about substantially changing our regulations, the business community might well end up complaining. The argument would be, we have built all these plants with this old regulation in effect, and if you reduce the requirement, you will be giving new plants a competitive advantage over us and that's not fair. That is the congressional notion of equity. MR . JASINOWSKI : Fletcher, would you like to comment on that specific question or more broadly on the question of sunset review? MR. BYROM : Not really. MR. JASINOWSKI : We've worn you out, really. MR . BYROM : I think everything has been said that is pertinent to the discussion. MR. JASINOWSKI : I think you've all been very patient, very productive. Secretary Kreps, myself, and others thank you. I only have one further ques- tion and that is, what would be the view of the group regarding the continuation of a seminar such as this, perhaps quarterly or at some other interval? Is there any feeling that we ought to do this on a regular basis or should we just go off and work quietly on these various problems? PROF . MEYER : One suggestion. I do admit to hesitation because I realize there are hazards in it. But it might be useful to think of experimenting 74 with some groups that are a bit more specialized and trying to see if there is some way of institutionalizing (while not creating a new set of dangers) a process to get people to talk about particular tradeoff problems. MR. BYROM : I think that one of the things that is so essential, this is nothing original here, but we need to have dialogue on these things. I just think that somehow or other, we have to find the means whereby we can break down the adversary characteristic of the advocacies that we have and get to the point where we try to make the society work. I don't know how to do it except to sit around and talk. MR . JAS INOWSKI : Any other comments before we close? MR. LESHER :* I would followup on John's point. I think there is a great deal of specialized work going on and you can bring these folks together and pull together some of that research and see what you have agreement on and what you have disagreement on and then a different type of group to come together to look at these broader based policy issues. Following up on what Fletcher just said, I think the Department of Commerce is due a word of thanks for convening the meeting. For too long, it has been a case of an adversary relationship and I think that increasingly, we agree on the goals and the questions are the most effective means to those ends. When you get to that stage, you can put aside the adversary relationships to some extent and begin to come down to these basic questions about how to get there. Meetings of this kind are most worthwhile. MR . J AS I NOWS KI : On that positive note, we will end and we thank you very much. (Whereupon, the meeting was adjourned.) * Submitted by Mr. Lesher as an Appendix to the Transcript of Proceedings : While there is a long way to go before we will have satisfactory data on benefits and the total costs of regulation needed for a fully-developed regu- latory budget, we think it is desirable and possible to take some more limited steps which might improve the Executive decisionmaking, as well as the public discussion, on governmental regulatory activities. For example, even though there are major hurdles before we have good data on compliance costs and induced costs, there is some value and no worthy objection we are aware of in producing a recapitulation and analysis of the budgetary costs of all of the government's regulatory activities. Similarly, while we are a long way from having adequate benefits data on regulatory activities, it could be very useful if each regulatory agency were to pull together its best estimates and judgments about the compliance costs and the benefits (and the beneficiaries) of the regulations they propose and enforce . We believe such initial steps could be very useful in advancing the dialogue and the decision process in a constructive way. 75 BACKGROUND PAPERS 77 PREFACE TO BACKGROUND PAPERS Participants in a Department of Commerce seminar on the subject of regulatory reform were provided with several background papers as points of departure for the day ' s discussion. Though not offered as examples of extensive research or original thinking in this field, the papers underscore some of the issues of concern. The call for regulatory reform arises from a suspicion (in some quarters a conviction) that the Nation's economic interests are not being well served by the present body of government regulations. The public discus- sion of regulatory agencies, their functions and policies is essentially a dialogue on the best ways to arrive at a number of widely agreed-upon goals. It is also, implicitly, a reexamination of the ways in which business entities behave under various kinds of guidance, constraints, admonition, incentives, and penalties. The debate in this country is no longer over competitive markets, product safety, livable environments, constructive use (including nonuse) or vital resources, and removal of hazards from the workplace. Within tolerances, these may be taken as settled issues. The argument is about our methods to achieve the desired objectives through Federal intervention. How much are we willing to pay and who should pay for what? Are prescriptive rules in every case the most effective, least burdensome method of getting results? Are there perhaps more subtle, indirect levers that might be applied? Above all, what are the true costs of regulations to set against their undoubted benefits, and has the time not arrived for a system of accounting to guide policymakers in these matters? The analytical tools brought to these questions will do much to set the tone of our inquiry. If, as some observers suggest, the heavy compliance costs borne by industry are largely the assumptions of burdens previously shouldered by the public, then in a sense they are not costs at all, or at least not new costs. If these expense items are mainly a transfer, then regulations involve philosophical and political choices. On the other hand, if regulations are viewed as instigators of totally new costs of such size as to become a major propelling force in inflation, or a deter- rent to productivity and economic growth, the subject deserves careful economic analysis and sober consideration wherever fiscal policy is formulated. Such would certainly be the case should preliminary studies indicating compliance costs for U.S. industry of the magnitude of 6 to 8 percent of Gross National Product prove substantially correct. It was in this context that the Department of Commerce, via its Office of Regulatory Economics and Policy, commissioned a series of studies (of which these four are short-term examples) of the effects of Federal regu- tions on firms, sectors of industry, geographical regions, and the economy 78 as a whole. The Department also began exploring the concept of the "regulatory budget" to anticipate, if possible, the problems that might be encountered in setting up an accounting procedure somewhat parallel to that of the national budget, and to consider its potential usefulness to the executive and legislative branches. What we now have on hand are surveys of research already completed on the effects of government regulations, on the costs and benefits at various levels and divisions of industry. We are beginning to find ways of obtaining national aggregate figures, and we are making a start in assess- ing the longer term implications of regulations on industrial structure, location and technological change . As the magnitude of the compliance burden becomes more and more apparent, we must give more attention to regu- latory alternatives. And our work on the regulatory budget is presently examining, conceptually, a comprehensive regulatory review process which might possibly be integrated into the existing annual budget process. One of the clearest conclusions to emerge from a survey of existing literature on the costs and benefits of government regulations is the fact that research on this subject is in its infancy. Respectable work is indeed to be found, but very little of it is mutually compatible. In an annotation of about 40 current quantitative studies, one author (Synergy) felt obliged to caution readers against making comparisons of the data presented in the tables, because the methodologies, data bases, and theoretical and analytical problems differed from study to study. The estimation techniques ranged from the most sophisticated macroecono- metric forecasting models available to informed guesses. And yet, if only for sheer dimension, there were startling conclusions. One research foundation study placed the economic loss from regulation of surface freight as high as one-third of the total income generated. A Federal commission estimated the costs of required paperwork at more than $100 billion annually, divided about equally between the public and private sectors. An analysis of air pollution abatement costs between 1976-1983 by a private consulting firm foresaw an investment of $53.6 billion, with annual operating and maintenance expenditures of $123.4 billion. A study of the cost of implementing federally-mandated social programs at colleges and universities showed an increase, over a ten-year period, from a negli- gible share to as much as one-eighth to one-quarter of the general admin- istrative budgets of the institutions surveyed. On and on the figures reverberate — exaggerated, perhaps; duplicative and overlapping, possibly; but certainly suggestive of substantial costs. It is argued that compliance costs of such magnitude must not only cast shadows across the marketplace in terms of investment, product development, profitability, and inflation, but also must have an effect on industrial location decisions. Are cities and regions being aided or victimized? It is reasoned, but hardly demonstrated, that the maintenance of environmental integrity may be less burdensome in one urban area than in another. We do not know as yet whether regulations by themselves bring about differential compliance costs here or there so significant as to be measurable factors in the birth, death, expansion or movement of U.S. firms. Intuitively it 79 would seem that regulations should have an effect on urban and regional economies. Yet, a recent review (Consad) investigating the impact of clean air requirements on actual or prospective industrial location decisions failed to reveal any clear trends. The rationale of the Clean Air Act is such that it is likely to have substantial locational effects, but it may be too early to discern such regulation-induced changes. Locational decisions are often such complex ones that a firm might find it next to impossible to assign compliance costs their proper weight amid scores of other reasons for staying or leaving. There are undoubtedly neat balances to be struck: the cost of remaining in the old location requiring heavy investment in allowably antiquated facilities versus the cost of investment in new technologies. Behind such dilemmas lies the largely unexamined proposition that there may be more effective, less burdensome ways of rescuing the environment, pre- serving the marketplace, assuring product safety, and keeping citizens healthy than through the enforcement of literally tens of thousands of government rules. Rules to be written, interpreted, administered, litigated over, revised, superseded, and endlessly published. For the past generation, social scientists have been asking whether it is possible that standards could be sustained with more loosely held governmental reins, whether some alternatives to regulations as we now know them could achieve the desired goals with considerably less strain on all parties. Are there indeed areas of industrial activity which could be better channelled by a combination of incentives, penalties, fees, taxes, subsidies, direct compensation to injured parties, permits, educational programs, disclosure, or other ways? Agreement is already widespread among professional economists that price and entry regulation in inherently competitive industries leads to inefficient utilization of resources, higher than necessary prices, and untapped market potentials. Many critics of the regulatory approach point to the waste which results when uniform requirements must be met in circumstances where there are notable differences in conditions. Some are especially concerned by oppor- tunities lost through uncertainty, inflexibility, and the slowness of regu- latory agencies in issuing or modifying rules. Others deplore regulatory impairment of entrepreneurial initiatives that might lead to productive enterprises. All abhor the red tape, the nuisance, and the invasion of privacy. Above all, they feel that problem-solving toward social ends can best be done on local grounds rather than by a remote bureaucracy. We do not know if alternatives to regulations will work; we have never tried them on any significant scale . Some observers insist that almost any alternative could be made to work, as well as existing procedures. As an illustration, the typical community rarely enacts laws prescribing the cutting of front lawns, but most lawns do seem to get cut. Other commenta- tors suggest that Federal regulations merely hasten a process that would eventually take place. Yet, it is precisely this slowness in responses to society's pressures that has provided the impatient impetus for heavy government intervention. The dominant impression left by our regulatory system is that it is not a system, that it is an aggregation of older and newer controls, assembled 80 in an ad hoc, add-a-part manner, for both presently needed and obsolete purposes. If its effect on the economy has become so great that it keeps company with defense, health, and education expenditures, the time is ripe for considering a mechanism such as a regulatory budget, to rationalize the regulatory process. One of our studies (Data Resources, Inc.) is tied to the assumption that a regulatory review process would induce greater sensitivity to total costs and provide at least the gateway to an eventual regulatory management system, should that prove desirable. The one great impediment to a budget-like accounting of regulatory compli- ance costs is the difficulty of obtaining accurate information on costs. Cost information can only come from the regulatory agencies involved or from industry itself. One can anticipate extraordinary differences of opinion and interpretation in such attempted reckonings . In any case, there is often a fine line to be drawn between certain devel- opmental or modernization expenses which might or might not have been incurred by industry, absent regulations. Without regulations, what would today's automobile look like? What other kinds of investments would the automotive industry have made in the past decade had it been free to build any kind of a car it wished? If we knew, we would have a much clearer understanding of regulatory burdens and benefits. Often Federal agencies and private industry may understate or overstate compliance costs. Our problem is to find a referee. No discussion of compliance costs can be very useful without consideration of offsetting benefits. It is generally the case that the benefits of regulations are more diffuse than their costs. An improvement of air and water quality may be slowly perceived, a decline in employment recognized overnight, while the connection between such benefits and costs — if there is a connection — may be difficult to establish. Clearly, a new set of regulations originates in the anticipation of benefits, an expectation that intolerable injuries will cease, or the desire to prevent some disaster from occurring. The regulatory impulse is benefit-oriented, and it often presents the economist with value-based conflicts or assertions that his discipline is ill-equipped to deal with. Conversely, the affixing of price tags on social goals confronts the consuming public with tradeoffs it is inexperienced in facing. We may be left in the position of the over- enthusiastic shopper who has paid "too much" now for things he will be happy in the long run he purchased. Our existing regulatory institutions are the result of prolonged considera- tion and painstakingly arrived-at decisions in past years through legislative and executive interaction. The methods (and underlying philosophies) which were mandated to regulatory agencies represented, at the time, our best solu- tions to the problems needing correction. Even in the light of changed economic and social circumstances, and new national perceptions, the present missions, procedures and relationships of these agencies cannot and should not be casually or abruptly changed. We need to proceed with both care and resolution to achieve consensus on how regulatory issues are to be dealt with in the future. COSTS AND BENEFITS OF REGULATION A SURVEY OF STUDIES Prepared for: U.S. DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE The Assistant Secretary for Policy Office of Regulatory Economics and Policy Prepared by: Lee Dymond; Donald Zimmerman; Terrence Davey SYNERGY, INC. 2337 18th Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20009 Purchase Order No. 8-36342 August 1978 A-3 COSTS AND BENEFITS OF REGULATION: A SURVEY OF STUDIES Summary The objective of this study is to survey and summarize the existing literature on the costs and benefits of government regulations. To accom- plish this task an annotated bibliography was prepared based largely on studies published during the 1970s which develop quantitative estimates of the costs of government regulation. The study is best characterized as a reference document which allows the reader to summarily acquire a feel for the breadth and depth of existing knowledge of the impact of regulation. The intention was to include an overview of knowledge regarding the benefits of regulation, however, the paucity of work in this area largely precludes giving the reader a quantitative overview of regulatory benefits. In addition to the annotated bibliography and the more extensive biblio- graphy of additional studies , a separate annotated bibliography of data sources, presenting the costs of compliance with government regulations, is also included. That separate annotated bibliography is necessarily brief, indicating the scarcity of published data. The studies chosen for annotation and summarized in the following tables reflect an objective choice of quality studies which include quantitative estimates of the costs of government regulation. The information presented is divided into five categories. These are: Table 1: Impact of All Regulations on the National Economy Table 2: Impact of Multiple Regulations on the National Economy Table 3: Impact of Multiple Regulations on a Specific Group or Industry Table 4: Impact of a Single Regulation on the National Economy Table 5: Impact of Single Regulations on a Specific Group or Industry The annotated studies represent a wide range of research methodologies, data generation and manipulation, and conclusions about the costs and benefits of government regulation on the economy. Estimation techniques range from informed guesses to the evaluation of regulatory costs through the most sophisticated macroeconometric forecasting models available. The level of sophistication and hence, quality of information provided, extends over a wide range, with most studies employing fairly elementary statisti- cal techniques . A brief survey of the tables indicates that the impact of all regulations on the national economy has not received much research attention. This type of study is quite difficult because of the need for comprehensiveness. A-4 Studies of the impact of multiple regulations on the national economy are more common and present a far greater breadth and depth of coverage, by industry and regulation, than do the studies of the impacts of all regula- tions on the national economy. Studies which assess the impact of multiple regulations on a specific group or industry are largely confined to environmental regulations, especially air and water pollution. More common are studies which assess the impact of a single regulation on the national economy. Here, in addition to environmental regulations, studies on the regulation of transportation, both air and surface, and agricultural regulations receive much research emphasis. Table 5 shows the impacts of single regulations on specific groups or industries, but this information is deliberately kept to a few selected examples. This category contains the overwhelming majority of studies done on the impacts of regulations. Space permits a presentation of only a few studies as an example of the type of analysis and cost estimates developed. Table 6 on Data Sources reveals that data sources on pollution abatement costs comprise most of the available data on the costs and benefits of regulation. Even in the area of environmental regulations the amount of published data is quite limited. It is difficult to summarize briefly the results of all of these studies. Any attempt to determine an aggregate cost of regulation will, on the one hand, necessarily involve doublecounting across studies and on the other hand, most likely understate the true costs of regulation because few of the studies include all costs of regulations. If any conclusions can be drawn from the information presented herein, they must center around the notion that research on the impacts of govern- ment regulation is in its infancy. Much additional work in the areas of model development and data generation is sorely needed. Different studies undertaken to assess the impact of government regulations on the same industry present difficulties in making comparisons. The area of study on the benefits of regulation has merely been alluded to with very little in the way of quality research having been completed. For all of the reasons mentioned above, the reader is cautioned not to depend upon the summary tables included in this report as a basis for any determination about the impact of government regulation on the economy. Careful reading of the annotations, indeed of the studies themselves, is necessary before one can begin to assess the state of the art in measuring the impacts of government regulation. A-5 TABLE OF CONTENTS TOPIC Page I. SYNOPSIS A-7 Introduction A-9 Synopsis and Conclusions A-9 Structure of Report A-10 II. SUMMARY TABLES ON COSTS OF GOVERNMENT REGULATION A-13 Table 1 - Impact of All Regulations on the National Economy. . A-15 Table 2 - Impact of Multiple Regulations on the National Economy A-16 Table 3 - Impact of Multiple Regulations on a Specific Group or Industry A-18 Table 4 - Impact of a Single Regulation on the National Economy , A-20 Table 5 - Impact of Single Regulations on a Specific Group or Industry A-25 Table 6 - Data Sources A-26 III. ANNOTATIONS OF STUDIES ON THE IMPACT OF GOVERNMENT REGULATION. . . A-29 Impact of All Regulations on the National Economy A-31 Impact of Multiple Regulations on the National Economy .... A-33 Impact of Multiple Regulations on a Specific Group or Industry A-51 Impact of a Single Regulation on the National Economy A-80 Impact of Single Regulations on a Specific Group or Industry A-120 IV. EXTENSIVE BIBLIOGRAPHY ON REGULATORY IMPACT STUDIES A-125 Impact of All Regulations on the National Economy A-127 Impact of Multiple Regulations on the National Economy .... A-128 Impact of Multiple Regulations on a Specific Group or Industry A-132 A-6 TABLE OF CONTENTS (Continued) TOPIC Page Impact of a Single Regulation on the National Economy a-134 Impact of a Single Regulation on a Specific Group or Industry A-138 V. DATA SOURCES ON THE COSTS OF GOVERNMENT REGULATION A-139 Sources of Data A-141 Annotations A-142 Bibliography of Data Sources A-146 VI. INDEX A-149 A- 7 I. SYNOPSIS A-9 SYNOPSIS INTRODUCTION The objective of this study is to survey and summarize the existing literature on the costs and benefits of government regulations. To accomplish this task an annotated bibliography was prepared based on current quantitative studies of the costs and benefits of government regulation. Most of the studies included are limited to those published during the 1970 's so that the information and data presented is relatively current. A more extensive bibliography of studies which attempt to measure the costs and benefits of government regulation appears at the end of this document. In addition to the annotated bibliography of studies measuring the impact of government regulation and the more extensive bibliography of additional studies, a separate annotated bibliography of data sources, presenting the costs of compliance with government regulations, is also included. That sepa- rate annotated bibliography is necessarily brief, indicating the paucity of published data. SYNOPSIS AND CONCLUSIONS The studies reported in this evaluation present a wide range of research methodologies, data generation and manipulation, and conclusions about the costs and benefits of government regulation on the economy*. Estimation tech- niques range from informed guesses to the evaluation of regulatory costs through the most sophisticated macroeconometric forecasting models available. The level of sophistication and hence, quality of information provided, extends over a wide range, with most studies employing fairly elementary statistical techniques. The generation of data also ranges from informed guesses to precise engineering cost estimates. In some cases this is unavoidable. For example, in the area of environmental regulations, much of the proposed pollution control technology has not been commercially tested and thus real world cost experiences are nonexistent. A brief survey of the tables indicates that studies which assess the impact of all regulations on the national economy do not receive much research attention. This particular type of study is the most difficult to undertake because of its explicit need for comprehensiveness. Studies of the impact of multiple regulations on the national economy present a far greater breadth and depth of coverage, by industry and regulation, than do the studies of the impacts of all regulations on the national economy. Studies which assess the impact of multiple regulations on a specific group or industry are largely confined to environmental regulations, especially air and water pollution. The greatest frequency of studies are those which assess the impact of a single regulation on the national economy. Here, in addition to environmental regulations, studies on the regulation of transportation, both air and surface, and agricultural regulations receive much research emphasis. Table 5 shows the impacts of single regulations on specific groups or industries, but this information is deliberately kept to a few selected examples. This category contains the overwhelming majority of studies done on the impacts of A-10 regulations . Space permits a presentation of only a few studies as an example of the type of analysis and cost estimates developed. The last table on data sources reveals that data sources on pollution abatement costs comprise most of the available data on the costs and benefits of regulation. Even in the area of environmental regulations the amount of data published and available is quite limited. It is difficult to summarize briefly the results of all of these studies. Any attempt to determine an aggregate cost of regulation will, on the one hand, necessarily involve double counting across studies and on the other hand, most likely understate the true costs of regulation because secondary and tertiary costs are not considered in most, if not all, of the studies undertaken to date. Secondary and tertiary costs are those costs which result indirectly from the primary costs of regulation. For example, in the area of noise pollution control, the primary cost of one abatement procedure may be to erect a barrier along a highway. The purpose of the barrier is to block the noise created by surface transportation. The secondary cost might be the decrease in value of the land adjacent to the highway and the barrier because of the unsightliness of the barrier. A tertiary cost in this case might be the cost to local government revenues resulting from the lower tax receipts collected on the lower valued land adjacent to the barrier. If any conclusions can be drawn from the information presented herein, they must center around the notion that research on the impacts of govern- ment regulation is in its infancy. Much additional work in the areas of model development and data generation is sorely needed. Different studies undertaken to assess the impact of government regulations on the same industry present difficulties in making comparisons. The area of study on the benefits of regulation has merely been alluded to with very little in the way of quality research having been completed. For all of the reasons mentioned above, the reader is cautioned not to depend upon the summary tables included in this report as a basis for any determination about the impact of government regulation on the economy. Careful reading of the annotations, indeed of the studies themselves, is necessary before one can begin to assess the state of the art in measuring the impacts of government regulation. STRUCTURE OF REPORT The first section of this report is composed of several tables which summarize the types of regulations that affect various groups within the economy and the sources of data available. The reader is cautioned against making comparisons of the data presented in the tables, because the metho- dologies, data bases, and theoretical and analytical problems differ from study to study. Following the tables is a section composed of the abstracts of the studies surveyed. The information in the tables and the specific annotations of studies are not meant to be exhaustive of the studies which provide quantitative estimates of the costs and benefits of regulation. Time and resource constraints require that only a sample, however represen- tative, of the more important studies be presented here. Following the abstracts is an extensive bibliography of studies available on the impacts A-ll of government regulation- Again, the extensive bibliography is much more complete in its coverage of studies of the impacts of regulations on the economy, but it is not by any means comprehensive of all the studies that have been undertaken to date in this area. Following the extensive bibliography is an annotated bibliography of data sources. All the information presented in this report is divided into categories. The five main categories surveyed are : 1. Impacts of all regulations on the national economy, 2. Impacts of multiple regulations on the national economy, 3. Impacts of multiple regulations on specific industries or groups, 4. Impacts of single regulations on the national economy, 5- Impacts of single regulations on specific groups or industries. This particular categorization scheme is suggested as a way to evaluate the research available on the impacts of government regulation, but it is in no way the only possible technique for segregating the various studies. While one might argue that particular studies cut across two categories or even that a particular study belongs in a different category, such controversy lends more credibility to the categorization than is intended. The fifth category, that is, the impact of single regulations on specific groups or industries is surveyed in a much more general and cursory fashion than are the other categories. There are several reasons for not detailing those studies that would be included in this category. The first is that even if one were to compile accurately all those studies undertaken to assess the impact of a single regulation on a single industry or group, it is not clear as to how they could be added together to determine the impact of government regulation on the economy. The second reason is that there is a very large number of studies of this type and much more time and many more resources would be needed to undertake this task than current research efforts permit. The tables which follow only include those studies which are annotated in this report. The studies chosen for annotation and summarized in the tables reflect an objective choice of quality studies which include quanti- tative estimates of the costs of government regulation. There are several people who have aided in the completion of this report. Robert Miki, William Sullivan, and the Department of Commerce staff have been very helpful in securing studies and commenting on annotations and the extensiveness of bibliographies. Professor Paul MacAvoy of Yale University was quite helpful in providing a bibliography of studies assessing the impact of government regulation on the economy. We wish to thank these people for their efforts. All remaining problems and errors in this study are the responsibility of the authors. A-13 SUMMARY TABLES ON COSTS OF GOVERNMENT REGULATION A-15 TABLE 1 IMPACT OF ALL REGULATIONS ON THE NATIONAL ECONOMY Source Year Administrative Compliance Total Costs Costs Costs Weidenbaum and DeFina, The Cost of Federal Regulation of Economic Activity 1976 $3.2 billion $62.9 billion $66.1 billion A-16 TABLE 2 IMPACT OF MULTIPLE REGULATIONS ON THE NATIONAL ECONOMY Source Year Regulations Included Total Costs Bergs ten, C. Fred, The Cost of Import Restrictions to Ameri- can Consumers not Tariff and non- given tariff restric- tions At least $10 billion and may exceed $15 billion annually Chase Econometric Assoc, Inc.. "The General Economy," The Economic Impact of Pollution Control — A Summary of Recent Studies (CEQ) 1976 Industry pollu- 1980 tion control standards Without government fiscal and monetary policy: decrease in GNP (constant dollars) — $13 billion for 1976; decrease in GNP (constant dollars) — $8 billion in 1980 With government fiscal and monetary policy: no decrease in GNP in either 1976 or 1980 Moore, Thomas G. , "Deregulating Surface Freight Transportation" 1960s Interstate Com- merce Act regu- lations for surface freight $3,775-$8,890 million (includes costs due to inefficient use of mode, traffic shifted to alter- nate mode, and traffic not carried) "Weidenbaum, Murray L. Business, Government and the Public 1974 Safety and pollution stan- ards of new automobiles $3 billion (cost to con- sumers @ $320/car, 9.5 million cars sold) MacAvoy, P. W. , "The Effectiveness of the Federal Power Commission" typi- cal year in the 1960s Federal Power Commission regulations $46 million in FPC expenditures A-17 TABLE 2 (continued) IMPACT OF MULTIPLE REGULATIONS ON THE NATIONAL ECONOMY Source Year Regulations Included Total Costs Chase Econometric Assoc, Inc., The Macroeconomic Impacts of Federal Pollution Control Programs 1973- Environmental 1977 regulations (air and water) A. Air Pollution Abate- ment Costs in 1973 dollars Total Investment Costs -$26.9 billion; Annual Costs-$38 billion B. Water Pollution Abate- ment Costs in 1973 dollars: Total Investment Costs -$28.9 billion, Annual Costs-$24.1 billion 1978- 1982 C. Air Pollution Abate- ment Costs: Total Invest- ment Costs-$23.3 billion; Annual Costs-$78.2 billion D. Water Pollution Costs: Total Investment Costs -$73 million; Annual Costs -$24 million Moore , Thomas G . , Freight Transporta- tion Regulation: Surface Freight and the ICC 1968 ICC Regulation $3.8-$8.8 billion A-18 TABLE 3 IMPACT OF MULTIPLE REGULATIONS ON A SPECIFIC GROUP OR INDUSTRY Source Group/or Industry Regulations Year Included Total Costs Arthur D. Little, Inc. Economic Impact of Environmental Regula- tions on the U.S. Copper Industry Thompson, Russell G. , Jas. A. Calloway and Lillicen A. Nawalanic, The Cost of Electri- city: Cheap Power vs. A Clean Environment Copper 1978-87 Clean Air Industry and Act as 1974-87 Amended (1970 and 1977); Fed Water Pollution Control Act as Amended (1972) Electri- 1975- Air and cal Util- 1985 Water ities Pollution 1974-87: $2,771.9- $2,978.3 million (1974 dollars) 1978-87: $1,861.9- $2,067.7 million (1974 dollars) Total investment Q i^ Sj s: o 5 <3 >^ Co O k. 5 s: o K kj ~- CD to CO n H ■a Eh c, o g.l o _o b) *» tU O E o e c o o .52 o C c 1> O. rt 5 o x: U U O M £ 2 O rj C o c 2 CJ O 2 o o co CJ C « o o "- to rt D u . *-» -t^ rt . — . . -* ^ t> l_ i_ C «3 C — t"~ >» x ,_.y cj cj — ■a c ° .5 « & t.^1 c o U Sou. e> E > c 5} x> • "" c « £ Ove. to 1 " «2 • V r- r*> x> — ' - -a -.a - ■— * ^r o °> O -o | o..E •; l» C CJ < O H C A u.£o. • X c c — x: a . ^ = ^ •-o>, &3--S. _ rt o "5 "~ °- o 5 o E E 3&< c 3 — ° c ^ o c O rt JZ xiJ — o. x: > *n "* x u. o t> CJ 5 5 c > o o , "C >. 3 (J ■a ~ - 8. CJ "• en t— . u. O OCJ c ^ s o o o z: c a. >» co O CJ *-* C CJ — Zl §s ^^- •a <~ ■ ^^ o oo " Hn-5 - » E CS to o .5 S o « ■a -5 HO E o J= O • -E Hut)" ° r"5 o Z3 CJ o E £ o 5 «j E o r: o o w .z: U « • " °- s « r^ — o o r; 3 i- >- C o r J rt ijg S-JS >. — ^ .o "5. 2 ^ « E h > x «J « o o "r-d> _C_ C r" "^ h« a a. Ecj >. .— cj o rt o E r-i « •a 'I 5 -^ to — O C c^ ° CJ „ to ES.E >. > = . o " ,ca -a LU C O CJ ■ — E « O co c c 3 u. F S. D. E o c; D ^.2^ JO ■a o E c X) o wEb-y .E c,r:o •o o a a 2 *> N" o x r: — — > 2 ° =« r- O CJ o .i: jc -o >> X) o E "E^ C ^ « O O «J " > > S3- n c -*»• "O co ;z: CJ o ^ _, C c 3 5 a xi s o S ^ E >» CJ CJ -.2 in CJ « "en 8" — c* c E El >» E-o |8 »„ c* o •- ■£ 5 CI ^ ~ ■° "S,.o v-" •£8s cr ^-> *" t^ ^i -j E .5 £ i. "O si « 3 B = ^^ .> y «> 3 c c: £o t: — ^ "C o =" >. r n vi c o « x: 8 £ .5 > eo CJ j-. *J ,CJ Ci> c^ a -^ 01 XJ ^J tr .y 3 > X) o c ■a c -a o- C -0 a c c "E Si II t: 3 c.y -a S o 5 c o rt t> c -- D. - - C y. i> o u,y u »i a 3 a _. ^> S O c rt CJ C3 — - C ej: g_ >• o cT c c o o > V, co c - <-S E cj «; t> i; — ^f rt tn « E D- C <- " E o E o CJ X S on tj en Q. 5 x; 3 CJ c ^j O jt: 5 _C en X o on tj tj -o en en O CJ tn C3 o E 5 r^ "u- CO E ^ o c-» E 3 -CT o C w; b ™ "CT 3 < 5. r; cj d o CO c Cu A-49 (10) Dorfman, Robert, "Incidence of the Benefits and Cost of Environmental Programs," American Economic Review (February 1977). Purpose : This paper analyzes the distribution of benefits and costs of environmental programs among segments of the population. Methodology ; The study presents Department of Commerce estimates of cash flows incurred for pollution control and abatement in 1972, categorized by broad sectors of the economy in which the cost was incurred. All the costs, whatever their point of initial impact, are ultimately defrayed by households. Government expenditures are transmitted by increases in taxes and by reduction in governmental services. Business expenditures are shifted to households, primarily through price increases. The benefits of pollution control programs are very difficult to estimate. The study attempts to estimate benefits from a survey conducted by the Gallup organization. The survey measures benefits by tabulating the amount people are willing to pay for a clean environment. Constraints ; Benefits of pollution control programs are extremely difficult to quantify. Conclusions ; The main conclusion is that a clean environment is a superior good and that at any stated price, more people at higher income levels are willing to buy it than are people with lower incomes. The study indicates that environmental protection programs entail a redistribution of income from consumers to producers , and the sums involved may be of substantial magnitude . A-50 (11) Hendricks, Wallace, "Regulation and Labor Earnings," The Bell Journal of Economics, (Autumn 1977) . Purpose : This paper investigates the contention that regulation by altering the structure of pricing policies of certain industries, has given unions the ability to raise wages above the level which would have existed in its absence. Methodology : Data are obtained for seven different occupations covering a range from white collar to unskilled blue collar jobs. The specific occupations were chosen because they are fairly comparable across industries and because reasonable sample sizes can be obtained for most regulated industries. The study uses regression analysis with three alternative specifications for the regulation dummy variable : 1. A single dummy variable for a regulated industry is used. 2 . Industries in the regulated sector are divided into three groups based on the extent and type of regulation. 3. A different dummy variable is assigned to each regulated industry so that they can be compared individually with manufacturing industries . Constraints ; This hypothesis is not easy to test since there are few (if any) workers in the same occupations in unregulated industries . Conclusions : The paper attempts to analyze the impact of regulation on the wages of labor of a given "quality." Once quality is controlled, earnings in regu- lated industries are generally lower for the occupations studied than in other industries. But with the possible exception of airlines, truck drivers in trucking, and electricians in radio and television, there is little support for the contention that unions have "special power" in regulated industries. A-51 IMPACT OF MULTIPLE REGULATIONS ON A SPECIFIC GROUP OR INDUSTRY A-52 (12) Arthur D . Little , Inc . , Economic Impact of Environmental Regulations on the United States Copper Industry (Washington, D. C. : Environmental Protection Agency, 1978) . Purpose : To assess the economic impact of the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1970 and 1977 and the Federal Water Pollution Control Act Amendments of 1972 on the domestic copper industry. Regulatory Intent : The intent of these regulations is to reduce sulfur dioxide emissions during smelting and converting. The regulations require that: The NAAQS are met at all times by use of permanent emissions reduction technology; all new sources must use BACT: significant deterioration of air quality in areas where ambient air quality exceeds the standards is not allowed; and where standards are not met, reasonable progress toward meeting them must be made. Water pollution standards apply to the mining, milling, and refining stages of copper production. Methodology : Assess the impact of environmental regulations on such key economic parameters as prices, output, employment, international trade, etc. Assess impacts on industry structure and competitive position. Capital and operating and maintenance costs for pollution abatement are determined based on historical data, mainly engineering cost estimates. The study is evaluated over the period 1974-87. Costs are in constant 1974 dollars and annualized. Assumptions : 1. All smelters will continue to rely on acid plants, tall stacks, and SCS to meet NAAQS . 2 . There will be no fundamental change in the cost or nature of pollution control technology. 3 . Smelters will not expand in ways inconsistent with meeting NAAQS. 4 - Kennecott at Ely and Phelps Dodge at Douglas will shut down in either 1983 or 1988. 5 . All operating smelters will invest in fugitive emission control systems . 6 . There will be little additional permanent control of smelter emissions beyond that currently employed. Constraints : 1. Paperwork and reporting costs are not considered. 2 . Capital expenditures do not include interest charges for external financing. Conclusions : 1. Under a constrained capacity scenario, this total of capital expenditures and increased operating and maintenance costs equals $2.1 billion for the period 1978-87 and $3 billion for the 1974-78 period. A-53 (12) 2. Under the reduced capacity scenario, the costs are $1-9 and $2.8 billion, respectively. The table below sets out the details of these costs. POLLUTION ABATEMENT EXPENDITURES (Millions of 1974 dollars) Constrained Capacity Reduced Capacity Capital Capital Expenditures O&M Total Expenditures O&M Total 1978-87 $1,162.5 $ 905.2 $2,067.7 $1,013.5 $ 847.8 $1,861.9 1974-87 1,875.3 1,103.0 2,978.3 1,726.3 1,045.6 2,771.9 A-54 (13) Thompson, Russell G., James A. Calloway, and Lillian A. Nawalanic , The Cost of Electricity; Cheap Power vs. a Clean Environment (Houston, Texas: Gulf Publishing Company, 1977). Purpose : To determine the increase in investment needed to meet air and water pollution control levels for electrical utilities. Methodology : A linear electric power model was used. It was structured to meet a national electrical power demand of 2.5 trillion KWh. It was used to estimate the increased investment needed for compliance of pollution control. Analyses were made for five different levels of pollution control. These cases were: 1 . power production and waste treatment configuration existing in 1974 2 . zero discharge of wastewater and particulate removal equipment 3. case 1 with new plants required to meet new standards on waste discharge 4. maximum restrictions on air emissions 5. maximum restrictions on air and water discharge Conclusions : The total increases in investment for the period 1975-85 in billions of 1973 dollars are: Case 1 $40.09 2 43.45 3 48.17 4 68.25 5 67.89 A-55 (14) Commission on Federal Paperwork, Final Summary Report (Washington, D. C. U.S. Government Printing Office, October 3, 1977). Purpose : To estimate the total costs of federal paperwork . Methodology ; The methodology of estimating costs was not given. Constraints : The costs are only estimates. Conclusions : The total costs of federal paperwork are more than $100 billion annually, Cost estimates to major segments of the economy are: Billions of Dollars Federal Government $43 Private Industry $25-$32 State and Local Government $5-$9 Individuals $8.7 Farmers $.35 Labor Organizations $.075 A-56 (15) Boothe, Joan Norris, Cleaning Up; The Cost of Refinery Pollution Control (New York: Council on Economic Priorities, 1975) . Purpose : To estimate the capital requirements and total increase in product cost of achieving legislative levels of air and water pollution control in the petroleum refinery industry. Methodology : The Council on Economic Priorities estimated, based on information about the pollution control share of total refinery costs, the total capital requirements to meet total refinery pollution control. It then subtracted estimates of equipment already in place (estimates obtained from the American Petroleum Institute and the U.S. Department of Commerce) from this. It then estimated costs of new refinery capacity. Product costs were calculated from a model containing depreciation, cost of capital, and operating and maintenance costs. Constraints : Cost estimating procedures were not given in the text. Conclusions : The total costs of pollution control investment needs in millions of 1974 dollars are: 1974-77 1978-83 Total Upgrade existing $1,000 $ 800 $1,800 1974 capacity Control new 450 100 550 1974-77 capacity Control new — 1,000 1,000 1978-83 capacity TOTAL $1,450 $1,900 $3,350 Total added product costs in millions of 1974 dollars are: Total 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1974-83 Low $198 $319 $435 $546 $560 $574 $593 $601 $606 $610 $5,042 High 236 387 537 682 706 730 759 777 792 806 6,408 A-57 (16) Temple, Barker and Sloan, Inc., Economic and Financial Impacts of Federal Air and Water Pollution Controls on the Electric Utility Industry, Executive Summary . Prepared for the Office of Planning and Evaluation, Environmental Protection Agency, May, 1976. Purpose : To examine the combined effect of EPA's direct regulatory programs on the electric utility industry. More specifically, the study addresses four impacts: (1) the direct financial impacts of the regulations on the electric utility industry and its customers; (2) the effect on the ability of the investor- owned segment of the industry to finance both its basic needs and the pollution control equipment associated with the regulations; (3) the differences in the impacts on utilities and consumers in different regions; and (4) the secondary impacts upon other industries, especially major industrial users of electricity, Regulatory Intent ; With respect to the Clean Air Act of 1970, the analysis focuses upon two regulated emissions: (1) sulfur dioxide and (2) total suspended particulates. The electric utility industry is a major emission source of both. In terms of the Federal Water Pollution Control Act, the study analyzes three types of effluent guidelines: (1) thermal effluent, (2) intrainment organisms and (3) chemical effluent. Methodology : A detailed projection of the industry's baseline conditions is made for the period 1975 to 1980 and 1975 to 1985. Emphasis is placed on a 5-year growth rate in sales, a 5-year growth rate in peak load, capital expenditures since 1974 and external financing since 1974. Baseline projections on annual operating revenues, average consumer charges and average residential customer's bills in dollars per month are also made for the years 1975 to 1980 and 1975 to 1985. An estimate of the impacts of pollution control equipment installed to meet federal regulations and state and local regulations is made separately as well as an estimate of the impacts of the installation on projections of generating capacity. The additional costs from compliance with the regulations are modeled into a computerized policy testing model of the electric utility industry developed by the contractor. Revised forecasts are then obtained based on the additional costs attendant with the pollution control procedures . Assumptions and Constraints : The executive summary of this particular report does not highlight the assumptions and constraints of this study. Conclusions : The major direct financial impacts are the following: (1) capital expenditures for plant and service will increase by $25 billion during the 1975 to 1985 period, (2) capital expenditures in the 1975 to 1980 period will increase by $14.5 billion, (3) external financing during the 1975 to 1985 period will increase by $21.9 billion with a $14.5 billion increase during the 1975 to 1980 period, (4) the combined effect upon operating revenues and average consumer charges is projected to be a 6.7 percent increase by 1985, (5) direct impact upon the average residential consumer is to increase his average 1985 bill of $42.40 by $2.80 per month. Direct A-58 (16) and indirect impacts will cause an increase of approximately $5.80 per month in the average residential customer's cost of goods and services including electricity. An analysis of regional impacts shows that the East North Central region will be the hardest hit in terms of capital expenditures, while New England would be the least impacted. Secondary impacts would, in general, be very small. The total increase in operating and maintenance expenses is estimated at $1.8 billion per year by 1980 and $3.2 billion per year by 1985. The total premium paid by consumers because of federal pollution control regulations is projected to be $3.9 billion in 1980 and $6.5 billion in 1985. Over the entire period of 1975 to 1985 the cumulative cost to consumers will be $40.2 billion. A-59 (17) Sheppard, W. , et_ aJU Battelle Columbus Laboratories, The Economic Impact of Environmental Regulations on the Petroleum Industry, Phase II Study , a study for the American Petroleum Institute, June 1976. Purpose ; To provide a reliable, self-consistent data set on the cost of pollution abatement regulations impacting all of the various sectors of the U.S. petroleum industry. Costs occasioned by state and local regulations are included. The final objective is to provide information on incremental energy requirements occasioned by environmental regulations. This study encompasses the base year through 1985 with the base period being the year in which the industry first incurred a cost due to an environmental regulation and thus varying "for different regulations . Regulatory Intent : The regulations covering this industry include the Clean Air Act, the Federal Water Pollution Control Act, and the Noise Abatement Act. Two regulatory scenarios are considered in this study. The first consists of anticipated regulations, e.g., regulations either in effect now or which the EPA and Battelle believe have at least a 50 percent probability of promulgation by 1985. The second scenario, the restrictive regulatory scenario, includes regulations which are believed to have a reasonable probability, perhaps 10 percent of enactment by 1985, if national environmental policy demands more stringent controls . Methodology ; The study includes federal, state and local regulations and their costs. Three areas were considered: offshore, coastal waters and the outer continental shelf. Capital costs and operating costs were given primary attention. Annualized costs were calculated by adding the cost of financing to the operating costs. Determining environmental costs involves determining the costs of controlling the pollution problem, not necessarily responding to specific regulations . Thus , the methodology entails determining exactly the pollution problem, determining the control technology needed to abate the problem, and estimating the capital costs of the abatement procedure. The estimates of abatement costs come from various sources. The ten most costly regulations impact the following pollution problems: sulfur in gasoline; sulfur in fuel oil; wastewater and rainwater effluent in refineries; brine disposal, onshore and offshore; noise in refineries; lead-free gasoline; vapor controls; sulfur in refinery fuel; gas; prevention of pollution of shallow aquifers during drilling and production; and pollution subsequent to abandonment of wells. After estimates of the cost of each of these pollu- tion problems to be abated are developed, for each senario for onshore, offshore and outer continental shelf areas and for all levels of government, they are summed to get the total costs of pollution control. A-60 (17) Assumptions and Constraints ; The regulations and attendant costs are not included. Where the impact was small, say $10 million total investment, and the difficulty in obtaining figures large, the problem was omitted. Some regulations did not lend them- selves to forecasting. They are not included. Other costs, environmental in nature, were not related to current or expected regulations (e.g., land- scaping and screening of refineries and producing wells) . Some opportunity costs were estimated, but not included in the grand total. No attempt is made to calculate present or future R&D costs related to pollution abatement on the part of either the industry or its suppliers. Much of the cost data collected from various sources showed some inconsistencies. Conclusions : The table below shows a categorization of annualized costs to 1985 expressed in millions of 1974 dollars for specific abatement procedures by sector of the industry. The four sectors analyzed are: exploration and production, transportation, refining, and marketing and distribution. Each of the two scenarios anticipated and restrictive, are shown separately, as are the costs incurred for federal as opposed to state and local regu- lations. The total cost of regulations on the petroleum industry equals $10.3 billion under the anticipated scenario and $17 billion under the restrictive scenario. Of the $10.3 billion expenditure under the anti- cipated scenario, $5.5 billion is due to federal regulations and $4.8 billion is due to state and local regulations. Of the $17 billion expenditure under the restrictive scenario, $10.6 billion is due to federal regulation and $6.4 billion is due to restrictive state and local regulations. In terms of industry sectors, refining accounts for large portions of the total cost for abatement. In the anticipated scenario, of the $10.3 billion total expenditure, $7.6 billion is incurred in refining. In the restrictive scenario, of the $17 billion total expendi- tures, $12.7 billion is accounted for in the refining sector of the industry. These figures represent 73.4 and 74.5 percent respectively of expenditures . (17) A-61 o w PS w CO 53 o o CO S3 O M < O w PS ^, o to F- CO O CJ Q W H CO W o >* Pi S CO H>:h>-( puu ojujs OAJ }.1J i JUJJJ 3AJ JJJjnsojj jciopoj pojcJjDjjuy u pu p w ^1 o •o to *f 1» c ./> ca 1/t »T-# *o >%-o > c I — o o •J c: O u **-• £ *H - W Q. C M •-• O iJ u 1J Wi -< C «1 _l <_1 « *> <> 3 o. o o cj jr —* c O > W ^-» - rH to Eh o t: «j - R ^4 i3 r-l — • •1 w ifc * IV o o — ' ■> J ° o o *j o j: -^ -^ "n on o. t: J 3 O o. o o f-» -O ■4 O «**" fM« •-• •« A-62 (17) Table 9 (continued) summary of estimated costs of regulations considered- cone. 1985 Annualized Coats Pollution Problem Regulation -o Disposal of dirty ballast and bilgevatec Concatenation of no-lead gasoline Trans-Alaska Pipeline System Environmental Impact Spill prevention and cleanup Hydrocarbon emissions during tanker and barge loading Hydrocarbon emissions from pipeline •torage (Alaska) Transportac ton Segregated ballasts on new domestic tankers over 70,000 DVT, 1977 Mo sheen permitted from discharges of oil Trans-Alaska Pipeline Authorization Act 1973 & 1974 Segregated ballasts on all new tankers over 70,000 DUT, 1980 No oil discharge permitted 1983 Segregate gasolines 1974 Trans-Alaska Pipeline Authorization Act 1974 Deepvater Port Liability Fund 1974 Contingency planning and oil spill cleanup responsibility 1973 Double hulls on new tank barges 1979 Double bottoms on new tankers in domestic trad.- 1980 Retrofit double hulls on existing tank barges 1980 Maximum at 0.5 psia vapor pressure during Houston/Calveston tanker and barge loading 1973 Maximum of 0.5 psia vapor pressure during tanker and barge loading at various ports 1978 Recover vapors or incinerate 1974 Totals, Transportation 9.6 1.1 41.7 2.3 47.8 11.0 41.4 4.4 45.8 19.: 205.1 19.7 .224.8 9.6 1.1 41.7 10.9 1.6 2.3 47.8 11.0 41.4 4.4 10.2 49. i 45.8 56.4 275.9 56.4 332.3 (17) A-63 Table 9 (continued) summary of estimated costs of regulations considered -cont. 1985 Annualized Cost (Million 1974 $) Pollution Problem Regulatloa Refining Particulate emissions from Nev source, 1 lb/100 lb coke burned after FCC Unit "* rch ' 197A All existing retrofit to 1 lb/100 lb coke by 1977, All retrofit to 30 lb/hr maximum by 1980 Submicron particulate emissions **g house or equivalent required by 1983 on new source from FCC unit Smol'.c from flares CO emissions from FCC units (CO boiler) Sulfur in refinery fuel gas Sag house or equivalent required by 1980 on new source Bag house or equivalent in existing units by 1983 Smokeless flares required, 1977 New 60-irces, 500 ppm after March, 1974 Retrofit 500 ppm by 1977 New sources, 100 ppm after 1980 EPA regulation for new refineries 0.1 grain H S/DSCF, 1974 Retrofit to new source standard by 1977 Retrofit to new source standard by 1975 New sources, 90 percent removal, 1977 Bay Area. 300 ppm, 10 ppm ground level 300 ppm on existing units by 1980 100 ppm sulfur lu 1930 30 ppm sulfur in 1980 Claus sulfur plant ^ c * New source, 99.5 percent recovery by 1977 All units 98 percent recovery by 1980 All units 99 percent recovery by 1980 (a) Not included in total (b) Included in cost of ocher regulation (c) Hypothetical regulation used to include cost of sulfur plant as a separate category. SO. emissions from FCC units Sulfur in gasoline Sulfur oxide emissions Emissions from sulfur plants A-64 (17) Table 9 (continued) SUMMARY OF ESTIMATED COSTS OF RECULATIOHS CONSIDERED -Cant. 1985 Annualized Coses (Million 1974 $) Pollution Problem Regulation at u <-> o <=> _j o. O C u c -< © n > o -r« o Sulfur in fuel oil Lead in gasoline Hydrocarbon vapor from steraga tanks Hydrocarbon emission from oil* vater separators Wastewater and rainfall effluent (BOD. COD) Cadmium Cyanide Noise control New utilities limited to 0.7 percent sulfur, August 1971 Existing local sulfur limits (0.3, 0.5, 1.0 'percent, etc.) Twice existing requirements for 0.3 percent S oil Unleaded 91 RON grade available, 1974 Lead phasa out schedule } 185.9 Floating roof tanks for 1.5+ psia liquids In new tanks, 1974 Floating roof on all tanks for 1.5+ psia liquids, 1980 Covers required on new units, 1977 Covers required on old units, 1980 EPA rules for 1977, 1983 State regulations Zero discharge for 1985 Coastal refineries 320 ug/1: inland 70 or 2000, by 1977 100 ppb fee* cyanide by 1977 Residential property line, 55 dBA by 1985 Residential property line, 45 dBA by 1985 923.7 (a) 14.5 (-2.8) 1708.5 (b) (a) See footnote page V-122 for comparison with a mote recent estimate. (b) Not included in total. 1893.1 26.6 173.4 569.0 2553.9 923.7 14.5 Ca) 26.6 (-2.8) (b) 2267.1 (-15.9) 173.4 >: 1138.0 Totals, Refining 4273.2 3287.4 7560.4 8107.7 I 4506.5 12694.2 A-65 (17) Table 9 (continued) summary of costs of regulations considered (cont'd.) 1985 Annualized Costs r-'lllion 1974 $^ Pollution Problem Regulation tx n •a "O iH o V 4 u •j u «5 « o P. O.J •H ^4 O o -a •H ■n c u K <• 5 5 Hydrocarbons from storage tanks Contamination of unleaded gasoline Hydrocarbons from service stations Hydrocarbons from distribution Oil spills Discharge of oil Distribution and Marketing Floating-roof tanks for 1.5 + psla liquids In new tanks, 1974 Floating-roof tanks for 1.5 + psla liquids la old tanks, 1980 Unleaded 91 RON grade available, 1974 Collect vapors from vehicles by balanced system, selected new stations, 1980 Collect vapors from vehicles by balanced system, selected existing stations^ 1976 Collect vapors from vehicles by blower system, selected new stations, 1980 Collect vapors from vehicles by blower system, selected existing stations, 1976 Collect vapors from station tank filling, selected new stations, 1980 Collect vapor from station tank filling, •elected existing stations, 1976 Collect vapors from selected new terminals, bulk plants, and trucks, 1980 Collect vapors from selected existing terminals, bulk plants, and trucks, 1976 SPCC plans 1975 HPDES permits 1977 Zero pollutant discharge, 1985 0.4 133.7 8.3 11.3 218.1 0.6 42.3 17.6 43.9 44.2 96.4 0.4 133.7 t 27.2 0.6 42.3 17.6 43.9 59.4 512.5; 1 » 44.2. 96.4 Totals, Distribution and Marketing GRAND TOTALS ALL SECTORS 246.8 370.0 616.8 5480.1 4818.7 325.1 664-6 989.9 1 1 10.585. 3 1 6449.3 10,298.8 17,034.6 ~I A-66 (18) Public Interest Economic Center, Who Bears the Cost of Pollution Control?: The Impact on the Distribution of Income of Financing Federally Required Pollution Control . Prepared for the Council on Environmental Quality and the Environmental Protection Agency, August, 1973. Purpose : The purpose of this study is to determine the way in which the costs of the national environmental program will be distributed among various income groups throughout the country. Methodology : The pollution control expenditures distributed in the study are taken from The Annual Report of the Council on Environmental Quality, 1973 , and provide a 10-year forecast of the incremental costs of pollution control. Pollution control costs include those for air pollution control, solid waste management, water pollution control and automobile emission control. The distribution of financing between federal, state and local government is then determined over the time period up to and including 1980. These three groups make up one of three categories of costs . The second and third categories include private industry's expenditures and automobile emission controls which are the responsibility of the individual user of automobiles. Two kinds of measures of the way in which costs would be distributed among families are (1) an estimate of the average dollar cost per family unit within each income bracket, and (2) an estimate of the effective tax rate Or the dollar cost expressed as a percentage of total income within any income bracket. The latter is used as a basis for measuring progressivity or regressivity of the distribution. Tax increases are distributed to income classes in proportion to the taxes paid by each group in 1972. All the data are contained in a Brookings Institution's Data Merge File. Survey data are taken from the 1967 Census Bureau's Survey of Economic Opportunity . Using the file, it is possible to obtain the distri- bution of income for any definition of income. With a definition of income it is possible to obtain from the Merge File the effective tax rate within any income bracket for any tax, based on whatever incidence theory is selected. The data in the Brookings file are used to distribute the burden of a tax on the various incidence theories by simulating the effect of any income tax structure on the tax returns of each individual in the sample. The Brookings Merge File also allows the simulation of the distribution of any specified change in taxes. With projections for 1976 and 1980 of income distribution and the distribution of tax payments, changes in effective tax rates and income distribution due to pollution control expenditures are developed. Assumptions : Each of the specific areas studied has a number of assumptions made about the analysis. We report here only some general assumptions which are made throughout the entire study for reasons of brevity and clarity. The study relies on the best available data, but only looks at primary costs and does not look at secondary costs throughout the economy. In addition, the study does not look at benefits from pollution control expenditures and thus there is a bias in assessing the impact on particular income distributions within the economy. The financing of government expenditures on pollution control is assumed to take place under two alternative methods . One is to increase taxes sufficiently to cover the incremental outlays and two is, of A-67 (18) course, planning a reduction in government expenditures. It is assumed that local governments finance all capital expenses through bond issues. The first major category of assumptions assumes that the economy is highly competitive with perfect mobility of resources and an inelastic supply of capital. A tax on any form of capital is considered to be shared by all owners of capital in proportion to the income they receive from this source, The second major assumption, more likely in the short run than the first assumption, is that the property tax on improvements is borne by the occupants of residential property and consumers of products produced using commercial and industrial real property. The share of property taxes which falls on land is borne by the owner. The corporate profits tax is borne equally by the owners of capital and by consumers of goods and services. Constraints : Only the primary costs of pollution control are considered. The secondary costs and other ramifications throughout the economy are not considered. Only the costs and not the benefits of pollution control expenditures are evaluated. Conclusions : The three tables below provide a summary of the distribution of pollution costs calculated as, cost as a percent of family income for the three different types of financing (all governments, private industry, automobiles) for the years 1972, 1976 and 1980. Note that in each of the years the private industry costs as a percent of family income decline as income increases. Automobile costs also decrease as income increases, excluding the very lowest income category. The all governments pollution control costs change relatively little across income classes and may show a slight tendency to rise toward the very highest income classes. This conclusion is true regardless of the particular assumption made. (18) A-68 10 Eh co H co O o t! Q rt 9 M a o c_> u B X o >< M ►j r-j H O O g 55 Ph w o r ~J H « g w ra s < H w CO *: H a CO & o u ei § co o i . S H Z> CO CO * * CO u y M CO o 2: o >* y 2 O U< H to 9 10 3 o CO CM o in o CM r-t ST ■q 1 * o .-i O 00 n V0 CN M cr> CN CN o O o o 03 rH -T *y *r T ■V •^ • CN CM o (TV O CT> O CM CT» O CM 1 1 CM 1 rH 1 H <]) CM •3" CO CO 13 C D tn o O O O CM CM in m 1 1 I VI CD m O CD > rH CM CM o a, B m IQ # O rH 10 fci c -H to 2 % (!) rH •A «H td tt 6 * •* CO •» c o T-t •P 3 JJ iH +j CO c H CO £J> ■5 .* O O H a • • 6 o S 1 < H C) w «w >i >i •d Ja A CJ > •rl •a o •s V* -H •H <1) r-H rH •o Ol 04 en U4 fij a 3 -p CO co (3 -a CO CO o u T> TJ ■p 3) CJ CO CI w •H R) PJ a ca m +: * * (18) A-69 Eh tO H CO O u ^ u y % u ( ) o 53 u hi 53 >< o r-l M H H S M Pj r-l CO O r~ fM Pj 01 rH o O « e o M ?3 P4 ( > O HI 6 ra «^ 8 in H « to H Q o n (-> g g to •<■-« o M in 00 o •3* •-T ID CO o CO CM en CU H ro ro O 01 ro CO CO r> r- CO >1 M 9 C0 CM CM H H H rH rH r-l rH LO tO r3 ra: H o ft O r» r-l H cn C0 CD O rH CM m CM O G1 r- r^ r- r- r- r— r-l m b in CM CM rH r-l rH «H rH rH rH to to raj * * CO a H cm ro to cm CM co o (^ CD CD in M< rH o * • ft ■ « • ft • • • *?« CM o o o O o o o O o o ! B n; * £a CO r- O ro CO VO r^ r- co CO < fH CO co r> CO in m m m m CM > L0 h n> r-l o o O o o o o o O cd p M • T o H * H CO o rH CU IX) en CO r- m cn 10 Pi H ro r^ CO IO m m CD CD r- Ci ! ;-: m to CM o O o o o O o o o 1 to r-C 8 I<^ O H ^ a o r» CO CD G\ CM o\ 0i ^r CM ►-I in CD m in N* in in in r- CO «$ rs M rH O o O O o o o o rH to to *c CO O o o CO o to V «x> (0 CU M 1 CM CO o •0 t\ M' r » CD CD "nT CM CO U %i O c CM IO CU o ro O f~ in r» 1 "-' ::> rH rH CM CM CO o o Cr> •H w g to •■ « o •H 4J -H 4-» ■H +J W a H to tJl .s r^ o o 5H m • • e cx fS o W cc M C) w m >i >n T3 rQ rQ CD > 'Ci •d •H (U CJ rl •H •H CD rH rH ti (^ ft Si4 a< ta 3 3 -p to w nj tJ to to 0) o c •p -p o (tf p r d •H •5 o> •P 4J CO to to m (U CD rQ •<-» 4J r: to to o o o •H 'J u •|J :J • c c rfi a) ■rl rH o o >-l P< T1 VI CO nf CD 0.) co to ..-| to rt rfl P m M (18) A-70 to H in O u •J o Cil e: 2 H o ^ o O S3 o H is >< o -1 M H £ s ^ Cm C\l •j O M o 00 Im Pn CTi O Q) f-( r- 1 Cm H fi O PJ ^ 1 o 53 o H H cm VD H r- rH rH CO ro o CO s» vr O CO vD VD in vr vr n r~ u> i m CM H rH rH rH rH rH rH o in •H. 3 n; s H o H H o ro cn VO CO o-> m CM rH r- Bi O r~ vO in Vr Vl' vr co 00 2 M D "* KT CM CO CO O > in M H> O' cr> r» VD vD in VD VD in n cm O o O O o O O o O P4 Q P< ss H "Z. o M * H CO VO r» ro rH cn cn cn cn rH in §S in %r n co co CM CM CM CM m H D rH o o o o O o o o o m in § in fll fi. £ 8 O M ) 1 EH SO n in CM CO r^ VD CO o in 3 Pi O vr m n CM CM CM CM m vr in in wi o o o O O O o o o CO vr O o o CO o 10 CM vo CM CO 1^ vo CM o nJ rH C VO • o vr r- VD in VD en o >< H it) ►J £ w in r-~ H rH rH CM ro vr CO o • • M O 3 n i 1 1 1 1 1 i 1 cn £ o o rf! i5 ^ co U VD CM CO vr O o o CO [M M -P o m rH VD CM CO r^ VD CM u • •d • • » • • • * • CJ ! «/► G cj r- O vr r- VD in VO cb 1 —' U rH rH rH CM m vr tn •H 3 rH •H VH f4 to c o -H -P zi 4-> •H •P in c M W tn U -H r^ l) O U CQ • • R at r< O B P4 W DH >• >1 T) ^ rQ CJ > T1 T) -rH 0) CJ U -H •M (1» rH *-* •cl ft ft P4 ft nJ 3 3 ■P CO 10 (fl T1 t/> to G) t#> CJ o M o w 10 -rH r-t rt rf Q « CQ * * A-71 (19) URS Research Company, The Economic Impacts on the American Paper Industry of Pollution Control Costs (San Mateo, Cal. : URS, 1975). Purpose : To estimate the economic impacts of air and water pollution control on the paper industry. Methodology : A model was constructed of the paper industry that shows the rela- tionship between the industry's cash flow and its capital spending decisions. The model was run for the years 1975-1983 to determine the impact of pollu- tion abatement expenditures on the paper industry in terms of each of needed capacity and its inflationary potential, product shortages, job loss, mill shutdowns, smaller investment in job-creating facilities, and import- export implications . The model shows that pollution abatement expenditures are passed through in both higher costs and also lack of supply to meet the demand requirements of a growing economy. The general methodology of the model is as follows: 1. The tonnage demand for 5 or 10 years ahead is forecast. f 2. The capacity needed to meet this demand is forecast. 3. Capital needed to finance anticipated plant and equipment requirements is forecast. 4. Capital available from internal sources and from external sources is forecast. 5. The difference between capital needed and capital available is a measure of the pressure on the industry that will affect capital spending decisions. Conclusions : 1969-1974 Period $l-$2 billion of an available $4.7 billion of available funds went for pollution abatement projects. $l-$2 billion was equivalent to 4 million tons of new capacity. During this period growth of new capacity slowed from 3.8 percent per year to 2.9 percent per year. Mills produced few grades of paper during this time in order to avoid downtime caused by shifting machine from one grade to another. This effort to stretch production resulted in general shortages to consumers . A-72 (19) Forecast for 1975-1984 Period 1. If costs were to remain at 1974 levels and the industry's profit level remains at the period average: a. the industry will be short $16.7 billion to satisfy capital needs, b. it will be short $7.7 billion of anticipated pollution abatement expenditure, c. this represents a shortage of 18.2 million tons of new capacity by 1984. 2. If it is assumed that paper demand grows an average of 3.8 percent a year during this period and plants operate at 92 percent of capacity: a. there will be a shortfall of production of 21.7 million tons; consumer demand will remain unsatisfied, b. consumer demand can be satisfied if values in the marketplace rise from $436 per ton in late 1974 to $500 per ton in 1983 at constant prices. This figure is $838 per ton when inflation is included. The average household's expenditure for paper products will rise from $219 per year to $420 in 1983. c. U.S. exports will decline and imports will increase. The net change could be as much as $5.7 billion per year. This is a potential loss of 35,000 jobs to American workers during 1978-1983 even if plants produce at 96 percent capacity. 3. If environmental spending were reduced by half in the period 1975-1983, imports in the economy would be less severe: a. shortage of capacity would be 11 million tons instead of 17 million tons, b. values per ton would only have to rise to $809 per ton to provide needed capacity, c. outlays per household would be $17 less per year. A-73 (20) Van Alstyne, Carol and Sharon Coldren, The Cost of Implementing Federally Mandated Social Programs at Colleges and Universities , (Washington, D.C. : American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 1975). Purpose : To provide quantitative examples of the cost of implementing federally mandated social programs at colleges and universities and their impact on the financial condition of academic institutions. Methodology : An intensive investigation of six institutions by a small task force was undertaken, emphasizing the definition and measurement of costs, and the quality of data collected. In the analysis, a fundamental distinction was made between the total cost of an activity and the incremental cost specifically attributable to compliance with the federally mandated social programs. The federally mandated social programs included in the study were: 1. equal employment opportunity 2. equal pay 3 . affirmative action 4. age discrimination 5 . wage and hour standards 6 . unemployment compensation 7. social security tax increase 8. health maintenance organization 9. retirement benefits 10. wage and salary controls 11. occupational safety and health 12. environmental protection Constraints: Because the study was the first of its kind and it required much conceptual work at the outset, it was limited to six institutions. Also, the data showed little comparability from one institution to another. Conclusions : The cost of implementing the federally mandated social programs at these six institutions has doubled over the last 5 years considerably faster than increases in overall cost of instruction. Several of the federally mandated social programs have contributed substantially to the instability of costs at colleges and universities from year to year and thus compounded the difficulties of financial management and budget balancing. Administering these federal programs is itself costly. Over the decade, these costs have increased from a negligible share to as much as one-eighth to one-quarter of the general administrative costs of these institutions . A-74 (21) Arthur D. Little, Inc., Steel and the Environment: A Cost Impact Analysis: Report to the American Iron and Steel Institute , (Arthur D. Little, Inc., 1978). Purpose : To find projected total environmental control capital and operating costs for the years 1978-1985 for the steelmaking and steel forming operations of the steel industry. Methodology : Models were developed for production costs, capital and operating costs, and the cost impact of the proposed environmental regulations. Data were collected containing information on operating cost factors and in-place environmental control facilities. The environmental control model was revised to reflect current and projected changes in environmental regu- lation. Engineering estimates were made of capital and operating costs necessary for central systems needed to achieve compliance with current and projected regulations. The costs of environmental control were grouped through 1979 (near -term) and through 1985 (long-term) . Constraints: The models were judged to have the following accuracies: • calculated primary iron and sheetmaking costs + 5-10 percent • industry near-term environmental control costs +_ 10 percent • long-term environmental control costs +_ 20-25 percent • steel forming products costs + 10-15 percent The analysis does not include control costs for carbon monoxide, nitrogen oxides, open dust source emissions, water quality related costs, monitoring and analytic costs or Occupational Safety and Health Administration costs. Conclusions : The costs of environmental control are summarized in the following tables. (21) A-75 Table 13 DISTRIBUTION OF CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS FOR ENVIRONMENTAL CONTROL OF THE STEEL INDUSTRY OF THE UNITED STATES BY TYPE OF POLLUTION {millions of 1978$) Type Air Fugitive (process and material handling) Water (including priority pollutants) Thermal Storm Runoff Total Capital Invested in Environmental Control Facilities In-place in 1976 Total Capital Still Needed Near-Term (through 1979) Compliance Capital* (including in-place) $2,800 (46.5%) 3,220 (53.5%) $6,020 (100.0%) Long-Term (through 1985) Compliance Capital* (including near-term) $2,930 (29.8%) 1,880 (19.2%) 3,970 (40.4%) 150 (1.5%) 890 (9.1%) $9,820 (100.0%) 4,900 $4,920 'These capital costs do not include provision for control of solid waste, carbon monoxide, nitrogen oxides, open dust source emissions, or water quality, monitoring and analysis, or unusual site- specific expenditures. Table 14 STEEL INDUSTRY OPERATING COSTS ASSOCIATED WITH ACHIEVING COMPLIANCE WITH LONG-TERM ENVIRONMENTAL CONTROL REGULATIONS, BY TYPE OF POLLUTION Type Million 1976$ % Air 765 35.3 Fugitive (process and material handling) 320 14.8 Water (including priority pollutants) 440 20.3 Thermal 30 1.4 Storm Runoff 30 1.4 Solid Waste 580 26.8 Total 2165 100.0 (per year) Oper. & Maint. Capital Recovery Charges Million 1976$ % 435 29.9 280 19.2 590 40.6 20 1.4 130 8.9 0.0 1455 100.0 Total Million 1976 $ 1200 600 % 33.2 16.6 1030 28.4 50 1.4 160 4.4 580 16.0 3620 100.0 (21) A-76 Table 15 SUMMARY OF IRON AND STEEL INDUSTRY CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS (billions of 1978$) 1978-1985 Per Am num Capital Utilization Zei o Growth 2% Growth Zero Growth 2% Growth Environmental Control 4.9 8.0 0.6 1.0 Replacement 24.0 24.0 3.0 3.0 Expansion 12.2 1.5 Non-Steel Operations (not ava ilable) Working Capital (not available) 28.9 44.2 3.6 5.5 Projected Industry Cash Flow is $3.3 billion per annum Note: In addition to no allowances for capital costs for non-steel operations and working capital, this table does not include capital costs for control of solid waste, carbon monoxide, open dust source emissions, or water quality, monitoring and analysis, or unusual site-specific expenditures. Table 16 PROJECTED STEEL INDUSTRY CAPITAL COSTS OF ENVIRONMENTAL CONTROL, BY TYPE (millions of 1978$) Type Air Fugitive (process and material handling) Water (including priority pollutants) Thermal Storm Runoff Tota! 6,020 5.900 9,820 11.100 'Minimum value used in 1975 study. Stage II** on Near-Term 1976 Model Stage I** 1972 Model Long-Term 1976 Model Existing Facilities 1972 Model 2,800 2,700 2,930 2.700 — 1,880 3.200 3,220 3,200 3,970 3.800 — 150 500 — — 890 900* Compliance Stages 1975 Study Stage I Stage II Solid Waste Disposal (oswntially as practiced in 1972) x x Air (to meet 1975 primary standards) x x Air - Fugitive Emissions Water - 1977 EPA Guidelines x x Water - 1983 EPA Guidelines Thermal Pollution Control Total x x XX XX A-77 (22) Tuccillo, John, "Taxation by Regulation: The Case of Financial Intermediaries," The Bell Journal of Economics , Autumn 1977, Vol. VIII, No. 2. Purpose : To estimate the implicit tax levied by the regulatory system on the following six financial services: 1. Full service powers of commercial banks, 2. Prohibition of interest on demand deposits, 3. Differential interest rate ceilings, 4. Differential reserve requirements, 5. Access to borrowing facilities, and 6. Ability to operate as mutual organizations. The purpose is to determine the additional costs imposed on mutual savings banks and savings and loan associations because they are not regulated in the same manner as commercial banks. Regulatory Intent : Regulations on financial intermediaries usually take the form of regulations on both price for inputs and outputs and on output itself. The former type, most apparent in regulation Q ceilings on deposit interest rates and usury ceilings, is intended to produce a subsidy which has the effect of reducing the costs of funds to depository institutions. The latter type, which constrains the portfolio composition of these depository institutions, tends to allocate the flow of funds through these intermediaries to the real sectors of the economy. Methodology : The impact of regulation is estimated by translating regulatory requirements into measures of implicit taxes and subsidies. This is done by calculating the effective rates of federal taxation using a redefined economic income base. This economic income base includes a standard defini- tion of income, but is expanded to include the income effect of those aspects of regulation which act as subsidies or taxes. For example, a subsidy is granted for savings and loan associations because of lower reserve reqirements. The methodology for determining a subsidy is to calculate the difference in reserve rates by subtracting from the percentage of deposits held by banks as non-earning reserves, the ratio of cash to deposits in savings and loan associations in a particular chosen size class. This result gives the percentage of S&L deposits which would have to be transferred into non-earning assets if they were regulated as a bank. This figure has been multiplied by the savings deposits to total assets to arrive at the percent- age of assets which would have to be transferred to non-earning categories if reserve requirements were similar to those of banks. The return to the earning asset portion of portfolios is then calculated by dividing total portfolio return by the ratio of earning assets to total assets. Given this figure, we now determine the additional rate of return necessary on the portfolio to allow both this transfer to reserves to be made, and to maintain the rate of return to the portfolio by multiplying the percentage of earning assets necessarily transferred into sterile reserves by the rate of return A-78 (22) on earning assets. This can now be translated into an income effect, i.e., the extra income which would have to be generated by savings and loan asso- ciations to maintain gross portfolio income in the face of reserve require- ments equal to those of banks . The following steps are undertaken to calculate the corresponding adjustments and effective tax rates. Since this regulation generates a subsidy to S&L's because the reserve requirements are lower, it grants an increase in economic income as defined herein. This increase is added to economic income and effective rates are recalculated. Full-service powers of banks, especially the issuing of demand deposits, represent a competitive advantage in that they can attract customers through non-price means. This advantage requires higher prices on the part of thrifts for these institu- tions to remain competitive. Thrifts, thus, need to earn a higher gross income to match the net income of banks . This is a negative imputation to the economic income of thrifts in recalculating effective tax rates. Assumptions and Constraints : One, the analysis ignores all changes in relative prices generated by potential regulatory changes. This means that changes in incomes are net of any second order income changes which would be generated by changing relative prices. Income effects may be overstated. Two, financial markets are characterized by quick and efficient adjustment to regulatory constraint. If thrifts are constrained from competing with commercial banks with respect to full services, they quickly invent new liability instruments. As far as financial intermediaries can circumvent regulation, the estimates presented below are overstated. Conclusions : The result of the comparison of the differential reserve requirements on savings and loan associations with commercial banks indicates that savings and loan associations would have to generate between 6.6 percent and 8 percent more income if they were to be subject to commercial bank reserve require- ments in order to maintain the same net income. These figures vary by asset size class of the thrift institution. The effect of prohibition of services on S&L's has an income effect of between 6.5 percent and 7 percent. Given the differences in prohibition of services, reserve structure borrowing privileges and the effect of mutual form of organizations, the total impact of implicit taxes and subsidies on effective federal tax rates vary from -.4 to +.6 over the different asset size classes of these institutions. The interest prohibition on demand deposits and the borrowing privileges of commercial banks decreases the tax and subsidy value on effective federal tax rates for commercial banks in the area of approximately -1.85 percent. This latter impact, however, is offset somewhat by the ability of thrifts operating under a mutual form of organization to raise capital through deposits and retained earnings as contrasted with the banks necessity to issue equity shares. S&L's also have access to advances from the Federal Home Loan Bank system which carry lower interest rates and longer terms than do advances to banks from the Federal Reserve system. A-79 (22) The major advantage to banks under the regulatory system is their full- service powers. This advantage can be evaluated in terms of 6.5 percent to 7 percent of the income of thrifts in 1973. The major advantage for thrifts under the regulatory system is their lower reserve requirements. This advantage can be evaluated at about 6.5 percent of thrift income for 1973. A-80 IMPACT OF A SINGLE REGULATION ON THE NATIONAL ECONOMY A-81 (23) Hanke, Steve H. and Ivars Gutmanis, "Estimates of Industrial Waterborne Residuals Control Costs: A Review of Concepts, Methodology, and Empirical Results" in Peskin, Henry M. and Eugene P. Seskin, Cost Benefit Analysis and Water Pollution Policy , (Washington, D.C. : The Urban Institute, 1975). Purpose : To bring together a series of studies that have attempted to estimate the costs of industrial water pollution abatement studies that have been conducted or sponsored by the Environmental Protection Agency. Methodology : The conceptual methodology for analyzing industrial water pollution abatement was developed by researchers at Resources for the Future and includes the following objectives: To determine : 1. The factors which influence residuals generation in an industry and that industry's quantitative response to variations in those factors. 2. The range of options available to an industry to respond to increasingly stringent restraints on the discharge of residuals to the environment. 3. Models of residuals generation for different industries for use in analyzing regional residuals management. 4. The extent to which the biological, physical, technological, and economic interrelationships among the types and states of residuals require that all residuals be considered simultaneously in determing the optimal residuals management strategy for a plant. 5. The proportion of total costs represented by net residuals management costs taking all impact upon other costs into consideration. Most of the industrial waterborne residual cost estimates undertaken by government and non-government have used a cost per unit of wastewater flow methodology. The following five steps specify that methodology: 1. For each industry sector determine the volume of wastewater generated per unit of time. 2. Differentiate total wastewater volumes by size of hydraulic loadings per unit of time. 3. Determine the required residual control processes for each industry sector to achieve the desired level of control. 4. Determine cost functions for capital, and operation and maintenance expenditures, relating these to the volumes of wastewater flow per unit of time. A-82 (23) 5. Multiply the appropriate cost estimates by the corresponding wastewater volumes to determine total capital, and operating and maintenance costs for each industry sector. A comparison of several studies on how they approach this particular methodology is included in this paper. Assumptions and Constraints : The most serious shortcoming of this particular methodology is that its use is limited to estimating end-of-pipe treatment costs. No information is provided on the changes in end products or intermediate transfers. There is a paucity or outright absence of empirical cost information. Only gross costs are estimated and net residual treatment costs remain absent. This precludes meaningful analyses of public policies. Conclusions : A comparison of the cost estimates as published in The Economics of Clean Water , a report prepared in 1972 and again in 1973, by the Environmental Protection Agency, shows that capital cost estimates for water pollution control for 1977 in millions of 1971 dollars shows a 30 percent decrease in 1973 over 1972. That is, expenditures for 1972 for all industries were estimated to be $11.9 billion and for 1973 $8.3 billion. The cost functions used to calculate cost per unit flow appear to be almost identical in the 1972 and 1973 reports. The cause for the large difference in estimates results from the number of manufacturing establishments included and from the size distribution of these establishments as measured in terms of wastewater volumes. McGraw-Hill conducted a survey of pollution control expenditures by industry undertaken annually since 1967. The study was published in 1972. The study does not differentiate between expenditures for air pollution control, water pollution control and other forms of environmental protection. A more disaggregated survey was used by the Conference Board in 1971 to estimate industrial water pollution abatement expenditures. Another study published by the National Canners Association and American Food Institute uses a questionnaire survey to determine the costs of water pollution abate- ment. Cost per unit of flow methodology was used to determine the costs. In terms of aggregate treatment costs an estimate of $11 million in 1972 was made for annual costs. That estimate was expected to be $24 million (in 1972 dollars) for the year 1975. Capital costs of $58 million were expected to be $127 million (in 1972 dollars) in 1975. For irrigation costs annual expen- ditures of $13 million in 1972 were expected to increase to $20 million annually by 1975. Capital costs of $79 million in 1972 were expected to reach $122 million by 1975 (in 1972 dollars) . Municipal disposal and pre- treatment costs were expected to be $10 million annually in 1972 and increase to $24 million annually by 1975. Industry costs for in-plant abate- ment were estimated to be $6 million annually for 1972 and $16 million annually for 1975. A-83 (24) Thieblot, Armand J., Jr., The Davis-Bacon Act , Labor Relations and Policy Series Report No. 10 (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania, 1975) . Purpose : To estimate the increased costs to the federal government caused by payment of prevailing wages and fringe benefits required by the Davis-Bacon Act. Regulatory Intent : The Davis-Bacon Act requires contractors doing work for the federal government to pay their employees wage rates and fringe benefits that are no less than those prevailing in the local area. These wages are determined by the Department of Labor. Methodology : Thieblot measured the difference in bids and rebids when the Davis - Bacon Act was suspended for a little over a month in 1971. At the time of the suspension all bids received on construction projects were sent back to be rebid. Thieblot measured the difference between the lowest bid and the lowest rebid. Constraints : All the initial bids became public knowledge before rebidding, which probably influenced the rebidding decision process. There was probably a considerable amount of gamesmanship, and during the 45-day period between bids, inflation may have increased the bids by 1 to 2 percent. Conclusions : The difference between the original low bids and the low rebids was -.63 percent. For a federal government expenditure of $38 billion for construction work this would represent a savings of approximately $240 million. When corrected for inflation during the suspension period, the savings would rise to between $620 million and $1 billion. A-84 (25) National Commission on Water Quality, Staff Report to the National Commission on Water Quality (Washington, D.C. : U.S. Government Printing Office, April 1976). Purpose : To investigate and study all aspects of the economic, social, and environmental effects of achieving the Federal Water Pollution Control Act Amendments of 1972, Public Law 92-500. Regulatory Intent : To reach by July 1, 1983 a level of water quality that will provide for protection and propagation of fish, shellfish, and wildlife and will provide recreation in and on water. Also to reach by 1985 the elimination of pollutant discharge into navigable waters . Methodology : Costs were determined for two different methodologies: BAT — best available technology economically achievable. BPT — best practicable waste treatment technology over the life of the equipment. Two types of industry price impacts were calculated: Direct Price Impacts — calculations were based on a detailed static analysis of each industry market and plant-by-plant costs. Cumulative Price Impacts — calculations were based on each industry's pollution abatement costs, changes in costs of goods and services purchased due to pollution control, and indirect effects on productivity, inflation, and aggregate demand. For publicly-owned treatment works two cost scenarios were examined. The first assumed 72 percent federal funding for treatment plants and 28 percent for interceptor sewers and was based on projected EPA outlays. The second assumed funding of all needs except treatment of separate storm sewers by 1985. Macroeconomic impacts were calculated using the Wharton Econometric Forecasting Model. Conclusions : Accummulated capital and O&M costs to industry are as follows: Capital O&M BPT BAT (additional) New Sources (until 1983) $36.0 billion $23.2 billion $19.9 billion $6.8 billion $5.8 billion A-85 (25) The Commission estimated two different capital costs. Technology studies represent the cost of necessary hardware and installation, and economic studies consider the economic dynamics of the separate industries studied and their likely response to treatment requirements. These two estimates of capital costs for various industries are: Capital Costs— 1977 (billions of 1975 dollars) Technology Economic Iron & Steel Organic & Miscellaneous Chemicals Inorganic Chemicals Petroleum Refining Pulp & Paper Metal Finishing Fruits & Vegetables Plastics & Synthetics Textiles Steam Electric Power Feedlots All Other Industry $ 2.91 $ 2.08 4.29 4.29 .52 .81 1.05 .83 2.64 2.19 14.14 9.13 .44 .17 .16 .21 .54 .46 3.74 3.74 .71 .43 10.94 11.66 TOTAL $42.08 $36.00 There will be significant plant closings in Pulp & Paper, Metal Finishing, Textiles, Fruits & Vegetables, Feedlots, and Meat Packing. These will be mainly restricted to old, small, single-plant firms, many of which could not remain economically viable even without pollution control requirements. Regional impacts will be most severe in the Northeast, and to some extent, the Middle Atlantic and North Central regions. Two scenarios were examined for publicly-owned treatment works. The first was based on projected EPA outlays and the second based on the funding of all needs except control or treatment of separate sewer flows by 1985. Total federal, state, and local government capital expenditures in 1973 dollars were $60.9 billion for the first scenario and $158.1 billion for the second. When the effects of inflation are included the total federal share is estimated to be $52.3 billion for the first scenario and $184.4 billion for the second. The macroeconomic effects are: Inflation will be 9 percent above baseline projects by 1985 for an annual rate of .9 percent. Unemployment will be lower by .9 percent in 1977-80 and then much higher in 1984-85. Plant equipment investments and housing impacts will be midly negative. A-86 (25) Some benefits of water pollution control were also calculated. These are : The value of certain types of real estate near selected water bodies will increase in value by $92.5 million annually in 1985-2000. Reopening of beaches will result in new flows of economic activity estimated to be between $158-$521 million in 1985 to between $121-$701 in 2000. Commercial and recreational marine fishing will share economic gains of $3.9 billion in 1985 and $5.2 billion in 2000. Freshwater fishing will show gains of between $220-$521 million in 1985 to $217-$701 million in 2000. Boating will increase to between $498-$l,200 million in 1985, to between $528-$l,700 in 2000. Discounting by percent in 1972-85 to 4 percent in 1972-2000 results in a cumulative worth of between $33.3 and $88.1 billion. Discounting by 4 percent to infinity results in a worth of approximately $200 billion. A-87 (26) Mintz, Use, U.S. Import Quotas: Costs and Consequences , (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1973). Purpose : To estimate the economic costs of quotas on sugar and textiles. Methodology : Estimates of the sum of four costs attributable to import quotas were made. These costs are: Transfer Costs - The redistribution of income from consumers to producers . Import Costs - The difference in receipts received by importers and exporters between the quantity of goods under the quota and those receipts which would be received at the lower price without quotas. Production Costs - The costs of misallocating resources in production of goods which could be imported at a cheaper price . Consumption Costs - The cost of consumers reducing their consumption of the goods below what they would consume if there were no quotas . Constraints : Estimates of costs were based on estimated data from other studies. Relevant data for the textile industry were not avilable and thus the estimates presented are very rough. Conclusions : Costs in Millions of Dollars Sugar Import Cost $265 - $317 Production Cost $ 79 - $110 Consumption Cost $ 10 - $ 25 SUBTOTAL $354 - $451 Transfer Cost $227 - $256 TOTAL $581 - $707 Above are the estimates of the costs of import quotas on sugar. The first three costs were to total cost to the U.S. economy. Adding transfer costs to this total gives the total users costs of sugar quotas. Costs for the textile industry could not be broken out due to data limitations. Rough estimates of the total cost of textile quotas range from $600 million on cotton goods in 1970 to $1,100 million in 1976 and $1,900 million on woolen and manmade textiles in 1972 to $3,600 million in 1976. A-88 (27) Douglas, George W. and James C. Miller, Economic Regulation of Domestic Air Transport: Theory and Policy (Washington, D.C. : Brookings Institution, 1974) . Purpose : To estimate the total costs to consumers of CAB regulation of domestic trunk air carriers . Methodology : A model was developed to measure air passengers' full cost under present regulations and lowest possible cost. This was then aggregated across all travelers to estimate total costs for 1969. Constraints: The data available was excessively aggregated and certain costs may have reflected arbitrary cost allocation sales. Conclusions : During 1969 it was estimated that air passengers paid between $366 million and $538 million in excess fares. If adjustments were made for passenger purchased reduction in delay time, the total deadweight welfare loss in 1969 would have been between $248 and $356 million. A-89 (28) Keeler, Theodore, "Airline Regulation and Market Performance," The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science , (Autumn 1972) . Purpose : To determine the effects of domestic airline regulation on the fares and market efficiency of the American air transport industry. Methodology : A model to estimate long run airline costs was developed. The model is then used to predict hypothetical unregulated (cost-based) fares for 30 major domestic air travel markets. As a test the model is used to predict fares on the relatively unregulated California intrastate routes. Constraints : For pooled cross-section and time-series data, ordinary least squares will not necessarily be the most efficient possible estimates. Conclusions : The results of this study show that regulation has indeed had a strong effect on airline fares. Using data for 1965 this study finds a markup of 45-84 percent of regulated over unregulated fares. Airline executives claim that in the absence of regulation, imperfect competition would prevail, putting everyone into bankruptcy. This alledgedly happened in the 1930 's without regulation. It has been argued by some that airline regulation is basically a government-enforced cartel existing for the benefit of the regulated firms. A-90 (29) Davis, Karen, National Health Insurance (Washington, D.C. : Brookings Institution, 1975) . Purpose : To examine the distribution of benefits and costs associated with the seven major national health insurance plans embodied in proposed legislation. Methodology : This study reports the results of a 1974 study by the U.S. Department of Health, Education and Welfare entitled Estimated Health Expenditures Under Selected National Health Insurance Bills . The study summarizes the approaches and costs of the following proposed health insurance plans: 1. The American Medical Association Plan 2. The Long-Ribicoff Bill 3 . The Administration Plan 4. The American Hospital Association Plan 5. The Health Insurance Association of America Plan 6. The Kennedy-Mills Plan 7. The Health Security Act (AFL-CIO) Plan The study also summarizes the costs of no national health insurance plan. f Attached are a set of tables which set out the specifics of each of the plans as they existed in 1974. (29) A-91 Q, O Sot 3 "3 O */> 3 m ^3 -O U F. > > o CL O Z £ 3 5 y > 3 — O Q 2 r-- Eh to S* 3.2 tf» g — i 8S " 5 > > C3 U> a ? o o u Q. E <= °- § £ - J"- 3 CJ 11 o o <"> — — o CL « S-S2 ''T- o -3 C u ji r3 y) C o •- 13 E Oi « "r: >• -2J2 2 ^ ~. 3,q.--> C .£ ° 5 0> 2 J= to -* 3 _c — > 3 — £i <— C SL d allow crcdi cost of appro 'ould also rcq rablc lax tree c _3 O > O C c ,- 3 5 3 CD o "2 a 2 S ■= <- * p C CL 2 c ^ > O O « _. E .2 c c CJ — -o — . c £» r- H U l " T3 Oo CI Im (/» — rogra fTsct 1 illcd cics I to '-5 JJ D o rt CL □ u — _L U u _. .«• o c- 2 < X 3 to <2 t* CI tj ,. -C 3 £» P 3 O o C « o "5 Ci c -a £ °- c O o 3 j - --T3 O U .o — « o T3 * o^ o 2 ** u> 5 o =- = ^ . O CT3 -"a 9— u • - i« — * o >» o ^cl 3 ■9 S -j L "O .5c2 u " __ •O ">T3 o c •J «•« O « cj u <"". : - •» u h o u o ^3 c •- o 5 .^^ > C rt T3 3 « c X o 5.2 § 5 Ji-2-5 » * 5-f 21 « '-> 5 « 2 fc ™ o o ~ 2 o ..- C3 ^~ « O CL.C ■- JC u JT >. Q. o^-S ?§ £ M o a. J « t a: 2 '5. o (O -^ 3 ^ : u ^ "° l. \ s ■— x> ■— O = c (-4 3 r C C> 'Co X 5 -£ ■si O J% C3 ^ > CJ u .ij £• a CJ T) f ). U ^ r3 r3 i) "S C IL> — " ;- J3^ o o J -a a-^- E = ^9 rt "Ei5 3 ,3=£l ^: a ,« u S- •■ c"= "5. i. -= a 5? I? --O ■s e = y a o T3 > s, vj _cj O c r: oi3 * — = 3S a, a c o « a * n " cj a g •- ° u ""5 ■a 3 ■£ E~ c o -5 "^ '">" £-= ^ J, O « j; 7: "ESS >% o c '5. B£ -J - 3 :. e to •a ' 3 ^ -a p -a C — t '-> £• -^ 2 SQO^f o(>^do5 w^ ^ 8 =i °* y "^ — - CJ O > CL O c a a « s S 3 t -»- o 3 O > o 2 = 3 r3 g* -" J= U Zo ^^ "O "3 CJ ? .as -8 a LU o -a — > 3 g I- a» 3 T3 .£ S 2 § a •- > 3 o « c S E Li .— CO C ~ o P3 O ^; Q. O CL U t. „ Q i!.5 31! O T3 " 3 Z. JZ ** f3 H - T3 I „ 3 3 E '£ ii 3 ci O 5 S — jj cs o^ E o (J »- f3 *- * 3 -j t- .. ^* srt 5c 5 5 - «*• til ^ y? CO -/ -_ O -3 6 < 2- £ CC O CL (29) 2 ^T >» « 13 ,- r • *- Ji — -o £ o -5 ,o £ £ cj h c* ^o — O J3 CO £ c2 "° — "^ o ~ _ 2 y . o ~ '= i_ o T3 ur o *- e •— ut) C - -.2 r- a S ~ O O ? 2 c "o .5 S 3 T3 "8 gg-:E£- •• .£ ■2 « E CJ c C irt o _l .^ 3 CO H X! Eh (29) A-93 Si ■go.; d <-> ' J 222 5 S'5 1- > *^- £ - " re tj -, o °mE| o.c 2 u *"" -CT CO E SH o § *" O C — • 6 > -S o ' O n t - > 2 o « -* c -o CI •- •• <= M &^ = > a c to S .di c S \j t/ rt m 2 * C = * £ l! > ' — "o a •■• O ,- >\ *- -C^ »- o « c r«° .2 c_ 3 -o v — ■ •— o 2 2 £ j? i n u ■• ciy-P E U 5 re -o "3 p u « §S- ace S : i2 C ci 3 -j « s - E 3 ' y c 3 .5 C3 C 3 £ s EA«f Er g. a " 2 E ~Z « 3 t-O (U 3 Ol o 6 3 — O c >- to o ci re c .C 2 O =0 -J §^■3 22 8 S- u VI — PJ •" -^ S-E r O vi _ O SCO' EL ci 5 b Ere •£ 2 2 " v£org>.^ii3^SE Srac=s», :J !!>i2'- 5» C C ° - w fti _ff O Ti Q o.2 I t! » g_^5.E o S* 2 2 IE* a «ti*.«=Ji.oS£ E ££•-«! £ 5-3 £. E>n 2 2 2 ID a$r>>sH ■< u£ u > u s. ■a ci 2 -a c 3 E £ TJ 3 •-) _^ O tS. b a O --JJ — V CO C a s, "J LI O # o c 2 a < CO L* *i: ^ 1- re sz. _ 'to S.s u re -3 — m s -5 c re 0-H.S- 2 re .y -5 re 5 ■ S - - JT "3 ' J "§ u re vi 1= > C CJ .- ^1 — — o - — C « "> -J -1 2 * _o > •" « — <<^ o — • o -S 2. <^ ej n3 O ^ _ o ./j re S £ 5^ "" E ■ «5 3 3 — c C y .i — .5 y -j c o P (J CI c£ a. a e B o ^ - E 2 c< m-a S'.S'S a J g o f 3 CJ re c *— re a> iJ W = B co'5 £ u-o c 2^ re — •— w O VI I - -S a rt 4; Q. "O C •- .jf n- ^ ^; 3 re o c re-E &« ^^ !S c a tt o o d .; - "2 .£ 3 >» re "3 to C _. c o -2 c c 5 3 c c c y S - -5 « si I B- 2 a .S fo - 1 u S'8 rfg £ c2 u re o jc 3 re ^ u ^i= - u u 1 6 £ s-g-s-g 'IiSa|a"| re — *> >- a ,-, Q " p. -a 2 5 « i: £ § - J -S 2 Jr M . 3 3 .52 « t* = C TJ "~ o —^3 o P 3. "■ -Si c re — S- c- O re v. C ^> to . •« y-5 2 oE a e 2 r 1 « o 2 - 2 ? -J ^3 *. C 3 ^j q __ s-5.2^^- o c — o O 5 S3 11 o II = -a 5 2 2 E^ S-Sc C •— ^ — „ ^ c* c p -a *^ .0 5 "5 "fc r£ tc "S "^ >* u -. !_ -^- — r^ t_ & S" ?: -r ?>.5-£ "s o 'S'' t_ *■ P SE § re « b E to BJ'S O u C, b A ° «! re O c> ■a J; £ o c - o > v) >-i > S E |2£.§ .— C. ex c> > C£ S3 o > " > 3 CJ ^ /5 & S3 "3 W 2-2 kl ."2 E 2 3 > o a*> o ' ' i_ e u re *" o '-5 — <2 — cj re O a O 2 c — a rr E— - CI v> 0.-0 >- " -p- J-* ■% •r- .2 u o .b v. > j- 3 « o n P" * te o «; Cl r- 5" £. — '^.i! c> re c > c r) r4 r- O y "5. w a — ^ _. v- »-> v) 3 ra C" <-» _ to ^- CJ ^-- ^3 C2 £•-> "3 a ^T-2 = O 5 tb - a & -o c E . «£ ^.o o S-a r^ « "■• C ~ 3 a y 3 a 2£ H .y en -t ~ -a t O £ s o re 1- -~ CI to CJ °-sz '"6 re CJ — j-; '-> O <-> 3 « j'S I 5 j>TJ |^ -. v. E £ C < CI r: co re gS re s = CJ CJ •5.SJ o _ y a 1 si- E c E c «2 3,re y 5 ^, c ° ■E g-o" E • H cj ej 6 E-2 = —J cj o. re sz to re co — J£ re .!2 is 1* vi re a. cj 3 -a O cj coE CJ CJ 00 3 — Q._2 r ? C» C c -rj -- w ° C - o ■- 1- re -si --; O c cr: re - 5-° t- to . a t* o c c -o £ -2 g ■•= a ^ • - re J2 •/> C c -7; 3 t> o ci — to ^3 'r; cj >, cj Q. re C — ■- Q. C b ^ x' a 3 c re "" T3 i_ 3 y h y a c u -a c _ cj S c ..^ i: o. 3 vi C 2 to a = — C 3 „ U .v: _£ -o ^ v, O c • - § 3 ^ k aw •-; O .O iZ vi p- — "— o -3 CJ C t> j3 ""J , "o 3 i 2: -* Q. CO I M 2 ° C c re "3 L; C v re cj — 3 ra - _ ^ ;- r. ci .c- re _c- ^r ^; y EE V C5 - J= >> re ri £"T3 •5 _y y s» c CJ^ > ^_ re £3 S c :• e ? s a - .0 o re ■-* ^ '— - x: . b l' " J CO re a v. CI CJ E § o 3 2-i o v CJ 2-0 F ~i y ci O re -a — . o • — o.E 73 -o 3 •- "§ > CI — CI C .VI _ U Q CJ O .— C 2 S - = a co 2 u. ifl a ssc£a «_ O -3 v: J: .E <~*» - — t2 - ^3 CJ T3 3 1? g. M O E ISg-gbSg CI O C 3 -= c(j _ 3 O vi v) w -1 TO ■g c.e^S >;3 -a > re Hi SS E -C C C.-3 .> O 1 3 2-0 g s so: 2 .^ ximum visions cr emp amoun ording or fam a O y — ci — >-^ iv) _, .5 — > <- c E ^ ^- E ^ O re 2 5 — « "- 1 c 3 — ^ CJ 2 CJ sz. c i_ re CJ JZ. — " T3 ^ > — i£* JO t- p 1— :* rJ -ffl ^ ~3 O 3 /! n c TJ >: '-> 'ir '-» CJ 3 CO o ?; - c U o a. U . — Cl XJ 2 t> j!J -p co -* c 2) -3 00 o co c u- y « rt "— -1 CJ H S^S o u S S g." _ S t» c "■ • n 5 ° t> u o."o "5.* -3 2 -2 o 5 y il E - E E tj. L - m E "5. 3 3 .2 " o >> 2 .S jo S o 2 =* p 9 5 •- >n P E -1 > 2 « .O -a °- =: 3 n t- c c <« o W y O , 3 cL2£ c J cs e " • -- £ 8 !£ l-o ° O rj C "O 1 ao c ! c -j > 3 • o "• o a : « tS<"g E _ — TO c Cl -j ; ■° C cO * o o « j; — > — O ' 5 J a u 5 o h cl- • c.h -a ' . c «/> c — Cl Cl ci o E> O u •2"— •a 2 T> -P U> ■3 .„• -9 '5 > £? 5 E « "3 co u 2 So 3 00^ c o o t> .2 orS a E o ° °- 5 2 ,_ a P ci "» VI O ^ -j: rj °TP § P a D; .2 2 w *> w U T3 i: P 83 SI 5: o^ 8 :;5u •2 §5 ° ^5 5; 5 c u E £ Si! 8 .§aS! ci o o o a. o 5 8l — (_> > C to C T3 u rt ra -= D C -.Co ■^5 "a o rt S 5. «1 " o : — ° — 1 J3 "O P 2 > a f o 2.S-.S S 3 o c "a igJ"§ B 3 — O •5 CO t9 ■5-2^^ "5 •- -o x a C-8.-P f^ c «-> rt <<0 .P u. U o L* O d u c p •— c — o P a •czi -o CO- o ■? -O 2 2. O P (i u cr-* u ore •- j» to — E u t cr E o-p: o c ^ a u to o _. «j'8 - ?E i2"° o a *n c v> O. a '5 1 2 •S 2 5 o ■?: % o 5 ■a I" D. T3 ^ C _T £■2 "5 « 1jI,2 o ;5 *□ 2 o. 3 fc a e* 5; B f « a- 55 *- 3 W m C7 o£ = ° J< in n .-j — o "~ P iisi -* 3 TD » u. <^ L^ > T i^ O ^ Q o a a CO c E 3 5= o W3 o c3 zs 3 s s a u. < *5 o s E < rt fc* s >. CJ ■ • O to Ti JZ 60 "5. 2 T) h CI tl > C3 3 u. a Cl c tl ■0 CI to J= Cl r tu CI JS F > c ro 3 n CI tl -C ej >^ m >» t* a > r3 jr V9 o.-a J-> r: n T3 CJ fc f- > -a l_ w a. to 11 Cl •a r: 3 -a c eg C O rt * > O •1 irt 10 Cl to E 3 rt a u O a J > ■d 3 c X to fc X3 *"• tr» U C to r3 -a O U. CJJ C "1 TJ r3 C5, n C a id O a* Cl a O O n. C3 O U CJ ft <* 5 Ci-£ " > tri "St, T3 to C t> C3 — 5 E S S | b s c: S 8.a£s U 3-*= W»1T3 " ^ <2 E -rM w J- — O -3 Ss.5 ci c >- y Q. to 3 O. 1/3 tn r; c o 2:=o rs| T3 a- > 2 3 c — ." m cl cl •— CO cl TJ I £■£.= «> rt CO "5 u Si O JC - " c OT >. "2 " ~ " "° o >, " • '^ u 3 c S -o .. " 3 i'T) NT > "1 tl c ^ " C u ^<^ S?.= ^ E cc = 5 o.^: o co -?j f^ 1 1 - u ci est;" "-S.S 5.5 ** o j: o N c r ui y Cl >N t> 5 o •o E .3 S uu o ex 80 2 S CO n3 O U D. J3 TO - - to 8.5 § £ £ o C 5 -= * «* S 1; § S * £t * £ c I § S a si ; 2 e x * ^ s u « >,*• t. Q R tj TO Cl I- Cl •2 -^ ? -i y .9 o > S; 5 " Cl tOP ^3 3 -o — y Cl c o > °-£ S Cl 3 a o c ^ co .2 v .y 1/1 > .E op S °- CO JO c to r >» o > >-sg §2 .. J3 3 J= 5 o - i-TJ 5 X On -o -g tl J CO > — O D. - tl JZ ..■=:><— - H 3 •-■-s>> rt 2R'~- L 'i3 5 c c ° " c o2 iTI C Ulc 5 S H n-'E-o -£ ?.2 u| ? -a "-S O h= "P 3 «j o 3 c 3^1141 s t ? :~o CJ o c _ Sj226 S'E So y 2 C CO — UKoS 2 ci o 3 C Q. ? 2 o 5 3 3 w tfl 91 p £•- »> u — 1 c E2|o E 2 o " O LJ- JT en -p'-S ^ «ss Oct* £ o a .2 r" t> ci o n 2,u > ^^ u. t. O Q. o — >."2 =? x> c .2 '■a «"S 2 S ° pc -■= K.2-5 3 c < CO £ '5 > CO "a g E o J3 I 2 £ .2 "a a-. ■5^23 « 5 y 5 c-U< £ 3<5 Q. c c: o o ■3-^0 DC b d. (29) A-95 — . rj lO ~ r) t-t <- ~- o o-.r: — -a ■fl _o c rj c ucr ,_ . »-. 2 8. . -V) iz: CJ U O 1.2 O c CJ *— n >N h ^ ' o 11 E CJ CU> CJ a. CI fc P 1 ) u CJ Z c: 6 ^ .r .^ a a. i o TJ o C7\ C3 ■a O J> > » cj is J3 .b CJ Q, CJ O a. F O F ■a cj CO C o cj > CJ o *F TJ a. -a cj cj n CJ h •■• > -o cj J3 JS o (j to c 3 o o Q. E cj l- cj T) — cz Tj U ^ Q. F to CJ CJ >» O > J b O T3 CJ -a c D b o cr a F~ (A *s "5 > CJ c: F CJ jc O E n _> u. CJ ♦^ m — Cl — o e c-o5 3 i: F y n o -5 ^ = c i if ■rt cj """ c ■a c o E u ^ p\~ £ s fc ~ o ri p c-S-H £ o ^.o o « -o — *- , i cj 3 2-':2<£ E ? Z 2-2-3 E 35 £! "° c q.'> o 13 o 8i5 2 -"3-8 Eo a" o _ — c -o .2 cj o _ p 3 C o u u ° ^ "O *" "C» C. wi — a» S? c 2 > UJ jj TJ X CJ JZ o o o lb' t/> CJ n — C-0 TJ - a ° > t o * E > u *- 3 u « ra « O = si 2> C T3 CJ o a 'C O S c -a2cl 5§ S '5. § o j£ a: = a o ->. CJ 3 >- CO o co 5 ^ "2 <3 i> CJ 5; c. C > — -~ n c> o-c ?. 3 CJ ^J f> CJ O t- tj O T3 y1 (J CJ o n cj -J o . Q. — 5 2 CJ CJ O JJ r C C! n a fc cj ca O ,° ^CJ o .^ rj T3 ^1 , . "*^ li CJ c; Eg ( 1. CO g CJ '3 CJ 3 E o to c; h S^ c C3 c-J O CJ T3 , 5 CJ n .o « o CO & c o T3 CJ (J CO vl i/; Tl T3 "5 .b C Li CJ o o c CJ SI CJ CJ > > O o c Cj ^ i5 a o CJ CJ Jo c2 =^0 c 2 "5 o 2 h - ~ c o c cc; CJ 5; c2 C > o O US CJ c> C ^ a s ex ^r- ^ O *i c o •5, ^ CJ CJ — to C3 a; c-S o =: CJJ 3 5 a CJ a ji •5 *0 -S.-H S S s S WD." C cj E c CJ CJ CO £2 -a cj p 2 - cC o o Q 2 CM 0) rH (TJ Eh (29) A-96 S» .2 a. rj <- « "3 S.o E^T 2 - S Q.O^ § - J 2gisg§ «— c j; u « c> O ra <_. o Cl i WOra Gc o "— ■ ft o 0£ g o c. « "O « !i C O ci c> e.y «. "S &S E-S 5< , O C g Cl "1 U « u. u < E " c - e I: r b w § — > C Ci »» W ° " = i: o I O," it ' So s : <_ o £ > o .2 : «*!=•- » S * *3 = g > 3 to o o Jo. E g -. ° 5. v- u a « c •> o ° I C. O kj o - ,:» -*• L. « y ■~ U U CS E ° w cj < — • 3 .-_> o« J CO KJ .y n ■a . Cl c/» o ci o "3 r3 C E ^ •z.o ■n -o i_ cl o£ ■B-S I S c a Jg El CI •-/I CI O U u. — — 3 a a t/, c m c "^ S Eg- -; ~ ci S"r ■ ° ci -c ~Zz ci Ci C 3 >, -j C E P c ^ ^ t ) a co u ^ o o^ _ CI CI — "^ ."2 tll"j'> c -S o ■3 o o. o ui : u -n U ■gga -a c S ^ E- - o 5" I .§ i 3 ; >lrt U < w io x; 5 C c o — p ,2o a gS ^ a. « E « u|£ E 2 ui -b; o o o. •a . a e | S e | .= 2 a y > oS -o o > ^ CM CN H X! CC in 5 "> J2 2 »• s a 2 u u c S «tn « ° « t» t> .y oj? o — "*—u Pt2 t; y | § 1 5 a 1 § i -g 5. s's 3 h"S« Eh= £Ec3 o o ^ n — ra o .. > 7i — J2 CI J3 c Cl 13 i t b "> c _ a ta mug, ^ V |!"S c "> •» V" *» 1 o — CO c = c a * O.S--6 Jj2 f? O. * = .O "O c •- o a £! •- 5! «' W Cl X) - .y ^> „ o o >7'"£ C ''C: < jT3rr t _ -^12 3 E -5 !;S= o . 3 5 j= c = s; y a-o c i; c p o. ci «j i» ra k) ii ' « "- ci V.A, -a jc - C ° « o . " o -^ J2 7 • '5 E a '— £ cr° u " o c — -S js "3 O r3 Cl « o 7 — O a S ; -> r c E c c a. T3 > _o 1- a C3 a -y r; -o — Ct! " Cl - C ci — ci p co ^. xi -a <2 ttS 5^ 11 to tt - 5 E 5 2 _ Cl co<— O JJ 7 o c c -n 3 B ? n - ; n o ^ •« o - 7 «— E to E D &'° ° -" C O •• u s « 3 3 ^.12 y t; -fs g - 8 § S-5 Z *.<=£: l» Jw£ =1 E c 5 -S "3 •« 5 .£ "o « E — . "5 r, O ii < C- E- U^ E-2 A-97 (29) 3 £ < 5 a. C Eh U c _ .2 o — o 3 "3 o ^ .y o to — > ™ 2-o lie* ■a *~ s» a y •-» s-° u -a 5 > U =? o O £ 5 w — « u J; a y 2 - j > -5 ^"^ ■ — ■*» .- 3 ^00 2 -j y " U O — ? u a .i; o - •- £ > rz -O to e t» 5 o E 2 = -O o to coo t» c — — M i» one £3 c rt 'Ec2 « C 3 u rj o C . CO rs — — £*-£ C > .2-5 «_ c O a E y § C =3 >2'5 — Sou a p s ■■:. c U I "3 > y .= E >».b -= o n cr " c o.y t: =^ o-a~3 «» o -• .y — ~ 5 "3 .N O -o = a -a S 5 > 3 o 2 o ~= "a . c — n 5 g ■= £"2 u o c -"= - rt e o c5 ° .S 2 u'5 o 2r 6 - u O i/i o £; §-o °- -O "_ 3 C ~J o u - o * S c 3s ' rj II 2 = "''' o ;*s a., y ^ - ~ .y ^ U o, O C « — . 'J <0 — 3 i •S E S 9. s'^ h 3 & S <: r- a. -is II i j| y c-s P c vT u 2 c o o o 11 - O C ^ v) -■n O i» S: u» A-98 (29) • 13 2 " a % -2"~: Cl -D C o ^ CB Q L « 3 £2 S 2 £ * 2 2, ° "--' P. CO > 5 13 b- V) ° 2 S-S-o *- c n "Z, 3 t" — 2 p o W -S .Sao; £ «.§ " «— -- *r s? ' o c J. £i tn " ■■• CI -S ° 53 x o ■- - o ■ -c " •- >> 3 -o^ ci 3 3 — _> -c <— XI ~ ci — .. Cl t- V C 3 5 » Cl T3 H c> E "± -5 o " >» s .-. 3 rt R o *E ~> a c i_ P ci rj ci *e.o-z CI CI o ,vl cj) a. o 8.S II CO a o > •^ ci <_ •~ £ — ? H " rt T3- u o ^: — -C P = H __ c a u O ci o -° - & "R "° 10 ^> C^ 'J e- 8 = X) -5 C "g c. O o - c ©£■"" X> — c * g "5 5 g.2 = o o _ Q i- « C o " u H £ -z\ o. c ai ; n ■i -S-5 ■S « -o -S -5 2 EM £S 'g " g 2 I CO — ci p 2 ci a g «~ "tr JD~ F k o o £ 2js«- 5 -5 2 ^ . 3 T3 o c> _ i'^-o 55 ^ £f C g S 3 3 S2 p .a " s p S a a B 5? s C m> ~s •— eo ° S. °- P ? <-> C O o-<_ i S,3 — > >■ O u «f ^ o ^- •= o u c o c U g c E J E- -■S I -a g -o s - «* ™ c. £ _jn o — § S O § E c " r u.E , „ a 5 " 3 s l. « c 2 — •- 5; 10 o £4 — o 5 c j- o o O _ 2 n gSScfggs u 0.-0 « — c 2 « :gg H ^ 5 "2 2 •- Irt 3 _J £ c H w o c Co ° c O •— r- O »rt >v. — L. ■^ JZ « cl § a « cl tr to JZ j;.E 5 S •5 r-° o ». 2. j; c 1 g S - s - y c <2 5>o .0 -a c. E-— u 5 o > ct 5.55 S Si > 3 — o CI v) Q 2 00 Eh O D j w w 3 = Si C3 CJ> -35 I £ :§"£- p r3 >3 ci y O -s 2. — 1 ii =oc" — r3 2-c a. a II CO g bz ci •" C. > CI < CO c = *ci ci a O 'C O 1 o^ ' -c 1^ = cvj a ■- 7C « ci •;; u — u O y?" •, 8 4 c .i! CI o co-— U Q. = c ° c-2 5 »- O .. cut g g"5 V) C c .2 Sf s ° 5 o 5 .. CI ci c CI ZZ 11 — 2'c 6| «-g c| «.2 > O CI CI O CI CI ^; '2 > - C ^ ? -J. 55 Sua >. — JZ „ EgSs^f, := -^ >. p o 1 Z-5 CI _^ CI "3 S 1 ci II E -3 o c c id 5"a« ^: >. ci = cue 5"2*ci £ 5 & j- « •- b ■£ y ">•:: — fe u ° ■5 E-g 02 S — o c "so 5*5 a o « S- co ■« n o •s ^ " .. zz to w — c 1*1 i& o F. o co £ y o r o "8 «3 •6*3 E o "i *i « £ to -it co -. — 5» O «^ O te S .0-3 a. 5 a = »~ .,!»!( a 3 — ^ Ct ,C| L. w |5§6 c Q. C »« S g g .2 "> 2 rt tl CO D- a a. t_ ^-> . ■ -O n T3 *ci o £ E P si •2 c "O ' ~ 5 ci n E §•? > o >— ■a 5 co ^ P L. 5 s .O b r> o „• 2 3 £ 2-v2 e tir - -= Co 2 C •-' f ■s§ S 1 ". t_ »n CI CI -O Cl §2 » 2- ■ b E x O C *- - s " < k. CX 5SE — 5 5 a a "> • H o = o c.2 ^"52 c E: *"-> rr *- t» Cl _J «_ > . 1- o S -5 I tS g £! c-2— J3 I O O o g ci j. o . c i >- a ,b ci coS* a. S|3* o -2 «• i >. £-- " c 2uj „ E . Cl 3 «; = O ci ^1 _r -=••2:2 2 S.o 2 — « « 3 ^ SO 5" 3 CO — _o ci .2 o^ i, ^o"S ■J-. — o "g ii *: k 3 £ — >" -3i a i_ 2 .y o ? ■o •=> o ci 3 k« E c. S2 ra ~ O ^3 — T3 ■3 rs CJ Cl ci s a c - n ■3 - 2 3 >»?. .. ^ 11 .£. = 3 a a II O ci '• "5 2. ci ".2 Si o 5 - bj E 1 K y =, 2-!= 3 S'y y o c3 to s .= w-; c £?jcc o a- . c Cl 1 .« *- . ci -o ■•3 .a . 3 > or 2 j?2 > 2 o 2 c. > . o Cl c. Cl t, > y g o *— o i; c» n Q T3 cl ■o -X o g c"> A-99 (29) Assumptions and Constraints : One basic assumption underlying the HEW cost estimates is that the elasticity of demand for medical serivces with respect to the co-insurance rate is equal to -.2. A more serious qualification is that the HEW studies assume that the price controls of Phase IV of the 1971 to 1974 Economic Stabilization Program are in effect regardless of the provisions of a bill for controls on prices. This means that proposals whose cost controls are not as strong as those of Phase IV are shown to be relatively less expensive than would actually be. One aspect of cost that is not thoroughly treated by the HEW study is the indirect cost of national health insurance resulting from current tax provisions. The study does not attempt to estimate additional tax revenues that would be foregone through greater deductions and subsidies under current tax law. The HEW study did not indicate the methodology used to estimate the number of people who would be covered under any of the plans. Nor does the study indicate what assumptions were made to estimate the extent of supplementary private insurance coverage . Conclusions : Below are listed a number of tables which show federal, state and private expenditures for alternative national health insurance plans based on populations and prices projected in 1975. A comparison of each of the sponsored plans with no national health insurance plan is included. In addition, one table shows federal tax subsidies under alternative national health insurance plans for 1975. A third table shows the increases in federal costs under alternative national health insurance plans by source of increase in 1975. A fourth table shows the employer contributions and subsidies, enrollment and premiums for alternative national health insurance plans in 1975. (29) A-100 3 c V- o 3 --3 c o 55 -□»-<• — to C-, 23 ^ g fc G c ^5; 5 *3 c <2 ■S ^ S S; = ^- K' O O — r-J o> O CI r-l v~> >o r- «*> o o o o o — —I co •>* O vo r~ O O »ON>0 O (N OO io fl o Nn o m ov N r- C- O C\ "3- VO "icon OO J r*j o r~ co o - O — CNl ■O OO «N| n co to OO CO o I cc o — I — — «-> r- o ~* ° n a c-vo Q to _- jc«23 o ^ *5 ^ = '-3 g. 3 — c k" 3 O X c ^ o<-^ . . in ■ a D £ - « C n u - as > ^> - < F C "-3 t (29) A101 o. ^ LQ *» s --. *-*» -~- "C 7- O u ^ *-> ■ ■ij G X H it: to 5 <3 -S ^ i; «--. ^ X 5^ -2 — it 5: w y. rt H n to u. O r: -a o o U •a <— LD o CM o CD "~rz fH m X3 CQ tfl &H £ -2 oo o -s "a S x ~ — c Si ■5. p a E W o c to _tg ^ 2 T3 -Coo -C ■- > Q H (29) A-102 a z c 2 fN 0) = d 5 1-0 ?i o -. cm r~ O rM O «*» I v-i o C3 00 > c O. Z o ■J ~/n «• *~ o c 3 o u HI O — mm. > o ^ o n oJ c c r; 'J J-g — T o J J Urn n o 3 o to 00 c: O C O |_ r: o 2 c/l — o c3 3 H 3 _ -a O "o > ~ o - "r5 ££ O ^J '_* o cr J Z 21 z h (29) A-103 u w ~5 8 Q ^ V» . c o U E fcj CN -H ra En ~ 5 o *■ •a - 5— o a a c y o ^ E58 -2"5 c ^ — a = t) *. 3 .^ £ 3 2~ E *•= o o r- — *o o v=> — O 1 5 . . ■=.£-» ■ U M X E C™ S'S ° " i. 2 E c o s e- •-> = .2 =S S --•£ S E c.= .5 2 o "° o o w «* C i_ ~ ! 2 <-"33o o v 3 c t. * E o a S o ° n E C • T) 3 ; C £ " ^' « 5 c g a o . . JO " 3 Si . ~ • « f • w 2 E c£ o o • § = 8 ». S..S S "g 8 « 2 £■ > *5 ~ "5 2 - »So ° ° « ™ Q..-S ^ u-, £ fc o u £ 3 . £3a T3 " |J W -P ."5 § -g .£ o » ° "5 .*. ~, ■" i^ c- »- 3 c 3 o o -a 3 rs „ 5 c •> ^ e s. « 5 s | e O. - rS o D. c c^ o S o * c 2 J3 > D.T3 C . 2 S j= E c <— c >> o i. c — ,o c ^ o .5; II 1.2 3 3 o, a. a. UJ A-104 (30) Peltzman, Sam, Regulation of Pharmaceutical Innovation: The 1962 Amendments , (Washington, D.C. : American Enterprise Institute, 1974) . Purpose : To estimate the net benefits produced by the 1962 amendments to the Food, Drug, and Cosmetic Act — the amendments that instituted the efficacy requirement. Regulatory Intent : The 1962 amendments to the Food, Drug, and Cosmetic Act require the manufacturer to prove to the Food and Drug Administration that a drug has the curative powers the manufacturer claims for it. Methodology : The study begins by determining how many potential new drugs were not developed and marketed past 1962 because of the amendments. Then a consumer surplus approach is used to estimate net benefits of the amendments by assuming that the amendments eliminate exaggerated demand for a drug. The true demand curve is established when the drug is brought to market. The net benefit to consumers is equal to the consumers surplus received by consumers for purchasing the appropriate quantity given the true demand curve. If the exaggerated demand is indeed the true demand, the costs to consumers is equal to the consumers surplus given the exaggerated (but true) demand minus the consumers surplus from the amendment-restricted demand. Assumptions : A number of assumptions, favorable to the 1962 amendments, were made: 1. Unsafe drugs are kept off the market post-1962 amendments but were not kept off the market prior to the amendments. 2. An additional 2 years of delay in marketing is caused by the amend- ments although in reality this delay may be as long as 6 years. 3. The amendments have no impact on prices. Constraints : 1. In determining the value of drug safety, it is necessary to place a value on human life . 2. There is no expert agreement on whether the fraction of post-1962 drugs deemed ineffective is different than the pre-1962 fraction. 3. Separation of data into therapeutic categories may not be precise. Conclusions : 1. The number of new chemical entities making the market post-1962 amendments is reduced by more than one-half. 2 . The cost of developing and bringing a new drug to market has doubled because of the amendments . A-105 (30) 3 . The amendments have had little effect on removing inefficacious drugs from the market because the pre-1962 market was sufficiently well- disciplined to impose penalties on the producer of an inefficacious drug to warrant its removel from the market. 4. Because fewer drugs are brought to the market post-1962, drug prices are higher than they would be without the amendments . The reduced price competition impairs a $50 million cost on the sick. 5. The amendments have probably kept safe drugs off the market or caused sufficient delays in marketing to have caused real costs to the sick. 6 . The lower post-1962 demand for new drugs resolves into reduced net benefits to drug consumers of $300-$400 million annually from a reduced flow of new drugs and information about them. 7. An additional $15 million can be attributed to the FDA implemen- tation of the amendments. A-106 (31) Clawson, Marion, The Economics of National Forest Management (Washing- ton, D.C. : Resources for the Future, June 1976). Purpose : To explore the current management of the national forests, attempting to value their output in economic terms. Further, to consider all costs of national forest management, emphasizing capital costs, the greater part of national forest costs. Regulatory Intent : In 1871, Congress enacted the Forest Reserve Act to prevent the relatively rapid harvesting of virgin forests in this country. Until 1897, there was little or no management of these withdrawn lands and no legal authority for use in any way. In 1897, Congress provided authority for the use and management of national forests in legislation which is still basic today. In 1911, the Weeks Act provided for the purchase of private lands to establish and to extend national forests. In the 1930 's land was purchased under the Submarginal Lands Program and the administration of these lands has recently been placed in the hands of the U.S. Forest Service. Methodology : A comparison of the commercial forest land in national forests and forest industry forests is made. Expenditures per acre ,are compared between the forest industry forests and commercial forest which are national, to determine whether more money is spent per acre to manage the national forests. The following four major kinds of information are investigated. 1. The physical relation of output of every kind to different amounts of each kind of input for major site classes on each national forest under different forest management plans. 2 . The degree to which one level of use or activity for one output of a forest interferes with or is compatible with a given level or use or activity for another kind. 3 . Shadow prices for an economic evaluation of services and commodi- ties not generally sold for cash for locations with significant differences in value. 4. A capital account for national forests based upon reasonable estimates of the present worth of the timberland and improvements, and upon reasonable annual charges for the use of this capital. Assumptions and Constraints : Economics has, up until now, not been the basis for the allocation of available appropriations among regions or forests or specific localities within forests. Nor has it been the basis for decisions on forest function or management practices. It is important to value the output of national forests as the market would, and not at prices far below their present market values. A-107 (31) Conclusions : A combined estimate of the components of value shows that the present value of the national forests is approximately $42 billion. Cash income from the national forests in FY 1973-74 was almost $500 million and over 94 percent of this was from timber sales . The national forests incur a deficit of nearly $2 billion annually or about $9 per capita for the entire population. This represents the interest charge on the investment for national forest management. The present timber inventory in national forests is economically excessive. These forests still contain so much old timber and very large volumes per acre of valuable timber on which the annual growth is low, zero or even negative. The capital tied up in timber stands in national forests is excessive by about $12 billion. At a 5 percent interest rate, the excess annual cost is $600 million and may be even higher at current interest rates, That is equivalent to $3 per person for the entire United States. The total per acre appropriations for national forests investment and management in FY 1972 resulted in a figure of $6.53 per acre of commercial forest. The average expenditure per acre for a large forest industry firm averaged $5.06 per acre. These figures suggest that the Forest Service is spending somewhat more per acre of commercial forest and forest management than are the larger private firms. However, these figures are not wholly comparable for the following reasons: 1. The national forest figures include expenditures on all land within the National Forest System, whereas only half of the acreage of national forests is commercial forest. 2. The national forests figures include more expenditures for recreation, wildlife, watershed management and other non-timber purposes than do the forest industry figures. 3. The national forests figures include considerable expenditures for range management, whereas, the forest industry figures do not. 4. The national forests figures include more nearly all the costs for fire protection, insect control and disease control than do the forest industry figures. 5. The national forests figures include about $.50 per acre for property acquisition, whereas, the forest industry figures include nothing for this. 6. The national forests figures include considerable outlays necessary for timber sales preparation including advertising. 7. In addition to the above private forest adjustments, an adjustment must be made for the fact that the national forests figures do not include any payments out of revenue to the counties, whereas, the forest industry figures include a substantial amount for taxes. A-108 (31) The analysis leads to the conclusion that the general level of timber management expenditures on national forests is not too high and may well be too low. The real criticisms of national forests management is that the money is spent in the wrong places and for the wrong activities. If the timber inventory were reduced to the economically rational point, if timber management were banned on low production sites, and if major economies were achieved by simplified management, savings of $700 to $1,000 million might be achievable annually. At the same time, cash income could be doubled or more. A-109 (32) Smith, James S., "The Equal Credit Opportunity Act of 1974: A Cost- Benefit Analysis," paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Finance Association (September 1976) cited in Weidenbaum, Murray L. and Robert DeFina, The Cost of Federal Regulation of Economic Activity , Reprint No. 88 (Washington, D.C. : American Enterprise Institute, 1978). Purpose : To estimate the costs of compliance with the Equal Credit Opportunity Act. Methodology : Smith identified and estimated seven nonrecurring costs and three main recurring costs. The nonrecurring costs were legal fees, training costs, costs of destroying obsolete forms, computer reprogramming , costs of addi- tional storage space, printing and mailing of "Credit History for Married Persons," and conversions of the creditors systems to use two names on their files. The recurring costs were the costs on longer computer runs, costs of buying additional credit reports, and costs to credit-reporting agencies due to increased requirements for data processing and customers service . Conclusions : Smith estimated the total annual nonrecurring costs at $174.8 million and the total annual recurring costs of $118 million. A-110 (33) Kwoka, John E. Jr., "Pricing Under Federal Milk Market Regulation," Economic Inquiry (July 1977) . Purpose : To examine the purpose served and quantitative impact of price-setting procedures under federal marketing orders = Regulatory Intent : The Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 provides for the establishment of federal marketing orders. These orders set prices at certain locations that must be paid for fresh milk and manufacturing milk. There are now over 50 orders covering 80 percent of all fluid-eligible milk. Methodology : Estimates were made using a simultaneous equation system with the following variables for 1960 and 1970: Quantity of fluid-eligible milk supplied per producer by market area. Derived demand by handlers for milk for fluid use at retail, per capita. Retail price of fluid milk. The model was used to estimate the prices and quantities of fluid and manufacturing milk if there were no regulations. The efficiency loss in the regulated milk market and redistribution of income were then estimated. Constraints : Estimates were derived from a sample of markets that accounted for 40.6 percent of all markets in 1960 and 51 percent in 1970. The estimates were then increased by a factor to approximate all regulated milk sales. Conclusion : Redistribution of income from consumer to producer was estimated to be $300.1 million in 1960, rising to $750.2 million in 1970. Efficiency or deadweight loss was estimated to be $55.2 million in 1960, rising to $179 million in 1970. A-lll (34) MacAvoy, Paul W. , ed., Federal Milk Marketing Orders and Price Supports (Washington, D.C. : American Enterprise Institute, 1977). Purpose : To estimate the total deadweight social loss and transfer payments of Federal Milk Marketing Regulations . Regulatory Intent : The Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 provides for the establishment of federal marketing orders. These orders set prices at certain locations that must be paid for fresh milk and manufacturing milk. There are now over 50 orders covering 80 percent of all fluid-eligible milk. Methodology : This section of the book reports on two unpublished papers: Richard Ippolito and Robert T. Mason ("The Social Costs of Federal Regula- tion of Milk," January, 1976), and John E. Kwoka ("Pricing Under Federal Milk Market Regulation: Theory, Objectives, and Impact," 1975). Richard Ippolito and Robert T. Mason aggregated all federal order markets into a model containing one model federal order market. Kwoka estimated social costs in individual order markets and then aggregated his estimates . Details of methodology were not included in the MacAvoy book. Constraints : The model used by Ippolito and Mason aggregates individual federal order markets into one federal order market, aggregates supply and demand of milk on an annual basis, even though supply fluctuates through the year, and aggregates grade A and grade B milk. They believe these simplifications have a downward bias on the model. Conclusions: Ippolito and Mason estimate that in 1973 the total deadweight loss to the economy ranges from $125-$245 million and total transfer payments equal $250-$500 million. Kwoka estimates the total deadweight loss for 1970 to be $202 million and gross transfer payments of $805. A-112 (35) Heien, Dale, "The Cost of the U.S. Dairy Price Support Program: 1949- 1974," The Review of Economics and Statistics , Vol. LIX, February 1977, No. 1. Purpose : The purpose of this study is to estimate, in addition to the direct costs of the U.S. dairy price support program, the cost to consumers due to increased prices of dairy products. Regulatory Intent : The Agricultural Act of 1949 provided for the support of income to dairy farmers through the purchase of various dairy products . The purchases were made by the Commodity Credit Corporation, and consisted of quantities of butter, Cheddar cheese, and nonfat dry milk. The Act required the Secretary of Agri- culture to support prices between 75 and 90 percent of parity. This require- ment was in effect in the period from 1950 to 1973 when it was raised to 80 percent. In addition, Congress has also financed in part the National School Lunch Program, the Special Milk Program, and more recently the Food Stamp Program. Methodology : The methodology employed is to specify and estimate an econometric model of the U.S. dairy sector. The model is then used to measure the impacts on consumer prices over the period of 1949 to 1973 of the price support system and federal order system. These retail price changes were then used as a cost-of- living index to measure the costs to consumers of these programs. The model of the U.S. dairy industry may be divided into three sectors\j retail demand equa- tions, retail price formation relations, and farm output and price determination relations. The model was estimated over the period 1950 to 1969. The years 1970 to 1974 were used for prediction interval tests to validate the model. Assumptions : One assumption made in the study is that the Consumer Price Index can be used as a true cost-of-living index, enabling the computation of welfare lost due to higher dairy prices in dollar terms. Another assumption made was that in order to measure the impact of the Federal Milk Marketing Order System, the premium or differential for fluid market milk was set equal to zero for each year from 1949 to 1973. This is a somewhat extreme assumption since some small differential would presumably remain in order to cover the costs of meeting the more stringent sanitary conditions. Constraints : The study ignores factors such as administrative costs and the effects of reconstituted milk on the market, etc. In addition, there is no attempt made to estimate the costs to consumers of dairy import quotas . Conclusions : The direct costs estimated outside of this particular study of the CCC Dairy Price Support Program has been $7,048 billion over the period 1949-1974. This study shows that the additional loss to consumers over this period is $3,405 billion so that the total cost of the program over the 26 years of its existence is $10,453 billion or an average of $402 million per year. In mea- suring the impact of the Federal Milk Marketing Order System, where the premium for fluid market milk was set equal to zero, the resulting costs were $4,558 billion over the entire period, an average of $175 million per year. A-113 (36) Boyer, Kenneth D., "Minimum Rate Regulation: Modal Split Sensitivities and the Railroad Problem." The Journal of Political Economy ; Vol. 85, No. 3, 1977. Purpose : To test the hypothesis that the diversion of traffic from railroads to motor carriers has not been the result of minimum rate regulation. Regulatory Intent : The traditional view of the role of ICC minimum rate regulation is that it maintains that the traffic diversion to highway carriers from rails was the result of cream skimming due to ICC enforced maintenace of value-of- service pricing, and is based on the assumption that the service differential is small relative to rates. Methodology : The traditional comparative cost approach to estimating the economic loss due to traffic misallocation is overestimated by a factor of twenty. This study attempts to estimate econometrically the price sensitivity of shippers 1 mode of transport selections and thus arrive at predictions of traffic shifts resulting from deregulation in the most direct way. This study emphasizes mode choice sensitivities in the context of a modal split form. A regression model where some functional form of the combined annual rail and truckload motor common carrier ton/miles of 1 of 17 commodities shipped between two states is the dependent variable and is regressed on relative prices both in ratio and difference form, miles, tons, and several dummy variables. From these regressions the percentage of the total rail and road traffic that would be shifted to rails if they reduced rates by 1 percent of truck rates is determined. A calculation of the economic loss due to distorted mode choice using a modal split curve is then undertaken. This methodology is somewhat similar to the standard consumer surplus approach to this problem. Assumptions and Constraints : First, out-of-pocket costs are used to estimate marginal costs. However, they are accounting constructs based on numerous assumptions on the extent to which certain cost categories vary with traffic levels. Second, the analysis assumes that rail rates could drop to as little as one quarter the truck rates. A more plausible ratio may be higher. Third, there may be a source of error in the estimate of current rates. Fourth, the analysis con- siders only shifts of manufacturers between common motor carriers and rail- roads. Nonmanuf acturers are excluded as well as private carriers, pipelines, airlines and water carriers. Fifth, the data were collected in the 1960's and have since been subjected to inflation, the decline of the northeastern rail- roads, as well as a general increase in freight shipments over the last decade. Sixth, the possibility of model misspecif ication exists. Finally, the calcu- lations assume a fixed quantity of freight traffic. If the combined truck/ rail tonnage is sensitive to price levels, there will be additional costs resulting from distortions from traffic level decisions. There will also be losses in terms of secondary distortions throughout the economy. Conclusions : The study concludes that the intermodal traffic misallocation costs to the economy is $125 million per year. The author assumes that this is a plausible upper bound for the true economic loss due to traffic misallocation. A-114 (37) Goldfarb, Robert S. and John F. Morrall, III, "Cost Implications of Changing Davis-Bacon Administration." Forthcoming in Public Policy . Purpose : To estimate the costs and savings to society of changing the Davis- Bacon wage rates to be consistent with a more accurately determined local prevailing wage. In effect this study estimates the economic loss due to the inefficient determination of prevailing wage rates. Regulatory Intent : The Davis-Bacon Act, passed in 1931, requires contractors engaged in federal government supported construction to pay their employees at rates equal to or above levels as specified by the U.S. Department of Labor. The wage rates set by the Department of Labor are supposed to represent local prevailing wages. Methodology : The authors rely upon a newly available data base — a survey of union and nonunion average wages and Davis-Bacon rates in 19 cities for five occu- pations for September 1972 — to determine if the Davis-Bacon wage rates are in some sense equivalent to the prevailing wage rates, i.e., average wages. A determination of the percent by which union wages exceed average wages is developed, since union wages are usually used as the prevailing wage in order to determine Davis-Bacon rates. Given the total level of public construction in 1972 and the percent of total costs attributable to labor compensation, an estimate of the dollar savings for adjusting union wages back down to average wages is calculated. Assumptions and Constraints : A special 1975 Bureau of Labor Statistics study provided the data for this investigation. Most of the constraints on the data arise out of com- paring wages from this special BLS study with Davis-Bacon rates obtained from the Labor Department. The appropriateness of making the comparison is sub- ject to the following problems: 1. The special survey includes mostly large cities where the degree of unionization may differ from that of smaller cities. 2. The special survey does not include firms with fewer than eight employees . 3. The comparisons are only for five specific occupations in commercial and residential construction. 4. The survey counts as a nonunion wage, a wage paid to a nonunion worker on a Davis-Bacon job. 5. The survey is for September 1972, when the Construction Industry Stabilization Committee was in operation. 6. The BLS survey is for SMSA's, whereas the Davis-Bacon rates do not necessarily encompass the entire SMSA. A-115 (37) Another major category of problems involves the appropriateness of wage differences as a proxy for real cost differences. One particular problem has to do with the lag in the process of recording new wage settlements. If there is a lag in the recording process, Davis-Bacon may typically be below union rates and a long enough lag could bring Davis-Bacon rates below average rates . Conclusions : Given the difference between union and average wages and the amount of public construction in 1972 and labor compensation's proportion of those total costs, the percentage savings translate into dollar savings of $222 million to $571 million for 1972. The estimates made in this study are compared to those made in other study by Thieblot whose estimate of the costs run from around $150 million to $1 billion. A-116 (38) Friedlaender , Ann, "The Social Costs of Regulating the Railroads," ( American Economic Review , May 1971) . Purpose : To measure the social costs arising from rail regulation of value-of- service pricing and by the maintenance of excess capacity in the rail industry. Methodology : A short run and a long run cost function were estimated. The short run cost function was a cross-section estimated for 2-year periods, 1957-1960 and 1961-1964, for 88 railroads. The long run cost function was estimated using quarterly data for the period 1957-1964. From these cost functions short run and long run elasticities were calculated. Full capacity output was then calculated and the cost of lost output was estimated. Constraints : The estimation technique tends to overestimate the excess costs. Conclusions : The costs of excess capacity in 1969 were estimated to be between $2.4 and $3.8 billion. The deadweight costs' due to value-of-service pricing were estimated to be $220 to $270 million in 1969. A-117 (39) Grabowski, Henry G. , Drug Regulation and Innovations : Empirical Evidence and Policy Options (Washington, D.C. : American Enterprise Institute, 1976). Purpose : To ascertain the effects of Food and Drug Administration regulations on the pharmaceutical industry. Methodology : Grabowski surveyed articles by Martin Bailey, Sam Peltzman, and William Wardell ; and Henry Grabowski, John Vernon, and Lacy G. Thomas on the effects of government regulation on the pharmaceutical industries Conclusion : Grabowski 's conclusion was that government regulation has a signifi- cant negative effect on the rate of innovation. A-118 (40) Smith, Robert S., "The Occupational Safety and Health Act," (Washington, D.C- : American Enterprise Institute, 1976). Purpose : To evaluate the goals, the administration, and the impact of the Occupational Safety and Health Act of 1970. Methodology : Benefit-cost studies are the tools used to determine whether the increases in human welfare (the benefits) which arise from compliance with a particular standard are larger than the human welfare foregone because resources which could be used for other goods and services are devoted instead to increased safety and health (the cost) . The study attempts to answer the question whether the workers benefiting from increased safety would be willing to pay for the program. Constraints : It is not always possible to estimate people's willingness to pay for risk reduction and what evidence there is may be fragmentary or subject to statistical biases. Conclusions : Based on this study's analysis, the author conjectures that workers would not be willing to pay for increased protection. It should be stressed that estimates of benefits must attempt to discover what the beneficiaries themselves are actually willing to pay for the benefits, not what someone thinks they should be willing to pay. If individuals with accurate informa- tion about risks show little concern about them, and if we are willing to let people decide important personal issues for themselves, then govern- ment bureaucracies (like OSHA) are not justified in pronouncing workers "irrational" and by inflating benefits forcing more safety upon them than they would voluntarily choose . A-119 (41) Comanor, William S. and Bridger M. Mitchell, "The Cost of Planning: The FCC and Cable Television." Purpose : To determine the loss of efficiency because of the restricted demand caused by government regulation. Methodology : The maximum resources available for regulatory purposes are the revenues earned by the regulated firm which exceed their cost. The loss of efficiency from regulation depends crucially on the extent to which output is restricted by higher prices . The prices which can be set by a regulated firm depend greatly on the price elasticity of demand. Much depends on the appropriate value of the elasticity of demand. When demand is highly inelastic, prices can be increased without severely limiting the volume of output and therefore regulators have greater freedom to impose additional financial burdens on the firms . Constraints : Estimates of benefits and cost depend critically on detailed infor- mation on market prices and demands in the absence as well as in the presence of ongoing regulatory activity. Conclusions : Comanor and Mitchell do not measure the actual benefits of regulation, but they do state that they feel these benefits would be quite low. Comanor and Mitchell estimate the loss to the economy from the higher price of regulated cable T.V. at between $1 billion and $2 billion a year, depending on the magnitude of demand elasticity. Cable television repre- sents a minor part of the total FCC regulatory program and by no means represents the total cost of the FCC. A-120 IMPACT OF SINGLE REGULATIONS ON A SPECIFIC GROUP OR INDUSTRY A-121 (42) Miernyk, William H. and Jolin T. Sears, Air Pollution and Regional Economic Development in Input Output Analysis (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, 1974). Purpose : To estimate the costs of air pollution abatement from stationary coal burning industrial plants in West Virginia. Methodology : Cost projections of pollution control were collected from polluting industrial plants in West Virginia. These costs were supplemented from data in the pollution control literature. Cost data were collected for three alternative levels of pollution control: 1. Physical coal-cleaning 2. Physical cleaning with some Myers-TRW chemical coal-cleaning 3. Chemical coal-cleaning and sulfur oxide flue gas scrubbing Conclusions : The costs of air pollution control are given below. Millions of Estimated 1975 Dollars ALTERNATIVE Total Capital Costs Total Operating Costs Change in Total Gross Output $352 $439 $976 $ 55 $ 78 $152 $323 $413 $864 A-122 (43) Seskin, Eugene P., "Automobile Air Pollution Policy," Chapter III in Portney, Paul R. , Editor, Current Issues in U.S. Environmental Policy , (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1978). Purpose : Review the current status of mobile source pollution abatement, assess the costs and benefits of the current situation and recommend alternative methods for providing for environmental safety other than direct source regulation. Regulatory Intents : Title II of the 1970 Amendments to the Clean Air Act, officially labeled The National Emission Standards Act, detailed the timetable for automobile exhaust emission standards. With the energy crisis in 1973-74, the administrator of the EPA granted a delay in compliance. A new schedule to be met by all automobiles by 1982 was enacted. Assumptions : Cost estimates were taken from The Cumulative Regulatory Effects on the Cost of Automobile Transportation prepared by the Ad Hoc Committee of the Office of Science and Technology, Washington, D.C., 1972. No further details on assumptions or constraints to the particular estimating procedure are available in this article. Conclusions : The cost estimates of automotive emissions control over the 1976 to 1985 decade totaled $95.1 billion for meeting the original standards legislated in the 1970 Amendments. The annual costs after this period were estimated to be $10.1 billion. In addition, a 1974 NAS study entitled Air Quality and Automobile Emission Control, Vol. 4 The Cost and Benefits of Automobile Emission Control, Report by the Coordinating Committee on Air Quality Studies , National Academy of Sciences, National Academy of Engineering (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1974), also reported certain costs of compliance based on best available data at that time. Their estimates were in the range of $8 to $11 billion annually through 1985. Less stringent standards reduced the costs significantly. A-123 (44) Posner, Richard, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy , Vol. 83, No. 4 (1975). Purpose : To develop a model and estimate social costs of monopoly-inducing regulation in the United States . Methodology : A model to estimate the total social costs of monopoly was developed. The social costs were estimated as a function of the price elasticity of demand, the total sales revenue at the monopoly price and output and the ratio of competitive price to the monopoly price. Estimates of monopoly price increase and the elasticity of demand were obtained from current literature of industry studies and from these calculations of the social costs of monopoly were made . Constraints ; There may be some questions concerning the assumptions on which the model is based. The data on price increases and elasticities of demand are only crude estimates. Conclusions : The social costs of regulation were found to range from 14 to 31 percent of industry sales for physicians' services, 13 to 24 percent for eyeglasses, 5 to 10 percent for milk, 19 to 30 percent for motor carriers, 20 to 32 percent for oil, and 19 to 20 percent for airlines. Private monopoly may be less (social) costly than public regulations. A-125 IV. EXTENSIVE BIBLIOGRAPHY ON REGULATORY IMPACT STUDIES A-127 IMPACT OF ALL REGULATIONS ON THE NATIONAL ECONOMY Chilton, Kenneth W. , "The Impact of Federal Regulation on American Small Business — Attachment to Testimony Prepared for the Committee on Small Business of the U.S. House of Representatives," (March 8, 1978). DeFina, Robert, Public and Private Expenditures for Federal Regulation of Business (St. Louis, Mo. : Washington University Center for the Study of American Business, Working Paper No. 22, November 1977). DeFina, Robert and Murray L. Weidenbaum, The Taxpayer and Government Regulation (St. Louis, Mo. : Washington University Center for the Study of American Business, March 1978). Joint Economic Committee, Subcommittee on Economic Growth and Stabiliza- tion, U.S. Congress, The Cost of Government Regulation of Business (Wash- ington, D.C.: JEC, April 1978). Leone, Robert A., "The Real Costs of Regulation," Harvard Business Review (November-December 1977). MacAvoy, Paul W. , The Economic Effects of Regulation (Cambridge, Mass.: Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1965) . McCraw, Thomas K. , "Regulation in America: A Review Article," Business History Review (Summer 1975) . Weidenbaum, Murray L. , "Business and Government: The Changing Relationship" in Frank J. Bonello and Thomas R. Swartz, eds . , Alternative Directions in Economic Policy (Notre Dame, Ind. : University of Notre Dame Press, 1978). Weidenbaum, Murray L., "On Estimating Regulatory Costs," AEI Journal of Government and Society (May/ June 1978) . Weidenbaum, Murray L. , Government-Mandated Price Increases (Washington, D.C. : American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 1975) . Weidenbaum, Murray L., "The High Costs of Government Regulations," Business Horizons (August 1975) . Weidenbaum, Murray L. , "The New Wave of Government Regulation of Business," Business and Society Review (Fall 1975). Weidenbaum, Murray L. , "Reducing Inflationary Pressures by Reforming Government Regulation," in William Fellner, ed., Contemporary Economic Problems , (Washington, D.C. : American Enterprise Institute, 1976) . Weidenbaum, Murray L. and Robert DeFina, The Cost of Federal Regulation of Economic Activity , Reprint No. 88 (Washington, D.C. : American Enterprise Institute, 1978). A-128 IMPACT OF MULTIPLE REGULATIONS ON THE NATIONAL ECONOMY Bailey, Elizabeth, "Innovation and Regulation," Journal of Public Economics (August 1974) . Baily, M.N. and J. Tobin, "Macroeconomic Effects of Selective Public Employment and Wage Subsidies , " Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (No. 2, 1977). Bergsten, C. Fred, The Cost of Import Restrictions to American Consumers (New York: American Importers' Association, 1972). Berry, John, "Missing: $40 Billion," Forbes (March 6, 1978). Briggs, Jean A. "The Price of Environmentalism — The Backlash Begins," Forbes (June 15, 1977). Brimmer, Andrew F. , "Impact Controls and Domestic Inflation," a Paper Presented Before the Economics Seminar, University of Maryland, (November 11, 1970) . Carter , Anne P . "Energy , Environment , and Economic Growth , " Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (Autumn 1974) . Chase Econometric Associates, Inc., The Macroeconomic Impact of Federal Pollution Control Programs (Washington, D.C.: Council on Environmental Quality, January 1975) . Council of Economic Advisers, Annual Report (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1976) . Council of Economic Advisers, Annual Report (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1977) . Council on Environmental Quality, The Economic Impact of Pollution Control - A Summary of Recent Studies (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1972) . Council on Environmental Quality and Environmental Protection Agency, The Macroeconomic Impacts of Federal Pollution Control Programs : 1976 Assessment (Washington, D.C.: CEQ & EPA, 1976). Crandall, Robert W. , "Federal Government Initiatives to Reduce the Price Level," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (No. 2, 1978). Demsetz, Harold, "Why Regulate Utilities?" Journal of Law and Economics (April 1973) . Dorfman, Robert, "Incidence of the Benefits and Costs of Environmental Programs," American Economic Review (Feb. 1977). A-129 Economic Report of the President , February 1975 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975). Environmental Protection Agency, Economic Analysis of Effluent Guidelines (Washington, D.C.: EPA 1974). Environmental Protection Agency, The Economic Impact of the Federal Environmental Program: A Report to the Subcommittee on Agriculture , Environment and Consumer Protection of the Committee on Appropriations of the House of Representatives . Federal Trade Commission, Bureau of Economics, Staff Report on the United States Steel Industry and its International Rivals : Trends and Factors Determining International Competitiveness (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1977). Fisher, Anthony C. and Frederick M. Peterson, "The Environment in Economics A Survey," Journal of Economic Literature (March 1976). Friedlaender , Ann F., The Dilemna of Freight Transport Regulation (Washing- ton, D.C. : The Brookings Institution, 1969). Harbeson, Robert W. "Toward Better Resource Allocation in Transport," Journal of Law and Economics (October, 1969) . Hendricks, Wallace, "Regulation and Labor Earnings," The Bell Journal of Economics , (Autumn 1977) . Hill, Gladwin, "Midpoint of 'Environmental Decade': Impact of National Policy Act Assessed," Management Review (May 1975). Hill, Gladwin, Lloyd A. Free, and Donald R. Lesh, Protecting The Environ- ment: Progress, Prospects, and the Public View (Washington, D.C: Potomac Associates, 1977). Joint Economic Committee, United States Congress, The Economic Impact of Environmental Regulations (Washington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1974) . Jordan, W.A. , "Producer Protection, Prior Market Structure and the Effects of Government Regulation," Journal of Law and Economics (April 1972). Kangun, Norman and R. Charles Moyer, "The Failings of Regulation," MSU Business Topics (Spring 1976) . Klein, Burton H. , A Dynamic Theory of Regulation , Social Science Working Paper number 199 (California Institute of Technology, Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences, February 1978). Kneese, Allen V., Economics and the Environment (New York: Penguin Books, 1977) . Lave, Lester B. and Eugene P. Seskin, Air Pollution and Human Health (Washington, D.C: Resources for the Future, 1977). A-130 Levin, Richard C, "Allocation in Surface Freight Transportation: Does Rate Regulation Matter?" The Bell Journal of Economics (Spring 1978) . MacAvoy, Paul W. , Crisis of the Regulatory Commissions (New York: Norton, 1970) . MacAvoy, Paul W. , "The Effectiveness of the Federal Power Commission," The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (1970) . MacAvoy , Paul W . ed . , Federal Energy Administration Regulation: Report of the Presidential Task Force (Washington, D.C. : American Enterprise Institute, 1977) . Moore, Thomas Gale, "Deregulating Surface Freight Transportation," in Almarin Phillips, ed. , Promoting Competition in Regulated Markets (Wash- ington, D.C. : The Brookings Institution, 1975) . Moore, Thomas Gale, Freight Transportation Regulation : Surface Freight and the ICC (Washington, D.C: American Enterprise Institute, 1972). National Economic Research Associates, The Inflationary Impact of Federal Pollution Abatement Legislation (New York: NERA, 1975) . Noll, Roger G. , Reforming Regulation: An Evaluation of the Ash Council Proposals (Washington, D.C: Brookings Institution, 1971). Peck, Merton J. "Competitive Policy for Transportation?" in Almarin Phillips, ed., Perspectives on Antitrust Policy (Princeton, N.J. : Princeton University Press, 1965). Peterson, H. Craig, "An Empirical Test of Regulatory Effects," The Bell Journal of Economics (Spring 1975) . Portney, Paul R. , ed. , U.S. Environmental Policy (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1978). Posner, Richard A., "Taxation by Regulation," The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (Spring 1971) . Posner, Richard A., "Theories of Economic Regulation," The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science , (Autumn 1974) . Seneca, Joseph J. and M. K. Taussig, Environmental Economics (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice Hall, 1974). Shepherd, William G. and Thomas G. Gies , eds., Regulation in Further Perspective (Cambridge, Mass: Ballinger Publishing Co., 1974). U.S. Senate, The Status of Environmental Economics . A Report Prepared by the Environmental Policy Division of the Congressional Research Service of the Library of Congress for the Committee on Public Works, U.S. Senate (Washington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975). A-131 Von Furstenberg, George M. , "The Government and Capital Formation: A Survey of Recent Issues," Journal of Economic Literature (Sept. 1977), Walker, Michael J., "The Impact of Environmental Impact Statements," Management Review (Jan. 1974) . Weidenbaum, Murray L. , Business, Government, and the Public (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1977). Wharton Econometric Forecasting Associates, Inc., Wharton Short-Term Econometric Model Post-Meeting Forecast Review (June 1, 1977). A-132 IMPACT OF MULTIPLE REGULATIONS ON A SPECIFIC GROUP OR INDUSTRY Arthur D. Little, Inc., Economic Impact of Environmental Regulations on the United States Copper Industry (Washington, D.C. : EPA, January 1978) . Arthur D. Little, Inc., Steel and the Environment; A Cost Impact Analysis: Report to the American Iron and Steel Institut e (Arthur D. Little, Inc., 1978). Arthur D. Little, Inc., Steel and the Environment: A Cost Impact Analysis: Report to the American Iron and Steel Institute (Arthur D. Little, Inc. , 1975) . Boo the, Joan Nor r is, Cleaning Up: The Cost of Refinery Pollution Control (New York: Council on Economic Priorities, 1975). Commission on Federal Paperwork, Final Summary Report (Washington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office, October 3, 1977) . Council on Environmental Quality, Coal Surface Mining and Reclamation : An Evaluation and Economic Assessment of Alternatives (Washington, D.C: 1973) . Council on Environmental Quality, Who Bears the Cost of Pollution Control? : The Impact of the Distribution of Income of Financing Federally Required Pollution Control (Washington, D.C: CEQ, 1973). (Prepared by Public Interest Economic Center) . Dorfman, Nancy S., "Who Will Pay for Pollution Control? — The Distribution by Income of the Burden of the National Environmental Protection Program," National Tax Journal (March 1975) . Environmental Protection Agency, Economic Impact of EPA ' s Regulation on the Petroleum Refining Industry (Washington, D.C: EPA 1976). Environmental Protection Agency, Economic Impact of Pollution Control . Regulations on Steel Plants in the Mahoning River Valley (Washington, D.C: EPA, 1976) . Fieleke, Norman S., "The Cost of Tariffs to Consumers," New England Economic Review (Sept. -Oct., 1971). Hittman, Associates, Inc., Prepared for the Appalachian Regional Commission, Federal State and Local Regulatory Powers Affecting Energy Processing and Related Development in the Appalachian Region (Washington, D.C. : Appala- chian Regional Commission, February 1977) . McNicol, David L. , "The Comparative Statics Properties of the Theory of the Regulated Firm," The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (Autumn 1973) . A-133 Meyer, Robert A., "Capital Structure and the Behavior of the Regulated Firm Under Uncertainty," Southern Economic Journal (April 1976). Sheppard, W. , et. al., Battelle Columbus Laboratories, Final Report on The Economic Impact of Environmental Regulations on the Petroleum Industry Phase II Study (Washington, D.C. : American Petroleum Institute, June 11, 1976) . Spann, Robert M. "Rate of Return Regulation and Efficiency in Production: An Empirical Test of the Averch-Johnson Thesis," The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (Spring 1974) . Temple, Barker and Sloan, Inc., Economic and Financial Impacts of Federal Air and Water Pollution Controls on the Electric Utility Industry, Execu- tive Summary (Washington, D.C: EPA, May 1976). Thompson, Russell G. , James A. Calloway, and Lillian A. Nawalanic , The Cost of Electricity: Cheap Power vs. a Clean Environment (Houston, Texas Gulf Publishing Company, 1977) . Tuccillo, John, "Taxation by Regulation: The Case of Financial Interme- diaries," The Bell Journal of Economics (Autumn 1977). URS Research Company, The Economic Impacts on the American Paper Industry of Pollution Control Costs (San Mateo, Cal : URS, 1975). Van Alstyne, Carol and Sharon Coldren, The Costs of Implementing Federally Mandated Social Programs at Colleges and Universities (Washington, D.C. : American Council on Education, June 1976) . Weidenbaum, Murray L., "Government Regulation and the Cost of Housing," Urban Land , (Feb. 1978) . White, Lawrence J., "Quality Variation When Prices are Regulated," The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (Autumn 1972) . A-134 IMPACT OF A SINGLE REGULATION ON THE NATIONAL ECONOMY Arpan, Jeffrey S., "Regulation of Foreign Direct Investment in the United States: Quo Vasis, Vuo Vadit?" Journal of Contemporary Business (Autumn 1977) . Besen, S. M. et. al . , "Economic Policy Research on Cable Television: Assessing the Costs and Benefits of Cable Deregulation," in Paul W. MacAvoy, ed. , Deregulation of Cable Television (Washington, D.C. : American Enter- prise Institute, 1977). Boyer, Kenneth D. , "Minimum Rate Regulation, Modal Split Sensitivities, and the Railroad Problem," Journal of Political Economy (June 1977). Breyer, Stephen G. , and Paul W. MacAvoy, Energy Regulation by the Federal Power Commission (Washington, D.C: Brookings Institution, 1974). Brooke, Paul, "Why Do We Pay So Much for Prescription Drugs?" Business and Society Review (Spring 1975) . Buxton, Boyd M. and Jerome W. Hammond, "Social Cost of Alternative Dairy Price Support Levels," American Journal of Agricultural Economics (May 1974). CAB Special Staff, CAB Regulatory Reform: Report of the CAB Special Staff (Washington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975). Campbell, Rita Ricardo , Food Safety Regulation: A Study of the Use and Limitations of Cost-Benefit Analysis (Washington, D.C: American Enter- prise Institute, 1974). Clawson, Marion, Economics of National Forest Management (Baltimore, Md. : Johns Hopkins University Press, 1976). Comanor, W. and B. Mitchell, "The Costs of Planning: The FCC and Cable Television," Journal of Law and Economics (April 1972). Comptroller General of the United States, Need to Improve Benefit-Cost Analyses in Setting Motor Vehicle Safety Standards , B-164497 (3) (Washington, D.C: U.S. General Accounting Office, 1974). Davis, Karen, National Health Insurance: Benefits, Costs, and Consequences (Washington, D.C: Brookings Institution, 1975). Douglas, George W. and James C Miller, Economic Regulation of Domestic Air Transport: Theory and Policy (Washington, D.C: Brookings Institution, 1974) . Environmental Protection Agency, The Cost of Clean Air (Washington, D.C: EPA 1973) . A-135 Environmental Protection Agency, The Cost of Clean Water (Washington, D.C. : EPA 1971) . Environmental Protection Agency, The Cost of Clean Water and Its Economic Impact (Washington, D.C: EPA, 1969). Environmental Protection Agency, Economic Evaluation of the Promulgated Interim Drinking Water Regulations (Washington, D.C: EPA 1975). Environmental Protection Agency, Economic Evaluation of the Proposed In- terim Primary Drinking Water Regulation (Washington, D.C: EPA 1975). Environmental Protection Agency, Economics of Clean Water (Washington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1972). Environmental Protection Agency, The Economics of Clean Water - 1973 (Washington, D.C: EPA 1973). Farmer, Richard N. "The Case for Unregulated Truck Transportation," Journal of Farm Economics (May 1964) . Friedlaender, Ann, "The Social Costs of Regulating the Railroads," American Economic Review (May 1971) . Friend, Irwin, "Economic Foundations of Stock Market Regulation," Journal of Contemporary Business (Winter 1975) . Goldfarb, Robert S. and John F. Morrall , III, "Cost Implications of Changing Davis-Bacon Administration," forthcoming in Public Policy Gould , John P . , Davis-Bacon Act: The Economics of Prevailing Wage Laws , (Washington, D.C: American Enterprise Institute, 1971). Grabowski, Henry G. Drug Regulation and Innovation: Empirical Evidence and Policy Options (Washington, D.C: American Enterprise Institute, 1976). Grabowski, Henry C, John M. Vernon, and Lacy G. Thomas, "The Effects of Regulatory Policy on the Incentives to Innovate : an International Compara- tive Analysis," in Samuel A. Mitchell and Emery A. Link, eds., Impact of Public Policy on Drug Innovation and Pricing (Washington, D.C. : American University, 1976) . Hanke, Steve H. and Ivars Gutmanis , "Estimates of Industrial Waterborne Residuals Control Costs: A Review of Concepts, Methodology, and Empirical Results," in Peskin, Henry M. and Eugene P. Seskin, Cost Benefit Analysis and Water Pollution Policy (Washington, D.C: The Urban Institute, 1975). Heien, Dale, "The Cost of the U.S. Dairy Price Support Program: 1949-1974," Review of Economics and Statistics (February 1977) . Herman, Stewart W. , The Health Costs of Air Pollution: A Survey of Studies Published 1967-1977 (New York: American Lung Association, December 1977). A-136 "The High Price of Job Safety," Business Week (May 26, 1973). Ippolito, Richard and Robert Mason, "The Social Cost of Federal Regulation of Milk," unpublished paper cited in Paul MacAvoy, Federal Milk Marketing Orders and Price Supports (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Insti- tute, 1977). Jordan, W. A., Airline Regulation in America (Baltimore, Md. , Johns Hopkins University Press, 1970) . Keeler, Theodore, "Airline Regulations and Market Performance," The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (Autumn 1972) . Kelman, Steven, "Regulation by the Numbers — A Report on the Consumer Product Safety Commission," The Public Interest (Summer 1974). Kessel, Reuben, "Economic Effects of Federal Regulation of Milk Markets," Journal of Law and Economics , (October 1967) . Kwoka, John Jr., "Pricing Under Federal Milk Market Regulation," Economic Inquiry (July 1977) . LaMond, Annette M. "An Evaluation of Intrastate Airline Regulation in California," The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (Autumn 1976). Lave, L. , and W. Weber, "A Benefit-Cost Analysis of Auto Safety Features," Applied Economics (1970) . MacAvoy, Paul W. , Federal Milk Marketing Orders and Price Supports (Wash- ington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1977). MacAvoy, Paul W. and John W. Snow, eds., Railroad Revitalization and Regulatory Reform (Washington, D.C. : American Enterprise Institute, 1977). Mintz, Use, U.S. Import Quotas: Costs and Consequences (Washington, D.C: American Enterprise Institute, 1973) . National Commission on Water Quality, Staff Report to the National Commission on Water Quality (Washington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office, April 1976) . Nay, Joe N. , John W. Scanlon, and Joseph S. Wholey, Benefits and Costs of Manpower Training Programs : A Synthesis With Reservations and Recommenda- tions , Reprinted from the Joint Economic Committee, Benefit-Cost Analysis of Federal Programs , 92nd Congress, 2nd Session, January 1973 (Washington, D.C: The Urban Institute, March 1973). Noll, Roger C, Merton J. Peck, and John J. McGowan, Economic Aspects of Television Regulation (Washington, D.C: Brookings Institution, 1973). Oi, Walter Y. , "The Economics of Product Safety," The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (Spring 1973) . A-137 Paul, Robert D. and Martin E. Segal Company, "The Impact of Pension Reform on American Business," Sloan Management Review (Fall 1976). Peltzman, Sam, "The Effects of Automobile Safety Regulation," Journal of Political Economy (August 1975) . Peltzman, Sam, "An Evaluation of Consumer Protection Legislation: The 1962 Drug Amendments," Journal of Political Economy , (September-October 1973) Peltzman, Sam, Regulation of Pharmaceutical Innovation (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1974). Peskin, Henry M. and Eugene P. Seskin, eds., Cost Benefit Analysis and Water Pollution Policy (Washington, D.C. : The Urban Institute, 1975). Ragan, James F. Minimum Wages and the Youth Labor Market , publication No. 14 (St. Louis, Mo.: Center for the Study of American Business, Wash- ington University, August 1977) . Ruppenthal, Karl M. , "Some Economic Aspects of the Barge Line Mixing Rule," Transportation Journal (Spring 1970) . Smith, James S., "The Equal Credit Opportunity Act of 1974: A Cost-Benefit Analysis," paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Finance Association (September 1976) . Smith, Robert S., The Occupational Safety and Health Act (Washington, D.C: American Enterprise Institute, 1976) . Thieblot, A. J. , The Davis-Bacon Act , Labor Relations and Policy Series Report No. 10 (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania, 1975). U.S. Senate, Committee on Commerce, Motor Vehicle Safety Oversight (Wash- ington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1974). Weaver, Paul H. , "Noise Regulation Strikes a Sour Note," Fortune (March 1976). Weston, J. Fred, "Economic Aspects of Consumer Product Safety," in George Steiner, ed., Issues in Business and Society (New York: Random House, 1972). Yale Law Journal, "Is Regulation Necessary? California Air Transportation and National Regulatory Policy," Yale Law Journal (July 1965). A-138 IMPACT OF A SINGLE REGULATION ON A SPECIFIC GROUP OR INDUSTRY Caves, R. E. , Air Transport and Its Regulators (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1962). DeVany, Arthur S., "The Effect of Price and Entry Regulation on Airline Output, Capacity and Efficiency," The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (Spring 1975) . Eads, George C, "Competition in the Domestic Trunk Airline Industry: Too Much or Too Little," in Almarin Phillips ed., Competition and Regulation (Washington, D.C. : Brookings Institution, 1974). Grabowski, Henry G. and John M. Vernon, "Structural Effects of Regulation in the Drug Industry," in Robert Mason and P. David Quails, eds., Essays in Industrial Organization in Honor of Joe Bain (Cambridge , Mass . : Ballinger 1976) . Miernyk, William H. and J. T. Sears, Air Pollution Abatement and Regional Economic Development in Input Output Analysis , (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, 1974) . Muskin, Jerold B. and John A. Sorrentino, Jr. , "Externalities in a Regulated Industry: The Aircraft Noise Problem," The American Economic Review (September 1977) . Pope, Claude E. , Mortgage Bankers Association, "Regulation on FHA's Un- subsidized Housing Programs , " Statement before the Task Force on Tax Expenditures, Government Organization and Regulation of the Committee on the Budget, U.S. House of Representatives (Washington, D.C: MBA, May 20, 1977) Posner, Richard, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy , Vol. 83, No. 4 (1975). Seskin, Eugene P., "Automobile Air Pollution Policy," in Portney, Paul R. , ed. , Current Issues in U.S. Environmental Policy (Baltimore, Md. : Johns Hopkins University Press, 1978). Thompson, Russell G. , James A. Calloway, and Lillian A. Nawalanic , eds., The cost of Clean Water: in Ammonia, Chlor-Alkali, and Ethylene Production (Houston, Texas: Gulf Publishing Company, 1976). A-139 V. DATA SOURCES ON THE COSTS OF GOVERNMENT REGULATION A-141 SOURCES OF DATA This section represents a survey of the major sources of economic data on the effects of government regulation. Publications from the Bureau of the Census, Department of Commerce, Bureau of Labor Statistics and others are included. A fairly detailed search of publications by agencies such es the Environmental Protection Agency, the Food and Drug Administration, the Department of Transportation, etc., that promulgate environmental regulations, has been undertaken. Personal and telephone interviews were also carried out with experts in the field of pollution regulations, abatement costs, and compliance to determine the extent of data available. The main findings of this effort are that there is a general paucity of data on the costs of pollution abatement. In most cases, government agencies do not collect and publish data on the cost of compliance on an ongoing basis. Industries that are to be regulated submit their estimates of costs and com- bined with government cost estimates provide the information necessary to prepare Environmental Impact Statements. These estimates are generally not collected systematically, nor are they always presented in the regulating agencies' reports. It is the intent of this section, therefore, to cover the more general sources of costs of pollution abatement, to provide their listings and descriptions. We do not list the individual Environmental Impact Statements that provide a source of estimates of some costs due to pollution regulations. A-142 ANNOTATIONS 1 . American Petroleum Institute Pollution control expenditures for the petroleum industry in Environmental Expenditure of the United States Petroleum Industry 1967-1976 . (Annual series) Data: Total pollution control expenditures on air, water, and land, 1967-1976. Maintenance expenditure on air, water, and land, 1967-1976. Research and development expenditure on air, water, and land, 1967-1976. 2. Bureau of Economic Analysis Pollution abatement and control expenditure in Survey 6f Current Business (Annual series in February issues) Data: Private and public expenditures for pollution abatement and control. Private and public expenditures for air and water pollution abatement. Federal grants for pollution abatement and control. New plant and equipment expenditures for pollution abatement in Survey of Current Business . (Annual series in July issues through 1976, June issues thereafter) Data: New plant and equipment expenditures for abatement of air, water, and solid waste pollutions. Bureau of the Census Federal, State, and local government expenditures for pollution abate- ment and prevention in Environmental Quality Control, State and Local Government Special Studies No. 86, Government Finances: Fiscal Year 1975-1976. A-143 Data: Governmental expenditures for selected environmental quality control activities, 1975-1976. State governmental expenditures for water, land, and air quality activities, 1974-1976. Local government expenditures for water, land, and air quality control activities, 1973-1976. Selected large local government expenditures for water purification, 1975-1976. Pollution abatement expenditures in current industrial reports, Series: MA- 200. (Annual series) Data: Manufactures pollution abatement capital expenditures by SIC. Manufactures pollution abatement operating cost by SIC. Selected Industrial Air Pollution Control Equipment in Current Indus- trial Reports, Series: MA- 35 J (Annual series) Data: Value of shipments of selected industrial air pollution control equipment. New orders, shipments, and backlog of orders for selected indus- trial air pollution control equipment. Council on Environmental Quality Pollution abatement expenditures in Environmental Quality-The Annual Report of the Council on Environmental Quality . Years Available: Annual since 1970. Data: Estimated incremental pollution abatement expenditures. Estimated cost and fuel economy impacts of alternative emissions control requirements . Estimated direct employment in pollution control activities. Estimated total pollution expenditures. A-144 Environmental Protection Agency Air and water pollution control expenditures in Cost of Air and Water Pollution Control 1975-1985 (February 1976) . Data: Projected investment over 1976-1985 for air and water pollution control. Total cost of air and water pollution control, 1976-1985. Ranking of impacted sector by total abatement expenditures as percentage of investment and output, 1976-1985. Accumulated estimated air pollution expenditures, 1971-1985. Government spending for air pollution control. Industrial air pollution control expenditures. Water pollution control expenditures in Cost of Clean Water, Vol. II: Cost Effectiveness and Clean Water (March 1971) Data: Industrial investment in air and water pollution control, 1969-1970. Estimated investment for waste treatment works, 1962-1968. Effective rate of recapitalizations, 1962-1968. Relative growth of population and sewer service 1962-1968. Distribution of waste treatment investment, 1962-1968. Water pollution control expenditures in Industry Expenditures for Water Pollution Abatement from the Conference Board by Leonard Lund. Data: Capital expenditure cost data. Overall expenditures for operations and maintenance. Public sewer use data. Wastewater volume and effluent data. 6. U.S. Department of the Interior-Federal Water Pollution Control Adminis tration A-145 Water pollution control expenditure in The Cost of Clean Water and Its Economic Impact (4 Vol.), 1969. (Intent was to update annually) Data: Vol. I - cost estimates of new plant and equipment for selected industries to meet water pollution standards. Vol. II - new data on costs of municipal water pollution control. Vol. Ill - local financing of wastewater treatment systems. Vol. IV - five-year projection of estimated costs of controlling pollution in the Organic Chemistry Industry. 7. McGraw-Hill Pollution control expenditures in the Annual McGraw-Hill Survey of Pollution Control Expenditures . Years Available: Annual since 1968. Data: Industry expenditure for pollution control. Investment for air and water pollution controls. Total expenditure for air and water pollution control. Total pollution control expenditure as percent of capital spending. Total R&D pollution control expenditures. Capacity shutdown due to environmental and safety regulations. Investment in employee safety and health in the Annual McGraw-Hill Survey Investment in Employee Safety and Health Years Available: Annual since 197 3. Data: Investment in employee safety and health. Employee safety and health investments as a percent of capital spending. Capacity shutdowns due to environmental and safety regulations. A-146 BIBLIOGRAPHY OF DATA SOURCES American Petroleum Institute, Environmental Expenditures of the United States Petroleum Industry 1967-1976 (Washington, D.C. : API, 1977). Bureau of the Census , Environmental Quality Control, Government Finances : Fiscal Year 1975-76 , State and Local Government Special Studies No. 86 (Washington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office, March 1978). Bureau of the Census , Pollution Abatement Costs and Expenditures 1973 , Current Industrial Reports, Series: MA-200 (Washington, D.C: U.S. Govern- ment Printing Office, March 1976). Bureau of the Census , Selected Industrial Air Pollution Control Equipment , Current Industrial Reports, Series: MA-35J (Washington, D.C: U.S. Govern- ment Printing Office, 1974). Council on Environmental Quality, Environmental Quality-The Eighth Annual Report of the Council on Environmental Quality (Washington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1977). Cremeans, John E., "Capital Expenditures by Business for Air and Water Pollution Abatement, 1973 and Planned 1974," Survey of Current Business (July 1974) . Cremeans, John E., and Frank W. Segel, "National Expenditures for Pollution Abatement and Control, 1972," Survey of Current Business (February 1975). Cremeans, John E., Frank W. Segel, and Gary L. Rutledge , "Capital Expendi- tures by Business for Air, Water, and Solid Waste Pollution Abatement, 1974 and Planned 1975," Survey of Current Business (July 1975). Environmental Protection Agency, Cost of Air and Water Pollution Control 1975-1985 (Washington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office, February 1976) . Environmental Protection Agency, Cost of Clean Water, Vol. II: Cost Effectiveness and Clean Water (Washington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office, March 1971) . Environmental Protection Agency, Industry Expenditures for Water Pollution Abatement (Washington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1977). 4th Annual McGraw-Hill Survey: Investment in Employee Safety and Health (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1976). 10th Annual McGraw-Hill Survey of Pollution Control Expenditures (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1977) . Segel, Frank W. and Frederick J. Dreiling, "Pollution Abatement and Control Expenditures, 1972-76," Survey of Current Business (February 1978). A-147 Segel, Frank W. and Betsy C. Dunlap, "Capital Expenditures by Business for Pollution Abatement 1976 and Planned 1977," Survey of Current Business (June 1977) . Segel, Frank W. and Gary L. Rutledge "Capital Expenditures by Business for Air, Water, and Solid Waste Pollution Abatement, 1975 and Planned 1976," Survey of Current Business (July 1976) . Segel, Frank W. and Gary L. Rutledge, "National Expenditures for Pollution Abatement and Control, 1973," Survey of Current Business (February 1976). Segel, Frank W. , Gary L. Rutledge, and Frederick J. Dreiling, "Pollution Abatement and Control Expenditures , 1974," Survey of Current Business (February 1977) . U.S. Department of the Interior — Federal Water Pollution Control Adminis- tration, The Cost of Clean Water and Its Economic Impact (Washington, D.C. : U.S. Government Printing Office, 1969). A-149 VI. INDEX A-151 3 u H W Cm ffi u O Pd s W 28 O o w i u CD p rl 0) M-l fa m 0) a b m o ■k •H c n •H c 3 w D <+H in CU -P u CU 3 X P < P •H P o in • • p 3 p H c p 0) Sh rH £ O CU 2 & CU CU P SH fa CO •H > T3 c • • 3 w w •H cd cu en 3 .c >< O p rH H 13 c •• 3 w CO •rl id OJ in 3 ■3 >i O P rH U id H 13 13 3 cd (d p o rH o •H cu (0 H cu ft CU P co S H 1 CN CD 00 CD CO ^r CM ^f <* 00 00 "vT tn CN CN CN CN CO ro m oo (M CN ro rH 1 1 rH ■ rH •-{ r-\ rH r-\ rH rH 1 <-\ | 1 < 1 < 1 < 1 1 < 1 1 1 < 1 1 < 1 < 1 < 1 ■ U1 rH 1 1 1 1 < 1 1 1 1 < 1 1 1 1 *» 1 1 v 1 1 ! 1 1 1 ^-^ ^—^ *- V H CM LD vO CN ' — ' rH ro en kD CO •sr rH 1 rH •-i CN 1 < 1 1 1 < 1 1 1 < 1 l< 1 1 1 1 ^^ 1 1 ^ ( 1 1 1 1 1 1 oo 3 ■H O CM cd rn in -rl -sT % U id S ge rH 3 id Pm T3 C cd ,3 tJ Sh • 6 fo P T3 CU P ^ Q CU 3 >H cu O c • 5 XI id fc S A cu rt! cu id ta P A ^ N • • • C CU C T3 r-i •rH s u C a id C cu id s 3 r-t S o c p cu < cd w • •n o • hi cu CO b cu a C b tn W >. 00 •* CU ^ a. *. iH «. r» >l «. p *. ■Ml cu •. u in CU CU 0^ cu >i in >i C 43 u Q) Cn g X rH rH rH en 1H CU P cu >i CP g ■H •rl n ^ in O >1 CU -H -H (0 id cu CU cu o u M M •rl pq m PQ PQ PQ PQ PQ PQ PQ PQ PQ rH I rH I CN i cO VO CN I < VO U id cu rH >H o rH rl id P U c W •r) u fa >1 p • • •H in rH cu id o 3 C CM id C rH •H cd &H p c P cu 3 § cu g Sh u •H cu > > c o W CJ T3 C id tn P in O U P c cu p cd 3 c o •rl p 3 in cu u 3 P •H TJ C CU ft X w A-152 o w £ ft o w < G O •H +J .-^ 3 T3 rH 0) rH 3 C P-l ■H -P M G •H < u — rH rd CO •H 3 5h to P c; co CD 3 u T3 C CD M .c P nj 0J 14-1 P o O QJ 3 M A3 0) a) CO 3 pa cd CD <* SJ 1 Ol CO • S en w £ g D CO cu u p re rH 5H o> -p «-' o 5-i rH CU CU 0) 1 (C rd Cn CD & X CO •H = a, A id p •H 5-i O >, B 5h u ft > 0> o e H ft p <4H TS CD r- ^ 13 to o •H rH < h- r~ P U CO C U rH g id CT> en C ^ id sC O •H * Sh rH rH rH t) •H i rH PS G w O C u 0) rd ■ 5h ft ft rH S n3 r2 C CU U •H X s S c CU 4-1 m •H hi I O O rd 4- 1 rH O rH rH 5-) 10 O rH peS U g 3 ». ^ *. -H rH rd rd 4-> CO ■N CU H h. W CU rH c C u CO O rH 3 3 a 01 c a OJ u - £ CU rH o o CO 5H -H c C o en X! CO CU Eh Si p CO G -H P O c c u -H -p Qi p CU CO = EH ft r-1 5 rd g fft C rd •H rd e g 6 3 3 ro id m Si ,e rH o m oa u U o U u U o u u u CN n rH I < >1 P •H rH rd rd P C QJ •H U c 3 o u p c CU e CO CO QJ CO CO < U ■H s o c o u w -0 G rd C O •H P rd rH rd > O CO CM c o •H +J rH rH o ft m o p o rd e H U •H e o G O o w CU Si Eh CD rH I ro rH I < CN I CD P Si CJ> •H w 01 En I >i p •H rH rd O) C O rH •H u G 3 o U 0) Si p o p 5h O 0a 5} ft p> •H rH rd 3 CX o M ■H > C W O 5H •H > C w A-153 o w — - H U • < o cm s a % 3 rs — - i +j in -H O rH (0 CO 3 P OJ U fd fd g P H c CD O g -H g o c o u 0) o rj fd g oo 1 3 >1 £1 rH •H rH U fd +J P CO (!) -H TI Q CD Cm CD ,G Cn 4J C •H C O o a fd +J c u •H fd Cm a e IW H CD cu -G g Eh o c • • H O rH m o p. p c c -H u p a o •H P H rH O CU p o CO CD in 3 +J rH 03 T3 G CD CmT3 W fd 0) Cn (U CO u o hh CO CO CD C ■H CO 3 PQ >i rQ ^4 cn c CD o3 in P 3 Cm P CD -H - Cn Tl • Tl C H 0) 0» o. p ' s X • fd - J P CO -H C >t ft 03 P cO CD 03 U g U = CD P U UD "!•' i> r- CO CO Cxi CO KT CO CT\ ^ CO in ■SJ 1 cn cn CN CM ro m CM ro CO CN ro "sT ro r-l H rH rH r-l rH 1 rH 1 I rH I 1 rH rH 1 rH 1 rH 1 II i 1 1 1 O CTi 1 < CN CM CN 1 < 1 rU II 1 1 1 1 I I 1 I 1 rtj 1 1 1 1 1 < 1 1 1 1 1 < 1 1 i 1 1 < I < o rH i 1 1 < CO CO I < rH CN 1 < 1 < i 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 < ■<* rH < CN l Co 1 < 1 1 1 1 c o g •H 3 rH c P 03 CD o 3 = ■g rH •H rH m rH P f-i r- CD •H 3 o cn T3 g rH Cm rH •H CD p c >i rH O CD Tl 5 u CD O CM P CD T5 c CO C • CO •H CD U oj C J CD CO Cn CD S 03 g CD < P U <-\ >i 19 u 03 o H TS P CD » p Cm r- a» P P rH Sh >i u Cn u p m "HH <7\ HH P - u rH 3 CD rH rH O o rH CD P c CD CD P jC c -Q O CD Qa fd P c CD XI XI 03 p 03 Q CD Cn CD p p p •^ p (0 CD P O o a a 2 « O Sh Cm" C CO CO rH CO 5 S 03 « OS O CD o O CD W <** *. •^ «* CD i u u u u * P V •. N <* C C CO U •H c p P 03 «. 03 03 P > m fd fd e (U CD c CD 3£ CO C C a> § g g rH «* •rlfi £1 o XI -H ■H ■H CO UH UH Cn cn c Eh CJ Eh > Cm Cm g > rH U 3 -O o > 03 CD CD CD CD o O fd u G Q Q Q a Q p a Q a w w A-154 o B 3 o M < O 3 O a w w p. w u Pd p o to > o Eh ,_, u T3 •H 0) e 3 C c ■H o P u C w o u to ' — +J M >1 u Tl c C 0) (0 tn < P d) c +J id •H s p c 0J (d -p 0) rH u U ft IH H to P p c CO d) g u CD p 42 -P Eh kO & ■=3" CN rH 1 rH ■ 1 < 1 < "sT ^ H I 1 1 < 1 r- rH m u X3 en c •H id en >i to ■H CO rd (U a 0) > o •H •H P e 0) c l|H o M-l o w w T3 P rd CJi| to T3 (1) en O Ck cf p di 0) 42 P HH O c o •P P (0 rH (d > w o ■H e o c o o w w ip o p u rH O P d) P 42 c ■P u C •H c CO ■H -P P G 3 <4H 0) O -P CO P U G rrj O Ch rl U •H •P -P e fd h c & u c 42 d) P E O P p •p P > P f2 w a, p < 3 p r-i •• 3 E u fd •H p P Cr« CT> O < P ft 12 O rH fd d> P 0) C •P 0) P E ■H d a p •H o > c % w CQ LI in ro m 7 1 V I i i 1 < I I i i I I r- en rH ». P d) P fd p 5 W >^ P P CO C H fd Ph A-155 - ^c W • o o < 2 (X W Q r-1 9 % E-" M-l O rd (1) M w u ^ PS C D O O -H to (A \ CO PS •H o g EC £ Eh o D u < 0) 13 tO cO U rl -H *% rH C rO O U U CU W 13 0) Cm < c -H -p (0 -p in CU CO C r0 !h E-> -P £ tn •H cu • M Cm Cm C m I rO •* g !h g CD (U 13 rH C ■H 0) Q cO rH d) 13 5 a; Eh CD & -P c •rH 4-> rO rH 3 tj> 0> PS 14-1 O 10 -P to o u cO = •H 10 O rO to CD Eh g in LO LD LD LD CO m 0> ID CTi in CTt cr> CM V£> co ro ro ro CO ro CO (M ro CN ro CM CN ro CO rH ■ 1 •-i rH 1 rH 1 rH 1 ■ rH 1 rH rH <-i rH rH 1 r-i rH I 1 < i I I I 1 < rH rH 1 <: r- ro <* CN i ft M M H rH rH f0 r) s • 1 <: i i i i 1 < rH rH i < ro 1 1 13 C cO C c Sh a) 1 < 1 I 1 1 1 < 1 1 1 1 c 6 U 0) > 1 < rH CO 1 < CO CM O CN 1 < to •H C ro 1 < 1 1 1 1 l 2 1 k 2 q • C 3 CU a> ■P x 2 rC o W CU U o u d) b C ^ to in > fc , Xi Q 13 13 cO • OS q b s > 13 < c 3 fc CO H C cO 13 H 13 • • • . 13 >i «. f0 to O u to u 6 cO SE EC 0) & O rH ^3 to CU 13 -p >i >i CO >1 p r0 r^) tO -p U m H >H S rH • n -P <-{ ■P CU r0 CO PS CU CD 3: S PS to Sh x: * * • % CU PS r-i «. -P 13 13 to H Mi •rl -H o •H -p an rO to to cO cO 13 < «*. X) l-D >! X M to c •. a M r-\ <-i rH O ■». Vl to to >1 to a o ^ u a co C -P 13 ro *. & S U •s * to (0 *. •H c c cO •H c m -d o o cO CU CU g c K CO ^ - 1 rH CU 13 y-t XI A KH xi ■s Xi CU CU 13 P f-^ rH Q O •H H 3 CO CO cO M > ■H C VJ r-i rH ■P ft rl O o U !H u r0 CO rO CU d) •H •r\ •H a< Cm o a O O o EC EC EC EC EC EC EC EC EC H to c o •rl •P g CO O N U -H Xi r4 -H - -p cu to 0) -P 13 H-» C ■H (0 -P o u o u •H B c o u w CN rH I < MH O c o •H -p rO rj> CU PS -P C CU u CU > o o MM O 10 -P to to CU o u u tp re cu o x CJ Eh 01 CN rH I <; 4-' o r) •H > c H m o -p o rd O •H c o o tq cu Eh to c o •H -P CO rH Cn CU PS A-156 o S 2 O H EH < EH o < - B w • o o rt! a a, w P PI 1 Eh vo en en ■X) vo 01 en vO x) cn VO r* o o r~ ro CM CM co CO CM CM CO CO CM CO CM CO CO CM 1 rH 1 rH 1 rH 1 rH 1 rH 1 rH ■ rH 1 rH 1 rH rH rH 1 rH rH r-t 1 < 1 1 1 1 1 I i i i I < 1 1 1 1 u o> 1 rt! 00 I «c 03 CN rH CM 1 < 1 < 1 1 1 I 1 < 1 1 1 1 1 < 1 1 1 1 1 g 0) Cu ai 1 o c o u Id 0> £ >1 MH c D Xi b o> • • < £ A u Cn a c p CQ 5 T) p •H • a) «H id •B o> C c ^ p P M rH s < & p > 0> , cu U nrj P cd 3 MH P a) 0) P rH W 3 CD c o> ^ id o c • CU • pc; ** ■rl w ■« rH M •* •. «. ■* *. J a >i CO C U 3 c P. a «. ai «. >d «. «. •H CI) fd -h 3 a) id C CO rd c «. •. 0) c > ^ Xi •0 < b CP rH g •H 0) M o 01 0) C ■H rH a) 0) o > > > u o> a> rH a s It? cd id 0) 0) cd b w £ « s 2 rH i-l rH J PI a < VO CM crj SH 0) 0) 0) ■C p CO CO 0) c 0) > •H P o g 0) g m o m u w JH cu •H -d P ■H rd CO M 1 Cn p u M Oi £ Q* w 0) « rH rO U • • 0) c T3 o 0) •rl Cm p C id CO U Oi T3 !H O tJi c •H P 0) J* !H cd vO VO r~- CO ro CM rH '-t rH I <: 1 1 < ■-i rH | 1 < 1 1 " 1 1 T CO CO CM 1 1 1 ^ 1 1 ^ — , •nT CO 0) ge c CO a >o c cd CO * p • w u S o CO ft rH rd ft B 3 m CO Ph Eh 0) •* >1 w •H O S Sh > rd cu < U o U fd U S S VO rH I rH I CO CM I < vO -a c rd >1 >i QJ P > 0) lH ip 3 rd CO C/l rH o rH cu •H >i K 1 rH 3t ft fd !H w O u c g •H rH p rd c 3 s C g a •p CQ a> fl > P c •^r H A-157 o O s <; o ft M Eh < Eh O 2 O 3 IX) o 0) > CO w rH u rH « •H D ~ tc O "0 I CO •H dJ >H Cm CD U rd M-) U 3 a) to rH rd cr> •H w p = (C id c g rH O 3 -H 43 tn -P Eh Pi C O •H •P rd P O & CO G CO o >1 c rd i O U g M a) . Pi c .2 - o rH r^ rH O s H P M M a) 0) XI P rH Pi rd S •. rH » 3 •H rd o P* >1 p CD m rd CO Xt O 8 p a o CO P = sue id ci o CO IW -H IH P - W rd C H fd d) 3 e x: tn N Eh d) P = Pi rH d) Ph CO C P o -H P o 0) p o M ft SH CD tn 3 !h Q CO CN G vD O CTi U rH i U ♦ G EC CD EC >> G Ik O G CO •H !^ rV! d) CO P CD CD Ph 0< A-158 w w u ft 8 to o a! CO n l id u ft a) cr ft C a) o ft o c o g 4-1 O ca ■p to o u 13 H H rd (d X -H o o o o •H ■p co rd » a) CD H c = CO o ft c o •H -P Iti rH Cn CD ft c o ■H p c o •H P rd rH Cn CD ft u •H B c o u w IP, o to Q) •H O 0) CO ft & co \£) U O 4h a) to Cn to 13 CD CD C ■H -H P to 3 3 ft ft • >i iA XI >i to M CD U •P 13 -H C 13 id fd CD = tn CD cn CD 13 •P CD 10 C fd c 5 fd i-H 13 ft •H rH T) O C to fd 13 in rd cn u » CD -P ■P C (d CD - -p U rd 2 1 «> CO o CO o ro [-* r- cn CO r- <*< «tf ro co m ro cn n cn CO co rH I rH 1 rH 1 rH I rH I rH 1 f r-\ rH ■ rH 11 rH r-{ ■ 1 1 < I 1 < 1 < CM 1 < 1 II < < cn i < 00 II < S 1 < 1 < 3 to n CD rd rd • M r« rH E-t g U cn ■P c

iH 13 rH •H C H -H c • • to •* 13 fd CD rd e> rH • C U O r< rd T3 »D CD Q • • £ C ft 13 v l"3 ft id P • • rd TJ X c • • •H CD t to 2 C ft (d & b x 0) rH to H rd ft c rH *. -p P CD Ej H -P ■a -s H U 4 W Ik •* fD Q Q ft *. •H CD ft CD 13 TJ b ft ft +j ■p +J •o h. <*. u !h ^ o rd fd » CD rd C CD fd •^ Hi * CD r-t PS rH U U ■H X ft X X C rH X CD ft CD ^ ft ft p ■P G ft CD Cn a to CD CD •rH •H i rd 2: O rH rH td • u to T3 • CD < to U CD •H C A3 rd b rH fd •> 5 • rd a S3 r-i , rH < CD to a to rd 3 •H ft rH rH * •H c rH to T3 ft C 6 rd X Eh n CD P rd £ C rd CD rH u MH O P CO o u CD a o •H P u T3 o U ft CD a CD rH J^ P W 13 C rd A-159 cm o S3 w w o 8 CO o Eh T3 C fO «. T) >i 0) r^ oo ro ro <* n ro ro 00 00 ro CM ro (N ro OJ (N CN CN rH rH rH t-i rH <-i rH rH ■ •-i rH I rH 1 rH ■ rH rH i 1 <-\ rH 1 rH 1 1 1 » 1 •» - i 1 1 1 1 1 1 •■ 1 1 1 1 1 1 ^-^ ^^ . — * ^— n ro ro KD CN rH tO C -H P c •H CJi U •H CO <4H O ■P CO C •H 4-> tO rH c •H -P >1 CU rH CU p >H tO u CU 3 z CO = fa to -H O rH CU 04 CU u CD Pi Oi CU to 4-> CU c n v c H o £ CU u x: p tf CO 3 -H !h -H 0) U Eh X! c -p c to P | p •P H CU p u to tO •H p c -o p c CU r-{ >H < o •• -o (1) c 2 CU rT U 2 CD u iH ■P c O tO M p & o> ■4-) rH (0 • c tO •H CU c o CU C o c Xi g CU M G > M 4-> >1 « H !H P CO CU 1 p CM o •H o CU > (0 rH tO P P CU c CU -o tp u c T3 ■P 8 3 c c C ^ CU c; u . CU CU CU tO MH o> CU (1) >1 4-> U P P fO CU hH > >i c8 1 P 10 rH 3 MH Si ■H E p 2 2 fO MH c •H rH u • u 13 tP to o tO rJ O a. o P h3 tO 0) c ^ p Oi rH CU u g •H P u ^ M TI : > (0 K to CU c MH > •H P p o tO &> rH • M C Cm 2 > = •H C > u C 3 u u u CU ffi 3 (0 •iH o 1 4-> u to to P H O c c CU rH CU (0 s X 4-1 c £ 10 (0 w X A B rH *. ta XI x; rH CO to % C CU X 0) S Oi Oi o O CU CU 0) c o 3 * to c CO CU P z Oi ^ c •H c c c rD iH u CU p p c CU •H fO g CU o to P c cn •H CU -H -P ■<-i -H fO (0 <0 to tO >1 p s fn 3 c •H CU c )H c ffi Z to 10 Ba to CU (1) £Q T3 O U H V Q p CO CO rH 3 n u rH CO > 3 fl Eh MH c CU MH ■H 04 td < Cm CU CU CU CQ -o = P4 PQ = K E = o = tf CO CO CO • CO tO C O rH tO to CU CU Eh D 6 D 6 > > £ £ s A-160 u H w &4 a u o Cn s w %l o u U < o Cn cu M PQ § CQ % in U (1) oi J 0) c c c c a •P -H >H c C> JJ JJ «s c o <0 6 0) 0) 6 TJ ■n ■ p •a •» -p U-J 01 tn to O .-1 ^ C H 11 A 10 o 10 -H CJ TJ o •^ •h U 13 a •a c <4H 10 Eh O co rH O TJ Ifl u O c x: P o s 4J 0) JJ c H M Eh U W J J o u Pi o c Pm o •H CO 4-1 p o tn H iH c •H JJ Eh c W o 3 g H EH < -a tn x o o> U jj C -P w a> i CO < cn O cd 04 3 < O < u -a c to 10 Cn-H C O ■H 0) jj a, c CO •3 O 13 o c O 10 < tn tn £ m O 0) >i C JH o> tn to < C/J < 0> •P- CU 0) XI tn io -h men ■p (0 -P £ tn

jj u O (0 o S -a a< io o> e p p jj -p. o en io jj OHfl o h V C (I Cu u (0 tn T3 3 < o •o c <0 10 c u 01 JJ c P CD 3 O a c £ .. (0 iO O JJ l-\ (0 a "O P 1-1 o JJ 13 tn 3 -H JJ a tn o tn 5 c o tn jj 0) u cu -a 3 < § 13 C <0 ■0 c 1-1 cu JJ c (0 tr>-H 0> c u c •P CU •H jj a, JJ c c/j c 3 3 O 13 O O C o O (0 o < tn < tn 1) tn >i 6 in >. e o o> > o cu C JJ ^H C JJ cu tn <0 D tn cn > c C> >! < w < < 0j « •» >i tn ai a> > c u -H 3 u m to en a> cu -H ■ £ -a c JJ u tn cu tn E en •w "O C tn a 3 JJ cn u 0) a CO JJ c 01 O -a C o E iO e -H •a Cj tn <0 -1 JJ u E cu JJ « cnM •H JJ 10 i-H 10 o T3 c M 3 C u >, •H 10 tn m JJ tn Cn O Cu u Ul kj E jj 0) lJJ 3 u O tn c i-i 10 T3 10 Ul UJ cn U O •H JJ cn U-l U •H rH O U e c O cu 01 3 •o Vj U TJ 0) u a, X3 Cn c c cu O «-i < e cu tn o 3 0) 10 JJ SI jj t/j OC •H > o JJ o >4 u «-l tn jj -a 0) a> C U l-l iO <0 T3 JJ jj 10 -H w Qj 4) O a u C 0) c M tn > E MJ JJ E 13 io tn 10 CU .Q « E-- C C 10 M T3 U-l l-l a, 3 JJ U U <-! 0) JJ Uh U O W 10 > -a Cn to (0 •H o c i to 0) cn > c M. -H 3 P. to 01 10 cu -x: -a 01 cu oi jj ^H 10 10 l-i U JJ l-l 01 cu •h cn H4J C r0 (0 -H O n W •H JJ CU P 01 CU E Cn (0 CU tn E m >i o> > u 3 W3 Cn c -H JJ P o a 01 cs o 0) u -rJ a oi .- >1 01 Q> Cn > C P -H 3 U 01 to io cu CU -H — .C "O 10 3 JJ CU JJ 10 > 01 -a -h JJ Cn rtflC (0 M -H U JJ P -H 01 01 P -H CU X M CU jj M-l 0) > O "P. i-H O XJ •H £ >p a) Cu JJ OI Cn E -O -H JJ p JJ ai o o o s ■rj -W ~-H Cn C O x: « T3 3 JJ 13 a JJ 01 JJ 3 O 1 •w 3 p — p oi j<; io 10 OI -a 03 O E Ofl P 3 > 0) «-l CU O 10 JJ O oi c oi x: >i < 13 u o io -a o > O 0) O OJ JJ 10 o o •H •H 01 > JJ C P jj x: JJ JJ 01 P P 10 CU JJ C O JJ 10 U O 3 o -< •o c CU -H CU oi p m 01 c o r-t «W g —K M-J O >1-p. Oi o •-I -H 14-1 p 10 J^ 0) ^H n c x 0.1-1 Oi o x: jj Cn C 0) Id CO JJ > Z JJ o < 10 M £ Cn C -i-l JJ c 3 O u o < Cn C 01 •H E JJ a m jj -H 01 X >i u w JJ c 01 10 o u o 01 s CU s u 3 JJ 01 M 3 1 13 U C P u o cu a, JJ CO o X! JJ XI 10 c o • -O 01 o> jj ^n jj a cu C 10 "O cu a o oi e E CU -H p -t C O (0 sign JJ O JJ 01 C 01 O O 3 U O 13 0) c cn -h C ^H •^ rH P JJ 3 O 13 «-l E O •H CU iH jj x: E 01 v n •o Oi c c (0 E C" P C 0) iO rlJg >. OI U-l 13 IP •H O P CU CU P OJ > iO 03 3 » 01 tn JJ 0) c to x: •HOP JJ o o x: CU 0) CP <-H 01 3 f-t oi o o x: p o jj x; jj

2 are, and how the levels can be reduced. Each of these issues can be addressed as a separate subject and can be a source of enormous controversy. It is not, however, the purpose of this paper to deal directly with the three issues just outlined: • Is there a need for government intervention? • If so, at what level or point would the costs exceed the benefits? • What are the primary causes of the problem? Rather, our attention is focused on the question that follows once these issues have been resolved and some form of government intervention is planned: • How should the government intervene? Though this final question can be separated from, it is not unrelated to, the first three. Thus, to some extent, we will be occupied with the totality of the problem. 1.1 FOCUSING ON ALTERNATIVES Although perhaps a misconception, it appears that much of the controversy which surrounds the question of how should the government intervene, stems from two sources. First, people have honest differences of opinion as to how effective certain alternatives will be in achieving a given objective and second, there are significant differences in interpretation as to what is meant when concerned individuals discuss these alternatives. These differences of opinion and interpretations are compounded by the fact that there have been few applications or case studies of the use of alternatives to regulation. A selected review of the literature confirms this fact. Appended to this report is an annotated bibliography on a selected list of some of the more important works in this field. Several observations are justified on the basis of this review. First, the vast majority of these studies are highly theoretical. Little reference to empirical evidence or experience was made. The conclusions of these studies, therefore, could be best described as conjectural, which, while providing a lively debate and a rich literature, do not resolve the central question of experience with, and prospects for, the use of alternatives to regulation. The exceptions to the above statement are experiences in the Ruhr Valley with effluent charges and various incentive schemes to encourage the use of disposable containers and/or to encourage recycling. The Ruhr Valley experience, while C-15 interesting, is not directly applicable to the U.S. Between the U.S. and Germany there are significant differences in the degree of direct government/ industry cooperation and also extreme differences in the level of pollution control being sought. Additionally, application of a fee system to a portion of a small river system is quite different — simpler — than application to the entirety of a large river system. For an effluent charge scheme to be effective in the U.S., the charge rate would have to be substantially higher and, therefore, have the potential for creating significantly greater first and second order impacts. These impacts would have to be studied in-depth before proceeding with the application of an effluent charge approach in the United States or generalizing from the Ruhr Valley experience. Generalizing from the incentives systems which have been used is difficult and risky. For example, experience from the use of systems which discourage the use of disposable containers and encourage recycling can be misleading. These are areas where an incentive market mechanism is already in place to deal with the situation and where the application has been usually on a limited scale. Given that the creation and long-term viability of a market is critical to the use of market-type incentive systems, it is not clear, therefore, what insight they provide to more general use of alternatives to regulation. Second, is that the focus of the literature is narrow relative to the range of issues where government intervention is considered or advocated. The literature deals in-depth with emission charges and effluent fees but is severely lacking in discussions of incentive or informational approaches to questions of human health and safety, and the pragmatic balancing of risks, costs and benefits. The lack of studies in these areas limits the usefulness of a full-scale review of the literature when considering alternatives to regulation over the full range of government activities. Third, most of the studies focus on questions of economic efficiency. While economic efficiency is important, it is not the sole criterion with which to judge the efficacy of using approaches other than direct regulations. As stated by Russell Train, previous Administrator of the Environmental Protection Agency, in response to a question on the use of emission charges as a substitute for direct regulation, "...to substitute emission charges for regulations at this point would subvert the very significant progress we are making in dealing with our urgent environmental problems . It would be quite disruptive to make such a change until the initial objectives of the new environmental legislation of this decade are achieved." Whether this statement is true is not the issue. The fact is, that the use of emission charges was being rejected on the basis of a much different set of criteria. While economic efficiency is an important principle, other factors, such as effectiveness, equity, and political feasibility, must also be considered. Finally, while the literature may have its shortcomings, it cannot be dismissed. By reviewing the literature it is possible to construct a general framework within which the subject of alternatives to regulation can be constructively *„ , The Economxc Impact of Environmental Regulations," Hearings before the Joint Economic Committee, November 19, 21, and 22, 1974, page 191. C-16 discussed. While people may disagree with the definitions presented in this paper, the discussion in the following sections attempts to establish a framework and a common starting point for sorting out substantive versus definitional differences of opinion. 1.2 ORGANIZATION OF THE PAPER Section 2 discusses the alternative approaches or options available to the government. Within each of the generic classifications mentioned above, several options — such as performance standards, permits, taxes, or subsidies — are discussed. The objective of this section is simply to provide some definitions which can give focus to discussions of alternatives . It should be noted from the outset, however, that no attempt has been made to define all the possible options. The list in practice would be almost infinite since it is shaped directly by each situation in which government intervention is deemed necessary. Section 3 attempts to define criteria which can be used to evaluate the use of particular alternatives. These criteria were designed to be applicable across broad categories. However, this is not to say that all the advantages or disadvantages of a given alternative in each particular situation can be identified solely from these criteria. Likewise, the definitions given will not, in all likelihood, be universally acceptable, but may, nonetheless, serve as useful reference points for discussion. Section 4 discusses how alternative approaches might be used and how the tradeoffs could be considered in light of the criteria presented in Section 2 . This section covers a number of key issues and examples that highlight the differences between the alternatives. Section 5 is a summary. Although we have tried to avoid a dogmatic approach, certain observations were unavoidable. These are presented as general guides for discussion rather than as definitive statements. Indeed, this paper will have been successful if, as a result of the background information and the analytical framework provided, readers are stimulated in formulating different and possibly innovative observations on this subject. C-17 2. ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES The number of approaches that the government may take is large , but can be reduced to just three if grouped into broad classes. These classes are regulatory approaches, incentive or market-based approaches, and informational approaches. The approaches also may be combined into a fourth class — mixed approaches . In the abstract, each of these approaches can be considered variations on a behavioral modification theme. Each operates by causing some change in the behavior of a target population — regulation, by prohibiting some action via (usually) a legal penalty; economic incentive, by raising or lowering the perceived cost of the action to the affected party; and information provision, by improving the information base which shapes behavior. In application, of course, the alternative forms of intervention differ substantially. Likewise, the relative effectiveness in achieving the desired result is likely to vary widely. Each kind of approach has many variants. Table 1 lists the major variants for each approach. These will be discussed in this section. This section only lays out the basics of each approach and variant. No critique is presented here. 2.1 REGULATORY APPROACHES The major variants of regulatory approaches are performance standards , specification standards, and case-by-case permits or standards. 2.1.1 Performance Standards Performance standards are regulations that require certain results or outcomes . For example, new sources of pollution are often issued performance standards that require them to emit no more than X grams per horsepower -hour or Y tons per year of pollutants into the environment. Performance standards may be set with regard to the feasible or practical technologies that may allow them to be met, but, at least in theory, do not require that specific technologies be used for compliance. 2.1.2 Specification Standards Specification standards are regulations that require certain technologies or practices, leaving the results or outcomes flexible. For example, workplaces have often been issued specification standards requiring that hand railings be installed. The intention is to cut down on accidents but accidents are not directly regulated by the standards. 2.1.3 Case-by-Case Permits or Standards Whereas regulations are frequently set on a uniform basis for a region or industry, they may also be set on an individual case-by-case basis. In this manner, specific conditions are taken into account. For example, municipalities * Nichols and Zeckhauser, op . cit . , page 49. C-18 TABLE 1 ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES AND THEIR MAJOR VARIANTS • Regulatory Approaches Performance standards - Specification standards - Case-by-case standards or permits • Incentive Approaches Taxes (user charges, fees) - Subsidies Liability measures • Informational Approaches Disclosure Education Jawboning • Mixed Approaches - Marketable permits Surcharges Combinations of the above or others C-19 are sometimes issued permits allowing them to dump only certain quantities per year of solid waste into bodies of water. If binding, the permits force the municipalities to deal with extra wastes through some other means (such as recycling, burning, or on-land disposal) . Standards may also be set on a case-by-case basis, in theory. 2.1.4 Other Regulations Regulations have numerous forms and dimensions. Some deal with information reporting and recordkeeping, others with structures for setting rates for customers (to deal with pecuniary externalities such as the need for greater investments by utility companies to accommodate peak-load demand) , others with yet different problems. Regulations may also differ in terms of their penalties for noncompliance, the frequency of their monitoring and inspection, and the procedures by which they are set. Some may be intended for strict enforcement, others for use only if violations are extreme . 2.2 INCENTIVE OR MARKET-BASED APPROACHES The major variants for incentive or market-based approaches are taxes, subsidies, and liability measures. The feature in common to all incentive approaches is that they act in a market-like manner and work with the market to alter the total costs or benefits of actions for firms or the public . 2.2.1 Taxes or User Charges In the case of social externalities , the imposition of costs upon the public is like the consumption of a public resource and thus may be met with a user charge, fee, or tax. Ideally, the tax would reflect the damage to the public. If the tax on an action is greater than the costs of its avoidance, then the tax will motivate firms or the public to stop the action that is imposing the social externality. If the costs of avoiding an action were greater than the tax, however, the firms or public would tend to pay the tax and continue the action. This need not be undesirable if the tax reflected the costs of the action to society. For example, there are some discharges into the environment that save the public money overall or some accidents that would be avoidable only at tremendous expense. A tax may be difficult to envision for some situations, yet theoretically a tax might be designed. For instance, makers of consumer products could be taxed for each accident that occurs from defects in the product. Employers could be taxed for each accident on their premises caused by unsafe condi- tions. The tax would be both an incentive to improve safety and a source of revenue which might possibly compensate the victims. "U.S. Files Pollution, Ocean-Dumping Suits Against Philadelphia," Wall Street Journal , May 25, 1978. Nichols and Zeckhauser, op . cit . , pages 65-67. C-20 2.2.2 Subsidies Subsidies work in the opposite direction from taxes or charges . By making an activity less expensive, they promote its adoption. Hence, a subsidy for adopting a less polluting technology may lead to a reduction in pollution. A subsidy for worker training may improve job safety. Subsidies typically are paid from general revenues and are thus paid by the public. This differs from the tax approach, which assesses a charge for a specific action. 2.2.3 Liability Measures Matters of social externalities or imperfect information tend to be problems traditionally known as tort liability matters when handled through courts . One party is in effect seeking to avoid or recover damages inflicted by the actions of another . There are three main mechanisms that come under the heading of liability measures . Law suits are one means of dealing with these problems. To the extent that better or cheaper access to legal proceedings was provided to the public, this measure would tend to lessen some health, safety, or environmental problems. Legal clinics , class action suits , and other measures may improve the public ability to avoid or recover damages. Compensation funds may be required by the government to set up a pool or fund from which victims can be compensated for bodily injury or property damage. Workmen's compensation is one example. Employers pay into a fund that is used to compensate employees who have been injured on the job. To the extent that such funds are experience-rated, i.e., payments are linked to the actual experience of the firms in safety or pollution, they increase the liability or accountability of the firms to any members of the public that they harm. Insurance plans are basically a means of pooling risk but can also have an impact on the apportionment of liability and, thus, on the incentives for avoiding injuries or claims. If premiums paid reflect experience, insurance may function with little distortion of liability. If premiums are uniform, insurance plans may lead to distortions or lack of liability for costs generated by firms or the public. This would happen since damages and claims would have no tie to the costs to individuals, only to costs in aggregate. Naturally, other considerations are involved in insurance — notably, the desire to increase the security of the public, which is not the same as internalizing costs or risks. 2.3 INFORMATIONAL APPROACHES Informational approaches include measures that encourage better disclosure the public, educate the public on facts or risks, or seek to persuade firms or the public to change their behavior. The common feature of all informational approaches is that they work solely through information and allow the public to make choices with existing costs and benefits unchanged. The reaction of the *Nichols and Zeckhauser, op . cit . , pages 65-67. **Ibid. , pages 65-67 C-21 public, acting through demand and the price mechanisms, will in turn create incentives or disincentives for actions by firms or may directly represent the actions sought by policies. 2.3.1 Disclosure A disclosure approach would require (or provide an incentive for) firms to disclose the characteristics of their products or impacts of their environ- mental policies more fully. Existing advertising by firms tends to be short and catchy, rather than fully informative on technical details. Moreover, if a firm has a poor record on product safety or the environment, it may be the least likely to disclose its record voluntarily. In other cases, disclosure may be common but not in comparable terms to allow consumer judgments. The philosophy behind disclosure measures is that fully informed individuals are able to make better decisions for themselves than uninformed individuals. This will help reduce cases of hazards that were assumed involuntarily. 2.3.2 Education Educational measures go beyond disclosure to seek to interpret information for the public, bring it more directly to the public's attention, or prehaps in some cases even try to persuade the public to take a different assessment of its own welfare. In some cases it may be necessary to educate the public in order for a disclosure to be meaningful. For example, a basic public under- standing of nutrition is essential if disclosure of the nutritive content of a product is to be of value. Warnings of various kinds are ways to increase awareness of the importance of safety criteria in making choices. Hints and lessons may also be included, as when ways to lessen risks during household fires are broadcast over the media as public service announcements. 2.3.3 Jawboning Jawboning is a term that has been coined to denote efforts by the government to persuade the public to take some action. It has received much attention in relation to inflation and price increases, when the government has requested unions or firms to restrain wage or price increases . As applied to social externalities or imperfect information, jawboning involves government requests for firms to stop polluting or to improve safety . The requests are for voluntary action but may entail an implicit threat that if compliance is not soom forth- coming a measure such as regulation or litigation may be taken. Jawboning sometimes involves consent decrees — agreements by members of the public to stop an action without admission or guilt, liability, or wrongdoing. 2.4 MIXED APPROACHES Mixed approaches involve combinations of the above or other approaches . Aside from the possibility of mixing any combination of approaches in a package , these approaches include marketable permits and tax surcharges . Kelman, Steven, "Regulation by the Numbers — A Report on the Consumer Product Safety Commission," The Public Interest, Summer, 1974. C-22 2.4.1 Marketable Permits A marketable permit is a device that allows a firm or person to continue an activity but also to have the opportunity to sell that right to another firm or person. By issuing a limited number of permits, an authority can thus establish a ceiling on the amount of activity allowed, e.g., pollution in a basin or a number of accidents. By allowing such permits to be marketable, the authority can avoid situations where some firms have to comply at great costs while others comply but could have reduced emissions or hazards even further at less cost. The marketability allows flexibility within a context of the fixed aggregate permitted levels. Selling permits may also raise revenues for the government. 2.4.2 Tax Surcharge In light of the likelihood that less than 100 percent of emissions or hazards will be eliminated when a tax approach is used , a tax surcharge system may be adopted. This approach allows a specified level of activity at no charge and imposes a surcharge for all activity beyond the set level. For example, firms would be allowed to emit a certain amount of pollution each year without charge. Any emissions beyond this amount would be subject to a tax. Thus, a tax incentive would be combined with a regulatory approach. There would be a tax disincentive to continue polluting but no tax on firms that reduced pollution to acceptable levels . C-23 3 . CRITERIA Direct regulation has been criticized from every conceivable standpoint. Regulators find themselves in a buffer zone between the people they are attempting to protect and those that they are seeking to control. Within these buffer zones they are subjected to additional pressures from other regulatory agencies, from the legislators who drafted the implementing legislation, from the executive branches of government which will be held accountable, and indeed, from individuals within the agency itself who hold differing points of view. Criticism, however, must be expected. As stated by David Harrigan, a commissioner with the Connecticut Public Utilities Control Authority, "If you are the buffer you are going to be buffeted." This will always be the case in situations where someone stands to gain and someone stands to lose. Problems that appear to require regulatory solutions are almost always of this nature, involving instant confrontations in which the regulator's only shield is objectivity. Criticism does not necessarily have to have a negative connotation. By studying the major areas of criticism we can begin to identify common problems. These problems, in turn, can be used to establish criteria for evaluating both the use of, and alternatives to, regulations. The most common forms of criticism fall into three major categories: • Effectiveness • Efficiency • Equity These categories in turn contain several subcriteria which may, or may not, be important in specific situations. Also intertwined throughout the entire problem is the question of political feasibility. All four of these areas are deserving of separate treatment. 3.1 EFFECTIVENESS Effectiveness involves the question of whether the means by which the government chooses to intervene will accomplish the objective it was designed to serve. More specifically, effectiveness normally encompasses the concepts of administrative feasibility and enforceability. Being the most direct form of government intervention, regulation is often presumed to be the most effective means to achieve a given objective. This, however, is not necessarily the case. On the administrative side, direct regulation often suffers from both resource and informational constraints. Resource constraints involve questions of whether adequate staff is available "State Utility Regulators Find Job is "Turbulent* As Consumers Battle Companies Over Rate Hikes , " Wall Street Journal. C-24 to administer the program or whether the mix of skilled professionals is consistent with the requirement. Informational considerations involve whether the causes of the problem can be adequately identified, and, once identified, whether the control technique can be adequately specified to insure attainment. Too often these constraints are either ignored or the regulations are specifically designed to overcome these limitations. If these constraints are ignored it is unlikely that the objective will be achieved. If these limitations are treated explicitly in the design of the regulation, there is an excellent chance that the regulations will require overcontrol. In either event, significant waste and inefficiency can result. Criticism of effectiveness usually focuses on this waste and inefficiency. Enforcement is also essential to the effectiveness of an approach. Even if a regulation is administratively feasible it is not necessarily enforceable. Enforcement involves two issues: (1) can a violation be detected, and (2) can the source be forced to comply in the absence of judicial proceedings. For example, it may be administratively feasible to impose a unit charge on a form of pollution, but it may not be feasible to detect violations and thereby assess charges because of a lack of monitoring data. Likewise, even if violations can be detected, in many instances compliance can only be achieved after lengthy court battles. Access to the courts is a right to which all parties are entitled, but too often the use of the courts is a delaying tactic. Numerous cases can be cited where the economic benefits t>f noncompliance were much greater than the cost of lengthy court battles and the fines which might ultimately be imposed by the court. The use of direct regulation therefore does not necessarily ensure effective- ness, but neither do other forms of government intervention. The criteria, however, with which to judge the effectiveness of a particular alternative could be stated in terms of administrative feasibility and enforceability. The criteria to judge these two measures are: • Resource constraints • Informational constraints • Detectability • Compliance 3 . 2 EFFICIENCY Whereas the primary criticism of groups seeking government intervention is the lack of effectiveness, the primary criticism of those groups subject to control is efficiency. Efficiency from an economist's perspective would be defined as maximization of social welfare, conveniently defined as equalization of social costs and benefits at the margin. While these concepts are frequently discussed, they become increasingly diffi- cult to follow in practice. The problem lies in that many of the costs and benefits defy measurement. For example, how should we value the reduction in a unit of pollution which will only build up to harmful concentrations in the atmosphere over many decades, or how do we value the loss of freedom stemming from smoking bans in public places. C-25 In the absence of direct measurement of costs and benefits, the question often distills down to whether a "prudent person" would consider control to be in the public interest and whether the cost of control is reasonable. A related concept which is coming into increasing use is to interject risk into the equation. The question then becomes whether a "prudent person" would consider control to be in the public interest and whether the social risk of non- or only limited intervention is significantly greater or less than the cost of control. The reason for focusing specifically on risk is to make explicit the judgment that zero risk is not attainable or its corollary, some risk must be acceptable. The degree of risk we are willing to accept will vary as a function of the objective. When efficiency takes into consideration allowable risk, it becomes feasible to consider many alternative forms of government intervention. Direct regu- lation, which commonly carries with it the implicit objective of zero risk, is no longer required. Informational approaches may be deemed quite acceptable and incentive type approaches, which attempt to use the market, might even offer more efficient solutions. 3.3 EQUITY Equity is a highly subjective concept but one that is nonetheless quite important. In most cases of health, safety, or environmental protection, an approach is judged to be equitable if standards of performance are uniform and the source that has created the need for government intervention bears the cost. The reason why equity is an important concept is that it often conflicts with the first two criteria. For example, if uniform standards of performance are required, sources with particularly high costs of control may find it in their economic self-interest not to comply. This complicates the enforcement process and thus the effectiveness of the program. Likewise, it is widely recognized that the risk to the public is not uniform among all sources (e.g., urban versus rural powerplants) . If source specific characteristics are important in determining the degree of risk, uniform standards based on worst case conditions can lead to significant overcontrol thereby increasing the cost at little or no benefit to society. Similar examples can be cited with respect to the criterion that the party causing the particular problem bears the cost. It can be shown that it may be more efficient for the government to subsidize pollution control, rather than force individual sources to finance controls. In the case of individual compliance, additional legal and administrative costs are incurred without a reduction in the costs of control. Additionally, the benefits to the public may be realized sooner if a government subsidy is used. The equity aspect of regulation cannot be ignored. While it may not be explicitly discussed in the context of any particular case for government intervention, it is implicit throughout the established regulatory framework. Whether equity should be any less or more important than effectiveness or efficiency is questionable. Equity considerations deserve to be discussed to the extent that they constrain the use of alternatives to direct regulation. C-26 3.4 POLITICAL FEASIBILITY An issue which cuts across the boundaries of effectiveness, efficiency, and equity is political feasibility. Whereas it may be feasible in the abstract to discuss tradeoffs among the above criteria, it may not be politically feasible to discuss them. Political feasibility is dynamic; what might be acceptable under one administration may not be acceptable under another. Likewise the attitudes of the public change as does the ability of special interest groups to influence the decisionmaking process. It is difficult to establish criteria for evaluating the political feasibility of proposed actions. However, in the context of the issues discussed in this paper, it is probably most closely approximated by the perceived willingness of the public to accept risk and its willingness to accept innovative approaches Within the current cost-conscious environment, the willingness of the public may rank high on both of these counts . 3.5 SUMMARY Figure 1 attempts to summarize the above criteria. It is recognized that these criteria will not be universally acceptable or inclusive of all the considerations that are deemed relevant. They were meant solely to establish some broad guidelines for considering the alternatives presented in Section 2. C-27 FIGURE 1 CRITERIA FOR EVALUATING ALTERNATIVES TO REGULATION Effectiveness Administrative,. Feasibility Enforceability Resource Contraints Informational Constraints Detectability Compliance Efficiency Equity Costs Eenef its- Risk Uniformity of Standards Incidence and Burden of Costs Political Feasibility -Acceptance of Risk JVillingness to Use Innovative Approaches C-28 4. USE OF ALTERNATIVES The previous two sections have attempted to establish a framework within which to consider alternatives to regulation. By necessity, much of the material presented in those sections involved abstract concepts which at best offer insights only when applied to real problems. As noted previously, few studies in the literature have attempted to deal with the practical problems of alter- natives to regulation, or for that matter regulations per se. The case study presented below was one attempt to test intervention alternatives in an empirical context. While it may be difficult to generalize from the results of this study, it does illustrate how the tradeoffs between the use of tradi- tional regulatory strategies and other approaches might be compared. Two additional cases are discussed in this section. They could not be developed in as much detail, but were included to demonstrate the range of issues which need to be considered . 4.1 SHORT-TERM NITROGEN DIOXIDE STANDARD The Clean Air Act Amendments of 1977 require the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) to determine if a short-term standard for ambient concentrations of nitrogen dioxide (NO2) is necessary to protect public health. The Act required the EPA to review the available evidence on health effects , publish its findings, and, if a health risk were established, to promulgate a standard within one year. Simultaneously, the Congress required the EPA in conjunction with the Council on Environmental Quality (CEQ) to study the use of economic incentives to air pollution control, and more specifically, to the control of NO2. While neither EPA's health effects findings nor the study of economic approaches to air pollution have been published, certain findings of these studies are cited below.* 4.1.1 The Problem NO2 is the oxidation product of nitrogen oxide (NO) , emitted primarily (98 percent) by combustion of fossil fuels. The formation process includes both temperature dependent oxidation of NO by atmospheric oxygen (at high concen- trations of NO) and oxidation of NO by atmospheric ozone, at all concentrations of NO. N0 2 is subsequently transformed into other compounds, making the net level of NO2 at any point in the atmosphere the result of a complex interactive chain of reactions. High concentrations of N0 2 have been shown to cause health effects. Both laboratory and epidemiological studies have placed the health damage threshold at 1,000 to 1,500 micrograms of NO2 per cubic meter (ug N02/m 3 ) • Sources of NO x (N0 2 plus NO) include both mobile and stationary sources with both ground level and elevated discharge points. While the percentage of emissions from these sources will vary by time of day, by season, by region and by other factors, NO x is emitted on an annual basis roughly on the *These findings represent the view of the contractor and do not necessarily represent the viewpoint of either the Environmental Protection Agency or the Council on Environmental Quality. C-29 quantities and percentages shown in Table 2. The mix of sources is quite heterogeneous and if control is required it will involve a relatively complex control strategy. 4.1.2 Alternative Approaches to Control The Clean Air Act requires that once the need for control has been demonstrated that a control strategy be selected which ensures that violations will occur no more frequently than once per year. For a 1-hour standard this is an extremely stringent requirement, equivalent to a probability of occurrence of no more than .0001 in any given year. If the state fails to demonstrate that this standard can be met, EPA is required by statutes to impose its own requirements on the offending sources . Given the stringency of the requirement and the need for highly effective controls, certain approaches to government intervention may be precluded. Four classes of mechanisms were discussed in Section 2. These include regula- tions, incentives, informational approaches, and mixed strategies. All but the informational approaches were included in the EPA/CEQ study. In order to study these alternatives a sample Air Quality Control Region (AQCR) was selected. The AQCR was segmented into 5x5 kilometer grid areas with area source emissions (both mobile and dispersed area) and point sources modeled separately. In total, the region was divided into 640 grid cells with 796 separate point sources individually located. The alternatives that were considered in this study include both traditional and non traditional regulatory approaches. The traditional approach was to apply a concept called "rollback" to each source based on the maximum percentage control required for any source in the region. This would imply that if the maximum measured concentration was 800 ug/m^ and the standard was 500 ug/m^, every source in the region would have to reduce its emissions by 38 percent.* Nontraditional approaches included the use of emission charges designed to achieve the standard at each receptor and a least cost strategy which might be approximated either by source-specific emission regulations or a marketable permit type of approach. 4.1.3 Criteria for Evaluation 4.1.3.1 Traditional Regulatory Approach - Rollback 4.1.3.1.1 Effectiveness - Rollback The traditional approach is probably the most administratively feasible but also the most difficult to enforce. The concept of rollback is well understood by the state regulatory agencies. In most cases, it represents business-as- usual and a minimum information requirement. *If background concentrations from essentially uncontrollable sources were appreciable, the percentage control requirement would increase proportionately. C-30 TABLE 2 NATIONWIDE NO x EMISSION ESTIMATES, 19 76 (10 metric tons/year) Source Category Transport at ion • Highway vehicles • Non-highway vehicles Statonary Fuel Combustion • Electric utilities • Industrial • Residential, commercial, and institutional Industrial Processes • Chemicals • Petroleum refining • Metals • Mineral products • Oil and gas production and marketing • Industrial organic solvent use • Other processes NO Percent — X 10.1 44 (7.8) (34) (2.3) (10) 11.8 51 (6.6) (27) (4.5) (20) (0.7) (4) 0.7 2 (0.3) (1) (0.3) (1) (0) (0) (0.1) (0) (0) (0) (0) (0) (0) (0) Solid Waste 0.1 Miscellaneous • Forest wildfires and managed burning • Agricultural burning • Coal refuse burning • Structural fires • Miscellaneous organic solvent use 0.3 (0.2) (1) (0) (0) (0.1) (0) (0) (07 (0) (0) Total 23.0 100 SOURCE: "The National Air Monitoring Program: Air Quality and Emission Trends," EPA, December 1977. C-31 From an enforcement standpoint, rollback has proven to be extremely diffi- cult. When the cost of control is large, sources have an incentive to use any tactic available to delay compliance. In such cases sources can, with little difficulty, perform their own modeling studies and demonstrate that they are not causing a violation of the standards. Rollback also complicates the enforcement problem by requiring all sources to comply with a fixed requirement regardless of their actual contribution. By requiring all sources to comply with a fixed emission limitation, the number of sources which must be controlled can be several fold to several orders of magnitude greater than actually required to achieve the ambient standard. 4.1.3.1.2 Efficiency - Rollback The question of efficiency is one of how much expense is required to meet a fixed standard. In the case of a particularly ubiquitous pollutant, rollback may prove to be a reasonable approximation of the degree of control required, but if the pollutant is less ubiquitous, rollback may require control where none is needed. In the case of the short-term NO2 standard, the use of rollback increased total control costs an order of magnitude. Annual control costs under rollback were estimated to be $254 million as compared with $21 million under the least-cost solution. 4.1.3.1.3 Equity - Rollback Rollback usually requires sources of a similar nature to use the same type of control equipment to achieve the required reduction in emissions. Also, to the extent that sources comply with the regulation, the direct costs are absorbed by the sources. Rollback, therefore, ranks high from an equity perspective and this is one of the main reasons for its widespread use. 4.1.3.1.4 Political Feasibility - Rollback The political feasibility of continued widespread use of rollback might be questioned given current environmental conditions. This might be especially true in the context of this case study because of the significant degree of overcontrol imposed and the increasing recognition by the public that they ultimately bear this unnecessary cost. 4.1.3.2 Incentive Approaches - Uniform and Variable Emission Charges Two incentive approaches were considered which relied primarily on the market to regulate behavior. The uniform emission charge set a charge rate equal to the marginal cost of control of the highest cost individual source. The concept is that all sources will control up to the point where the marginal cost of an additional increment of control is less than the charge rate. Since the charge rate must be high enough to insure that standards are met at all receptors, the agency has no choice (assuming that it must comply with the Clean Air Act requirement of no more than one violation per year) but to set the tax at the highest marginal cost of control of sources contributing to violations. The variable charge rate recognizes that alternative categories of sources have different marginal costs of control and that the charge rate need not be applied uniformly to all sources to ensure attainment. Nine categories of sources were defined and a charge rate set equal to the highest marginal cost of control for any single source within each source category. C-32 In both cases, the charge rate was applied to all emissions from the source. Therefore, to the extent that emissions reduction is less than 100 percent, the source continues to pay a charge on its uncontrolled emissions. 4.1.3.2.1 Effectiveness - Incentives Incentive approaches tend to have greater information- requirements than direct regulation approaches, and consequently are less feasible from an administrative viewpoint. However, they are viewed as being more readily and effectively enforced . In order to implement the charge scheme for N0 2 , a relatively sophisticated multiple point and area source interaction dispersion model was created. The degree of sophistication will vary significantly depending on the specific pollutant to be controlled. In this case, the degree of sophistication was high . This requirement is critical to the viable use of incentives . Few agencies are capable of carrying out this form of analysis . In most cases , they lack the necessary data and expertise. While agencies could develop this capability they would find that implementing a pure charge system would prove to be administratively more difficult and costly than use of traditional approaches. Consequently, the advantages of a charge system must be large enough to more than offset the increased administrative costs for the charge system to be a preferable regulatory approach. The more frequent argument in favor of emission charge systems is that they significantly improve the enforcement potential . Sources under a charge system would find it in their economic interest to comply because failure to comply would result in higher total costs . The weakness in this argument is that in order to implement a charge system, the enforcement authority must be able to monitor emissions. Emission monitoring capabilities have improved enormously in the past ten years, but even the most reliable systems require continual calibration. The possibility of tampering or more likely, equipment failures would make collection of emission charges exceedingly difficult. The effectiveness of emission charges, i.e., incentive type approaches, need not be any more or less certain than regulatory approaches. It is sufficient to say that the relative benefits of either approach depend on the specific circumstances of the action which the government is attempting to control. In the case of N0 X , any emission charge scheme would tend to increase the administrative burden while providing no clear benefit in the context of enforceability . 4.1.3.2.2 Efficiency - Incentives Emission charges have traditionally been supported by the economic profession as the most reasonable method for equalizing costs and benefits . When unable to measure benefits, a second best condition in favor of emission charges is that they can be used to minimize costs for a given level of control . In theory, these arguments have significant appeal, but in practice, they can be difficult to realize. C-33 While arguments over the ability to equalize marginal costs and benefits have centered on the question of measuring benefits, control costs can be equally difficult to estimate. Costs per unit of control for identical sources can vary widely. For any source they are a function of the capital equipment which must be purchased, the operating rate of the plant, the age of the plant, the company's cost of capital, and other variable factors. In instances where the source of the pollution is independent of the ambient impact, many of these factors may be safely ignored. The traditional argument in such cases is that the charge rate can be varied until the standard is met. This, however, ignores the fact that control technologies are lumpy investments . A given control system may be capable of achieving a 20 percent level of control, but in order to increase the collection efficiency to 40 percent, an entirely new system must be purchased. Therefore, varying the tax rate could result in large cost penalties which could be avoided if the charge rate were set correctly initially Likewise, if ambient concentrations are associated with a specific source, the charge rate must be set at a level to obtain control from the highest cost source . The use of a uniform charge system to control NO resulted in control costs comparable to the traditional rollback approach, and, in addition, charge revenues far in excess of the cost of control. Since NO2 concentrations were directly related to individual sources, under the uniform charge system, the charge rate had to be set equal to the highest marginal cost of control. The costs to attain the standard at every receptor were estimated to be $239 million, as compared to $254 million under rollback. In addition, $468 million in charge revenues were collected on uncontrolled emissions. The variable charge system performed much better with direct annual control costs to sources of approximately $98 million and charge revenues of $75 million, but even in this case, the costs were significantly higher than the least-cost solution of $21 million. While neither system appeared to approximate the economists ' notion of least- cost, both systems did offer control cost savings over the traditional approach. Obviously, the variable charge system would have been preferred over the uni- form system, but it adds additional administrative complexity and cost. The complexity of the variable charge system, however, should not be overemphasized. The control cost savings which were estimated to be $156 million would be more than adequate to justify the more complicated approach and could readily be funded with the $98 million in charge revenues. Only a small fraction of these charge revenues would be required both to conduct the analysis and to implement the requisite information program. 4.1.3.2.3 Equity - Incentives The uniform charge system probably best represents the concept of equity which most people hold. The sources are permitted to determine the degree of control most appropriate to their particular situation and pay for emission discharges at a uniform rate above the level of control they choose to implement. All sources are treated equally, and therefore, equitably. Likewise, the costs are borne directly by the source. All costs, including those for which no measurable benefit is accruing to the public, are incurred directly by the source . C-34 The variable charge scheme moves away from the concept of uniformity, but continues to treat similar sources alike. Since similar sources may be perceived to have the same type of ambient impact (although this is seldom the case) , distinguishing by category may be viewed as consistent with the definition of equity utilized in this paper. 4.1.3.2.4 Political Feasibility - Incentives Obviously, since the study of economic approaches to control N0 X emissions from stationary sources was requested by the Congress, one can presume that the legislature is willing to consider alternative approaches to direct regulation in this instance. The charge systems in this case offered some benefits in terms of efficiency; they were considered to be more difficult from an effectiveness perspective, and if structured on a uniform variable charge rate framework, were similar to the traditional approach from an equity perspective. The tradeoff therefore is clearly between effectiveness and efficiency which, if the public is willing to accept more risk, would tend to favor such approaches. 4.1.3.3 Mixed Strategies - Marketable Permits/Optimal Direct Control Theoretically, a properly designed marketable permit system will result in a least-cost solution to achieve any given level of control. Under this type of system, the controlling agency issues permits which allow a specific amount of pollution to be emitted within the control region. These permits might be specified either in quantities of acceptable emissions or in terms of ground level concentrations. The former would be acceptable with a particularly ubiquitous pollutant, whereas if the impact is attributable to a single source, the latter would be required. Once the permits have been issued, each source in the region would be allowed to compete or bid for "emission rights." The bid rate would be a function both of cost of control to the individual source and the perceived value to other sources. Theoretically, an optimum would be reached in which the cost of additional permits was just equal to the highest marginal cost of control for each source impacting on each receptor within a given control region. This result was approximated in the N0 X study through the use of a heuristic integer programming algorithm. This result might also be approximated through the use of direct regulations that were based both on cost and ambient impact. Each source in a given area would control to the lowest marginal control cost level at which the ambient standard would be met. This might require different degrees of control at each source, but the marginal cost for each source would be the same. In the context of this study, the regulations to be imposed would have been derived directly from the least-cost solution. 4.1.3.3.1 Effectiveness - Mixed Strategies Clearly, any approach which requires the use of highly sophisticated modeling approaches would create enormous administrative burdens on state and local control agencies. Such a system would require that the agencies not only have a comprehensive emission inventory, but also the capabilities to carry out complex modeling studies. Neither of these conditions exists in most state or local agencies. The ability to ensure that the objective was achieved therefore would be highly uncertain. C-35 Likewise, depending on the degree to which sources were allowed to transfer permits , the requirements for any given source might be changed over time which would make enforcement difficult. Also, continuous monitoring would be required to ensure that each source was in compliance. This issue has already been discussed in the context of the uniform and variable charge system. The difficulties in this instance are no less tractable. 4.1.3.3.2 Efficiency - Mixed Strategies This system offers obvious benefits in the area of efficiency. Under the least-cost solution, only 94 out of 797 sources were required to implement controls. The cost of compliance and thus, attainment, was estimated to be $21 million or less than 10 percent of the cost under rollback or the uniform charge rate system. This result would obviously be extremely difficult to approximate in a real world situation, but it does illustrate the significant benefits which might result from more flexible strategies. The risk of not attaining standards, however, might be much greater because of the adminis- trative and enforcement problems that would be encountered. In addition, the total cost of the program must recognize the increased cost to the public for administration and enforcement capability. 4.1.3.3.3 Equity - Mixed Strategies The most significant difficulty with this type of approach is that sources are not treated equally. Firms would be differentially affected, depending on their potential ambient impact and the site where they originally chose to locate. Since firms generally have no control over the development patterns which occur after they locate in a region, they would be penalized for decisions over which they had no control. One of the major arguments that led to the enactment of the noncompliance tax penalty in the State of Connecticut was that firms should not be placed at a competitive disadvantage because firms competing for the same market fail to comply with applicable regulations. The marketable permit system, however, by definition discriminates among sources on the basis of a totally different set of criteria and could therefore result in significant economic dislocations . 4.1.3.3.4 Political Feasibility - Mixed Strategies There is no doubt that a system of market permits or optimal direct control would be a radical departure from the traditional means which the government has used to control air pollution. It would also involve considerable risk if administrative and enforcement requirements proved to be too complex. The Congress has continually reiterated its desire to have continuous control systems and move increasingly toward uniform requirements by source category. Whether this is by conscious design, or whether the cost of such policies has not been adequately represented, is a matter of speculation. The fact remains that the requirements for regulations stated in terms of percentage removal, the lowest achievable emissions rate (LAER) requirement, and the reasonably available control technology requirement (RACT) , force the regulatory process in the direction of uniform standards of performance independent of ambient impact. The use of marketable permit systems or direct regulations which are tied specifically to ambient impact might therefore rank low oh any index of political feasibility. C-36 4.1.4 Summary - Nitrogen Dioxide Control Table 3 attempts to summarize the conclusions of this case study. The ranking of low, moderate, and high is an indication of the consistency of the approach with the criteria. For example, low in the context of cost criteria under rollback does not mean that costs are low, but rather that this strategy was ranked low relative to the objective of minimizing total costs. From this table, it is clear that no single strategy is clearly superior. Most people would argue, however, that the criteria are not of equal value, and, therefore, a clearly superior approach might result if we could obtain agreement both in the rankings and the weights to be assigned to each criteria. Whereas this statement in and of itself might be true, it is clear that the conditions which are necessary and sufficient to obtain this result will, in all likelihood, never exist. In the first place, the subjective rankings presented in the table will never be fully agreed on, and even if they were, the assigning of weights would vary enormously among the interested parties. The situation, therefore, becomes one that is dependent on attempts to employ alternative approaches in actual situations so that the subjective nature of the tradeoffs which are implied when a particular strategy is selected can be evaluated on a less subjective basis. 4.2 CONTROLLING EXPOSURE TO ASBESTOS IN THE WORKPLACE Occupational exposure to airborne asbestos particles is a serious problem in terms of the number of people affected, the severity of the ^potential health impact, and the lack of information on actual risks. As such, it is a useful case study for comparing the relative benefits of alternative forms of govern- ment intervention. 4.2.1 Background Asbestos is a term describing several naturally occurring silicate minerals. There are currently over 3,000 different commercial uses of these minerals, some of which have no suitable substitutes. Thus, the economic consequences of reducing the use of asbestos are likely to be substantial. On the other side, exposure to high levels of asbestos in the air has been unambiguously linked to three types of cancer, though the interval between exposure and onset of the disease is likely to be 10 or more years. What is less certain is the lowest level which will elicit a health response. Despite the tenfold lowering of the Occupational Safety and Health Administration's standard for asbestos in recent years, no consensus has been reached on what standard will ensure absolute protection. In addition, there are technical limitations to the extent to which ambient asbestos concentrations can be reduced. 4.2.2 Intervention Alternatives 4.2.2.1 Regulation - Asbestos Clearly, the most effective way to protect workers from exposure is to prohibit the emission of asbestos. As noted above, this is not technically possible and such an action would force the closure of plants manufacturing asbestos-containing products. Likewise, setting an ambient standard which required emission control near the limit of technical feasibility would likely impose severe economic burdens on many firms, resulting in the closure of some plants. In both cases, the economic costs in terms of lost jobs and wealth would be substantial. A C-37 CO CD 0) i— I to •H XI +j -o 00 cO •H •H •M CO c fH to w -J s £ to rH 0) o 00 <4H fH •H CO C X => u X fn ^ o o +-> CO CO X r— i c— I 3 r- f oo O cd 0£ OS 3 2 O O _J -J CO to CD cd t— t CD +-> ♦j X M CO cO CO U U f-t •H CO O cd fH C -a T3 cO U o o > S S 4J x CO 5} rH •H CD X -O O CD ■M x CO 00 fH X 00 CO 00 3 •H M *H O X ■M CO CO £h fH CD CD -a 13 o O 2 O -J X! CO CD ■M x CO 00 u •rH cd -r- 1 "3 o s: 2 O -J o +-> CD +-" X CO 00 0) X T3 O X oo 00 X X +-) •rH i—l ■H X •H CO CO CD H. CD X > 4-> •H •rH ■M i— 1 CO ■H U X) CO ■M CO CO CO CO 03 +-> a> > § SH c CO c •H -o c 0) o cd •M < UJ •rH U CQ O CJ CD •rH hh • • 4-1 • • CJ-I t+H m UJ X •M •H CO CO CD tt. i-H CO CJ X •-H •M +-> •r-l •H 3 r~ 1 cr o UJ Dm X CO +-> CD •rH e <+H 2 +-> o X o CD CJ c > CO •H O CO ■M u CD CJ Cu O CD &.T3 •1— i cO X) -^ o CD O X! CO CD +-> XJ x; r— 1 ■M 0) T3 •rH ■M C •M to 3 CO •H p-H CO CO (U c •H fH o M CJ CD 2 ■M O CD •H i-H X rl ■»-> CJ -a iu +-> ^ o CO c O CO e CJ 5h o •H CD to W x: cO CO ■M 2 CJ •H <4-l X -a o 00 c CU •H •M •M X CO C CD fH cO +-> +-> C CO (O o •rH CJ CO •H X CU X! oox +J •I-( ■M X! •w c CO T3 •rH x: C +j CO 2 O fH * r-H CU 0) X •M «. +J CO CD CO rH r-^ fH CD Ch TJ E ■M • O ce 3 CO S X X ■M CD CO * •V O 2 5h 2 a O O O •— i Bh ^H i— i CO M-l CD +J o . Sh o CO CO +- oc •H e Sh to 00 •H CD +J c ^ •M to •H c •H o N cO fH CJ •H fH CJ S •M •rH CD CD CO C F X X •H ■P +-> e •K C-38 compromise position is to set the standard at an achievable level (given some economic impact criterion) . This will reduce but not eliminate the health risk. Regulation applied uniformly is an equitable approach, as noted before. Efficiency is only an issue if the form of the standard is considered. Ambient standards allow firms to adopt the most cost-effective emissions control strategy, while an emission standard will force the installation of advanced controls on every source within the plant. In the case of asbestos, however, the ambient standard is likely to be set so low that advanced controls on all emissions sources would probably be necessary. 4.2.2.2 Incentives - Asbestos The use of economic incentives can be justified on two grounds. First, taxing asbestos emissions (or the subsequent ambient levels) would work to encourage the adoption of more expensive and effective controls. The success of such a tax scheme may be similar to that of an NO emissions tax, discussed previously. Second, revenues from a tax could be used to compensate victims of asbestos exposure. Since the latency period for asbestos-induced cancers may be measured in decades, it is difficult to attribute individual health responses to specific instances or periods of exposure. A national fund, similar to the structure of workmen's compensation, appears to be most appropriate in this situation. Certainly, this approach is satisfying on equity grounds, since it would involve cash flows from those causing to those suffering from the problem. To further improve the equitability of application, payments from asbestos-using firms could be weighted by the size of their work force (and thus by the size of the potentially exposed population at each plant) . 4.2.2.3 Informational Approach - Asbestos Because our knowledge of the health effects of asbestos exposure is far from complete but continually growing, an informational /educational program for current and prospective workers in asbestos industries would seem most appropriate. Information should be presented in as specific and as quanti- tative terms as the current state of knowledge will allow. Workers can then decide whether the working conditions and the remuneration levels are suffi- cient for them to accept the associated health risks. Such a program is likely to be relatively inexpensive, and would not infringe on individual freedoms. 4.2.3 Summary - Asbestos From the discussion above, a mixed strategy combining elements of each of the three major approaches would seem appropriate for the asbestos problem. Regulation would assure that no one is exposed to obviously lethal doses of asbestos. Economic incentives may simultaneously encourage research on the control of asbestos emissions, and provide funds to compensate those workers with asbestos-related health problems. Finally, an information program would place workers in a better position to judge whether their employment is worth the risks involved. C-39 4.3 AUTOMOBILE PASSENGER SAFETY 4.3.1 The Problem The areas of automobile safety and passenger safety provide many examples of government intervention. The objective of government intervention is to protect the driving public and reduce the frequency and/or severity of acci- dents and bodily injury. This might reduce personal discomfort, lost work time, and hospitalization costs which might in turn stabilize or reduce insurance premiums. The requirement that seat belts be standard in all cars is an attempt to reduce bodily injury in the event of a collision. However, this program is ineffective because most people do not use seat belts. It has been proposed that passive restraint measures might be more effective. Air bags are a passive restraint system designed to protect the front seat passengers in a vehicle from bodily injury caused by a head-on collision. They are readily available at present on several car models at a cost of $300-$500. At present they protect only front seat passengers; however, devices adapted to the rear seat may become available. This passive restraint system provides protection comparable to that provided by a fastened seat belt and shoulder harness in a head-on collision. However, the device may provide little protection in some accidents (e.g., rear end or broadside impacts) . 4.3.2 Alternative Approaches 4.3.2.1 Regulation - Auto Safety The regulatory approach to the problem would require that all cars contain air bags or that all passengers wear seat belts. Requiring the installation of air bags would be effective in reducing bodily injury (assuming they function properly) in some types of collisions. This program would raise the price of every new car by $300-$500, imposing a tremendous cost on the public. This must be considered inefficient since the device provides no benefit greater than the fastened seat belts, which can be utilized at no additional cost to consumers. Since the regulation would be applied uniformly to all consumers and manufacturers it must be equitable. Politically it may not be feasible because of its infringement on the individual's freedom of choice. Requiring that seat belts be worn at all times could be equally effective in reducing bodily injury if it were enforceable. This might be realized by revoking the license of any driver if the driver or passengers in the vehicle were not wearing seat belts. This would be an economically effi- cient approach since there would be virtually no cost for equipment, and violations could be handled as traffic violations. Again, the political feasibility of this approach might be limited because it infringes on the individual's freedom of choice. C-40 4.3.2.2 Insurance Alterations - Auto Safety Another strategy which utilizes aspects of the regulatory and incentive approaches would be for the government to require that insurance premiums or claims be adjusted according to use and disuse of seat belts. In this program seat belt wearers would pay lower premiums than non-wearers, or coverage might exclude injuries which would have been avoided had seat belts been worn. Premiums could be developed from actuarial data. Indi- viduals could still choose their habits, but those who select the more dangerous habit would have to pay higher rates. Such a program readily ties into the existing insurance market. This program might be very effective. If individuals recognize clearly the increased cost associated with disuse, they would probably use seat belts more frequently. This program would also be fairly efficient in that there would be little additional cost and the extra cost could be allocated statistically to those likely to incur higher hospitalization costs. The program might be considered equitable since individuals of the same type (i.e., wearers, non-wearers) would be treated uniformly. Because the premium distinction is based on objective statistical data, it should be politically feasible to adopt such a practice. 4.3.2.3 Taxes - Auto Safety The use of passive protective devices such as air bags might be induced by imposing a tax on vehicles without them. This would be a market-based incentive to use air bags which leaves the individual consumer with the choice of buying air bags or paying the tax. The effectiveness of the tax would depend on its level. If set above the price of air bags, everyone would select air bags. If the tax were below the price of air bags, fewer people would buy them. If the program stimu- lated the purchase of air bags, it might be effective in reducing bodily injury. However, it would not in any way increase the use of seat belts. The program could be very inefficient since the costs could be substantial and there would be no safety benefits to those who pay the tax or those who wear seat belts. The inequity here is to those who wear seat belts and receive no safety benefit for their expense. 4.3.2.4 Subsidies - Auto Safety It would be possible for the government to subsidize the installation of air bags in order to reduce injuries in automobile accidents. Such a program might be justified because all drivers are penalized for the carelessness of some in the form of universally high insurance premiums. Seat belt wearers pay, directly or indirectly, for the hospitalization costs of those who do not wear seat belts. Thus they too might benefit from a program which emphasizes passive restraints. A subsidy program would be effective — both administratively feasible and enforceable. The program would be more costly to society than the use of seat belts, but efficiency might be judged by comparing the aggregate investment in air bags with the avoided expense of physical injury. This program would be equitable in that all individuals are treated uniformly. C-41 4.3.2.5 Information and Education - Auto Safety This approach would entail distributing clear information describing the risks and benefits of driving with no protection, with seat belts, and with air bags. The types of protection, advantages and disadvantages, and cost of each action would be made clear. The individual then would determine the acceptable level of risk and determine his/her own action. This would be a very easy program to implement politically and administratively. Whether it would be effective would depend on the voluntary response of the public. An individual might easily conclude that seat belts provide good protection at no expense and subsequently forget to use them. The program would be very efficient since individual consumers would opt to minimize their costs. The equity here is that each individual would determine an acceptable risk and behavior. All individuals selecting the same type of protection would bear the same cost. The program would be politically feasible since it hinges on the individual's freedom to act and accept risks. 4.3.3 Summary - Auto Safety This discussion is to demonstrate that approaches other than strict regulation might achieve the objective of reducing injuries. The major difficulty in solving this problem is that the least-cost solution (use of seat belts) is ineffective because it depends on a voluntary action by the public which is often not taken. The situation might be remedied by encouraging the desired action (use of seat belts or purchase of air bags) through the distribution of information, economic incentives, or regulation. The effectiveness of each approach depends on the mood of the public, its willingness to accept risk, and the political difficulties of legislating individual behavior. C-42 5. SYNOPSIS This paper has attempted to address an extremely complex problem, hopefully developing a framework that is useful for discussing alternatives to direct regulation. The alternative mechanisms for government intervention developed and the methods for their evaluation apply most directly to regulatory issues involving health, safety, and the environment. The dimensions of externalities and personal welfare involved in this subset of government regulation set it apart to some extent from other areas. For example, many agricultural programs are targeted to assure stable, long-term domestic supplies of farm commodiites which, instead of addressing externalities, deal more with sectional economics and national supply security. The dimension of social externality that exists in the regulation of health, safety, and the environment adds the confounding dimension of measuring non-dollar denominated benefits, but at the same time offers the opportunity of several possible regulatory mechanisms (as outlined in Section 2 of this paper) . Although some of these mechanisms are not applicable in other regulatory arenas (information transfer does nothing for grain stockpiling) , the tradeoff between direct regulation and reliance on incentive-based market mechanisms is broadly applicable in other regulatory arenas. More importantly, the criteria of evaluation (effectiveness, efficiency, and equity) readily can be applied to most regulatory programs. Over the past decade, the bulk of new regulation nas dealt with issues of externalities. This paper has shown that alternative regulatory approaches may have merit in dealing with externality problems. More importantly, it has shown that alternatives are not per se better than direct regulation, that alternatives perhaps more so than direct regulation must be evaluated for their ability to deal with specific cases or narrowly defined generic issues . Solutions to the general problem of regulation — that of public sentiment which has evolved toward a notion of excessive or inefficient regulation — are not clearly illuminated by these findings. What is the proper approach to this problem? A bottom up approach would focus on individual actions taken or proposed by regulatory agencies. Such an approach might require any agency to consider explicitly alternative forms of regulation and provide a comparative analysis of why a particular approach was selected. Some of the alternatives and criteria discussed in Sections 2 and 3 might be useful for this purpose. A top down approach might be selected in which some recognition is given to the fact that we are always dealing with limited resources and not all social ills can be remedied simultaneously. Such an approach would have to establish a risk/cost/benefit framework in which those social ills which represent a "clear and present" danger were given priority. This might mean sacrificing noise abatement standards in favor of a more aggressive toxic substances program C-43 Alternatively, these two approaches could be combined. An oversight committee would be responsible for establishing priorities and the agencies would be responsible for insuring that alternatives to regu- lations be considered. In an idealized framework, any or all of these approaches might assist in modulating the impact of current regulatory programs. This, however, ignores the fact that many agencies, because of their legislative mandates, do not have the flexibility either to prioritize their programs or to consider alternatives. In order to implement either of the above approaches, a significant reshaping of the laws governing these agencies would be required. One of the most significant conclusions of this report may be that it is difficult to see how the many Federal, state, and local legislatures might be persuaded to restate the laws which they have enacted. The problem rests with the fact that billions of dollars are spent annually attempting to identify potential problems, while little or no basic research is performed on how these problems might be mitigated at the least cost to society and with a minimum of disruption of the social fabric. Few, if any, studies are performed on alternatives to regulation. The absence of research in this area leads us to underestimate the true cost of regulation. To the extent that the true costs of a commodity are understated, society--the consuming public — will demand more than it can afford. Rectifying this situation will not be an easy task. Literally hundreds of regulations are passed every year which have both direct and indirect impacts on the economy. Since many of these regulations are directed at social externalities, the tools which have been created to deal with the economic consequences of government actions cannot adequately simulate the impact. It is, however, only through these mechanisms that we can hope to understand, or at least appreciate the magnitude of the problem with which we are dealing. Attempts to prioritize on the basis of risk/cost/benefit and to consider alternatives to regulations should assist in this process. C-44 ANNOTATED BIBLIOGRAPHY OF THE LITERATURE The sample of research articles that follow allow a number of observations on trends in research on alternative approaches to regulation. From this sample, a number of highlights may be presented as follows. The observa- tions relate only to the limited sample, which, though probably represent- ative of the whole, is not necessarily representative of all aspects of research in this area. • Most research on alternative approaches to regulation has been theoretical, rather than empirical. Problems stemming from ac- tual conditions have thus not yet been fully taken into account. • Virtually all articles have dealt with approaches to controlling environmental pollution, particularly water pollution. Conclu- sions reached in this area would not necessarily hold for differ- ent applications such as approaches for achieving health or safety. • Virtually all articles have focused on a comparison or evaluation of regulatory standards, tax, or subsidy approaches. There were no assessments in the sample on informational approaches. • The articles represent ongoing discussion among primarily academic economists. There have been frequent cross-references between works and debates over assumptions and conclusions. This has led to a progression in knowledge as previous assertions have been shown inaccurate and important assumptions have been identified. • Although there was not full agreement among authors, in general the authors concluded that tax approaches would be the most effi- cient approaches . Regulatory approaches were seen as having good administrative feasibility but numerous inefficiencies. While subsidy approaches were equated with tax approaches in terms of potential for efficiency, they were rated lower in terms of equity and were found to be administratively infeasible in the form that would have yielded its highest efficiency. Mixed approaches were sometimes found to offer desirable performance opportunities. • Although such generalizations may be made, the articles in aggre- gate have pointed out enough exceptions and special assumptions C-45 or conditions that it appears no fixed rule can be followed in applying alternative approaches. Further research is needed to assess the value of alternatives in specific situations and, in particular, to take into account factors of enforceability and political feasibility. The following twenty- two annotated references form a subset of the references listed in the Bibliography. Adar, Zari and James M. Griffin. "Uncertainty and the Choice of Pollution Control Instruments." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management , October 1976. Compares taxes, regulations, and marketable permits as applied to environ- mental control. The value of the approaches is discussed when the marginal damage or marginal control cost functions are subject to uncertainty. The article concludes that uncertainty in the marginal damage function has no effect on the choice of optimal approaches. It concludes that uncertainty in the marginal cost of control function does have an effect on the choice of optimal approaches. When the marginal cost of control function is uncertain, a tax approach will be desirable if the marginal damage function is very price elastic. This is thought to be the case for SO2 emissions. When the marginal cost of control function is uncertain, permits or regulations will be desirable if the marginal damage function is very price inelastic. The welfare effects of permits and regulations will differ, however. Amihud, Yakov. "The Efficiency of Taxes and Subsidies in Reducing Emissions by a Risk-Adverse Firm." Kyklos . 1976. Page 113. The article deals with tax and subsidy approaches to pollution control. The author notes that some economists feel that in the short run there is no difference between a tax and subsidy and that differences occur only over the long run. The author disagrees and argues that even in the short run, firms facing uncertainty and with risk- averse strategies may react differently to taxes or subsidies. A subsidy, he contends, will tend to lead to less reduction in emissions and may in some cases lead to increased emissions. C-46 Baumol, W.J. and W.E. Oates. "The Use of Standards and Prices for Pro- tection of the Environment." Swedish Journal of Economics . 1971. Pages 42-54. The article deals with taxes, subsidies, and standards in the area of pollution control. Unlike many other theoretical studies, which seek pareto optimal or efficient solutions to the problem of pollution and resource allocation, this study proposed that arbitrary standards of environmental quality be adopted as targets and that a set of effluent charges be imposed to meet the standards of environmental quality. The authors acknow- ledge that the outcome will not be pareto optimal but feel it will have the lowest costs for attaining specified pollution reductions. Boyd, J. Hayden. "Pollution Charges Income and the Costs of Water Quality Management." Water Resources Research . August, 1971 The article discusses tax and direct provision approaches to pollution control in a river basin. The author discusses the imbalance between the optimal level for pollu- tion fees if set as an incentive to reduce pollution or if set as a revenue-raising device to pay for the optimal level of investment in increasing the waste assimilative capacity of a river basin. A, tax set at the marginal cost of pollutants will yield more than is needed for river assimilative capacity augmentation. Similarly, if the tax were set just high enough to pay for what is needed to optimally augment river assimilative capacity, it will not be high enough to bring about optimal pollution reduction and thus not high enough for economic efficiency. Bramhall, D.F. and E.S. Mills. "A Note on the Asymmetry between Fees and Bribes." Water Resources Research . July-September, 1966. The article deals with taxes and subsidies to control pollution. The authors note two works that have reached conclusions on the differ- ences between tax and subsidy approaches. The first is alleged to have said that the main difference between the two approaches is equity, not efficiency. The second is alleged to have said that the only differ- ence in terms of efficiency will take place if subsidies are misapplied Ci.e., if they are given for the difference between controlled levels and uncontrolled levels of emissions as they are, rather than as they would have been without the policy). A subsidy for not polluting obviously creates an incentive to raise initial pollution levels to gain a larger subsidy. C-47 The authors disagree with both studies, however. They contend that both studies reach inaccurate conclusions because they look only at short run conditions. In the long run, taxes will lower corporate profits while subsidies will increase profits. The difference in profits will lead to differences in exit and entry from the industry and thus through competition to differences in prices. Hence, there is a long run efficiency difference between tax and subsidy approaches even when applied accurately to avoid initial overpollution. . Bramhall, David H. and Edwin S. Mills. "Alternative Methods of Improving Stream Quality: An Economic and Policy Analysis," Water Resources Research . Third Quarter, 1966. This article compares the costs of wastewater treatment and low flow augmentation for environmental quality control in river basins. It also assesses the comparative strengths of regulatory, tax, and sub- sidy approaches to wastewater treatment by the private sector. The article cites views expressed by Allen V. Kneese in The Economics of Regional Water Quality Management , (Johns Hopkins Press, 1964). The authors argue that subsidies would be difficult to administer because there would be little possibility in practice to know what the pollution levels would have been without the subsidies. The authors see three advantages for taxes over regulatory standards. These are: 1) taxes induce the greatest abatement of pollution where cheapest to do so, 2) taxes would allow investment decisions to be made decentrally by firms rather than by the central pollution control authority, and 3) taxes would create an ongoing incentive for firms to look for technologies to lower discharges further. Yet, the authors advocate a combination or mixed strategy in which taxes are supplemented by regulatory standards where proper tax levels would lead to too complex a schedule or where taxes were being irrationally ignored, especially if public health were endangered. Byrne, R.F. and M.H. Spiro. "On Taxation as a Pollution Control Policy." Swedish Journal of Economics . March, 1973. This article deals with a tax approach to pollution control. The authors attempt to demonstrate that a tax approach might not be efficient under certain conditions that they feel are common -- when firms have a number of production processes of fixed proportion, con- stant returns to scale nature. C-48 Fishelson, Gideon. "Emission Control Policies Under Uncertainty." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management . October, 1976. Compares tax and regulatory approaches for air pollution control. The article concludes that when the marginal benefits curve of air quality is steeper than the marginal costs curve, regulations will give lower costs. If the marginal costs curve is steeper than the marginal benefits curve, taxes will give lower costs. These con- clusions were based upon an assumption of linear marginal benefits and marginal costs functions. They will not necessarily hold under different conditions, i.e., non-linearity. On page 196, the article states: "The moral is obvious. The main effort is to be put into the study of the pollution abatement activ- ities and costs, before resorting to any specific policv." Apparently, this statement reflects the fact that the specific condi- tions in any given application may determine which approach would be best, rather than allowing a single approach to be best for all applications. * Herzog, Henry W. "Economic Efficiency and Equity in Water Quality Control: Effluent Taxes and Information Requirements." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management . February, 1976. Examines three tax approaches and a management system based on equal percentage treatment for discharges into a river. Examines empirical conditions for the Patuxent River in Maryland and assesses the equity and efficiency of each approach. The article found that information availability increased resource efficiency significantly but not impressively. There, it concluded, specific recommendations could not be made without further assess- ments of the transaction, administrative, and information costs of each approach. The article stated further that even less could be- concluded on equity comparisons. Johannesson, M. "Dynamic Aspects on the Use of Prices for Protecting the Environment." Swedish Journal of Economics . June, 1972. This article examines a tax approach to pollution control. The author notes that while it is possible in theory for optimal resource allocation to come about by an authority's first deter- mining the optimal reductions to be made by firms and then setting standards or taxes accordingly, in practice it would be difficult to do so. C-49 The author investigates whether an iterative procedure would lead to such an allocation under theoretical conditions. While finding that it would, he notes some factors that were not considered in his model and which might bear upon the outcome and which would use further study. Kneese, Allen V. and Karl-Goran Maler. "Bribes and Charges in Pollution Control: An Aspect of the Coase Controversy." Natural Resources Journal . October, 1973. Examines tax, subsidy, and mixed tax-subsidy approaches for pollution control. The article reviews the comparison between taxes and subsidies made previously in the literature. It notes some arguments claiming that there are differences between taxes and subsidies. The article contends that pure tax, pure subsidy, and mixed tax- subsidy approaches can all be made equivalent in terms of allo- cative effects. In particular, the problem of entry and exit can be dealt with by extending the system of taxes or subsidies in certain manners to firms that enter or leave the polluting industry. The authors note that nonetheless a subsidy approach that would yield optimal resource allocation would be unworkable in practice. They show the ability of a subsidy to reach optimal resource allo- cation in theory to point out in contrast how different existing subsidy programs are (especially the municipal wastewater treat- ment subsidy program) . They thus concur that in practice a Pigovian tax approach still seems the best approach. On page 712, the authors- conclude that "... in terms of attaining efficiency in an actually functioning program, the results of more than a decade of theoretical and empirical research since Coase 's article appear to point right back to the Pigovian approach-" Kraus, M. and H. Mobring. "Taxing Pollutees: A Comment." Kyklos 1974. Page 884. The article deals with a tax approach to pollution control. The article notes that one economist has argued that achieving efficiency through a tax approach would require taxing both those who impose pollution and those who receive pollution. The article examines this argument and concludes that the other economist CSerge-Christophe Kolm in "Les Pollues Doivent-ils Payer?" Kyklos , 1973, page 322) reached his conclusion by using a tax C-50 other than a Pigovian tax. A Pigovian tax, the article claims, will lead to efficiency if applied only to the imposers of externalities. Krier, James E. and W. David Montgomery. "Resource Allocation Information Cost and Form of Government Intervention." Natural Resources Journal . T anuary, 1973. Examines regulatory and incentive approaches in relation to environ- mental quality. The article discusses the relationship between concepts of property rights by societies and the forms of intervention by governments. The authors assert that as a resource becomes more valuable, it be- comes more economical to adopt forms of government intervention that have higher information costs so as to cut down on the al lo- cative inefficiencies (since these increase also as the resource becomes more valuable) . Uniform regulatory approaches are seen as having low information costs because of their simplicity while pricing approaches have higher information costs but offer efficiency gains. Still, the information costs of pricing approaches are lower than the infor- mation costs for regulatory approaches that would yield allocative efficiency (i.e., case specific standards for each source). The authors also note some reasons, however irrational, why pricing approaches have gained little acceptance. These include a public disinterest in theory, the influence of narrow special interest groups, and shortcomings in the government policymaking process. Mar, B.W. "A System of Waste Discharge Rights for the Management of Water Quality." Water Resources Research . 1971. Pages 1079-1086. This article examines the application of marketable permits to pollution control in water basins. The author examines existing policy on water discharge rights. He notes the information and administrative problems that regulations involve. The author advocates a system of marketable permits for discharges into river basins. To accommodate discharges by small polluters, the author suggests that some permits be sold to utilities who in turn will sell smaller amounts of discharge rights to small polluters or individuals. C-51 Marshall, Harold E. and Rosalie T. Ruegg. "Cost Sharing to Induce Efficient Techniques of Abating Wastewater Pollution." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management . December, 1975. Analyzes existing cost sharing (i.e., subsidy) programs for waste- water treatment grants administered by the EPA under the 1972 Amendments to the Federal Water Pollution Control Act. The article identifies and measures biases that lead to efficiency losses in resource allocation and technology choice. The article also develops a variant for cost sharing (i.e., making the percent- age subsidy the same for all techniques and aspects of costs to avoid distortions) that would eliminate the bias. It also notes some practical variants that would approximate the condition of neutral subsidy between technologies even though perfect neutrality might not be attainable in practice. Page, Talbot. "Failure of Bribes and Standards for Pollution Abatement." Natural Resources Journal . October, 1973. Examines subsidies, taxes, and regulatory standards for pollution control. The article reviews the literature that has concluded that subsidies and taxes are different only in their distributive effects and that regulations and taxes are similar if regulation is set optimally. The article examines what happens when free entry and exit are con- sidered and what happens to equity when controls are implemented. The article concludes that regulatory standards are made inefficient by opportunities for entry and exit of firms. Entry and exit opportunities also make subsidies inefficient. Changes in the sub- sidy approach would also do little to overcome these problems. The tax system is found best in terms of efficiency and equity. Rose. M. "Market Problems in the Distribution of Emission Rights." Water Resources Research . 1973. Pages 1132-1144. The article discusses a marketable permits approach and notes some implications for optimal direct regulation. The author analyzes a system of marketable permits and argues that given sufficient knowledge of the bidding strategies of firms, the pollution control authority could infer firms' marginal treatment cost functions from bidding behavior and then may be able to imple- ment an optimal solution of regulatory discharge standards for each firm. C-52 Russell, C.S. and IV. J. Vaughan. "On Taxation as a Pollution Control Policy: A Comment." Swedish Journal of Economics , Number 2, 1975, This article deals with tax and regulatory approaches to pollution control. The emphasis is on theoretical analysis but with refer- ence to conditions that may be found in actual practice. The authors note the condition of fixed proportions mentioned by Byrne and Spiro and contend that it is not likely to occur often in practice. The authors conclude that effluent charges will lead to least cost situations in pollution control though they will not lead to cer- tainty on the level of pollution reduction when the pollution con- trol authority lacks information on the marginal cost reduction or damage schedules for firms. If the marginal cost reduction curve shifts exogeneously, effluent charges will still lead to least cost situations. A regulatory approach, they argue, will guarantee the outcome in terms of pollution reduction but not the cost. If the marginal cost reduction curve shifts exogeneously, effluent charges will still lead to least cost situations. A regulatory approach, they argue, will gurantee the outcome in terms of pollution reduction but not the cost if the marginal cost reduction curve shifts exogenous ly. The authors note further that the real world is not static and not fully described by static models. The choice between taxes and regulations is not as clear as once thought. It is a choice between one imperfect option and another. They note also the need for regulatory standards when toxics capable of causing harm through short-term exposures are involved. Smith, V. Kerry. "A Note on Effluent Charges and Market Structure." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management . April, 1976. Examines efficiency from approaches in the presence of product market distortions. The article concludes that when there is more than one external diseconomy, the number of policy instruments needed to achieve optimal resource allocation will be at least equal to the number of external diseconomies that are to be corrected. In the case of pollution and product market distortions, two approaches -- e.g., an effluent tax and a product subsidy -- will be needed for efficiency. The article notes, also, that equity considerations may arise through the impact of pollution control approaches on the prices of products that are consumed by different classes of consumers. C-53 Taylor, C. Robert. "A Regional Market for Rights to Use Fertilizer as a Means of Achieving Water Quality Standards." Journal of Environ- mental Economics and Management . September, 1975. Examines one possible arrangement of marketable permits for fertilizer use to control water pollution. Compares this with a tax approach on fertilizer and examines empirical evidence for nitrogen fertilizer in Illinois. The article concludes that the effects of marketable permits and tax approaches would be the same if no permits were purchased by nonusers of fertilizer. It notes differences, however: • There are different options for nonusers to influence the amount of fertilizer used. • The effects of adapting the approaches to year-to-year changes in economic conditions and social values are different. • The permit approach allows more precise and certain achieve- ment of control over the total amount of fertilizer applied. In addition, the article notes that regional programs would face problems of bootlegging for any approach involving permits or taxes. A national program, though, would not. On page 17, the article states: "The cost of various enforcement schemes and expected compliance for the tax and rights (permits) policies as well as other relevant policies need to be determined so that the net social benefits of each policy can be computed. It appears to this author that such research will have to be based more on speculation and judgement than on objective economic research. " Nonetheless, the article notes, a rights (permits) policy would cost less than a per acre restriction (a favorite proposal among some administrators) to enforce. Tietenberg, T.H. "Controlling Pollution by Price and Standard Systems A General Equilibrium Analysis." Swedish Journal of Economics . June, 1973. The article deals with tax and regulatory approaches in what is generally a theoretical analysis. C-54 The author contends that the argument by Baumol and Oates for adoption of a standards and prices system depends on the existence of a parti- cular functional relationship between emissions and pollution concen- trations that is not found in actual environmental situations. For example, it is noted that the damage from one unit of pollution is different if emitted from a source downstream from a community than if emitted from a source upstream from a community. The author proposed a certain generalization of the Baumol and Oates proposal that takes into account his objections while retaining some of the advantages of the original proposal. Yohe, Gary W. "Substitution and the Control of Pollution: A Comparison of Effluent Charges and Quality Standards Under Uncertainty." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management . December, 1976. Examines taxes and subsidies in relation to pollution control. The article finds three sources of asymmetry between the impacts of tax and subsidy approaches. These are: • In the short run, it is difficult to determine the proper reference point for subsidies because polluters have an incen- tive to increase initial pollution levels to qualify for greater subsidies. • In the long run, dealing with exit from and entry into an industry is difficult in the case of subsidies. • Because subsidies will form a discontinuous function, they will make the marginal cost curve for firms discontinuous. In the long run, this will lead to greater production of the product and thus of pollution than would a tax approach. C-55 BIBLIOGRAPHY This bibliography lists a number of further references on alternative approaches to regulation. It is not intended to be comprehensive but lists references that account for a large portion of the research pub- lished in recent years on this subject. Adar, Zari and James M. Griffin. "Uncertainty and the Choice of Pollution Control Instruments." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management , October 1976 . American Enterprise Institute. Consumer Class Actions . 1977. . Waterway User Charges . 1977 • Amihud, Y. "The Efficiency of Taxes and Subsidies in Reducing Emissions by a Risk-Averse Firm." Kyklos . 1976- Anderson, D.R. "The National Flood Insurance Program -- Problems and Potential." Journal of Risk Insurance . December 1974. Arnold, D.F. and E. Petri. "Cost Reductions Through Tax Provisions for Pollution Control Facilities: What the R§D Men Should Know." English Economist . July-August 1974. Baumol, W.J., S. Rose-Ackerman, J.W. Sawyer, Jr., and D.W. Henderson. The Uncertain Search for Environmental Quality . New York : The Free Press, 19 74. and S.A. Batey-Blackman. "Emissions Permits vs. Effluent Charges.' Unpublished mimeo, 1978. and W.E. Oates . Economics, Environmental Policy and Quality of Life . Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice Hall, forthcoming. and W.E. Oates. The Theory of Environmental Policy. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice Hall, 1975. and W.E. Oates. "The Use of Standards and Prices for Protection of the Environment." Swedish Journal of Economics , 73, 1971, pp. 42-54. Boyd, J. Hayden. "Pollution Charges Income and the Costs of Water Quality Management." Water Resources Research . August 1971. Bramhall, D.F. and E. S. Mills. "A Note on the Asymmetry Between Fees and Bribes." Water Resources Research , July-September 1966. "Alternative Methods of Improving Stream Quality: An Economic and Policy Analysis." Water Resources Research . Third Quarter, 1966 Buchanan, J.M. and G. Tullock. "Polluters' Profits and Political Response: Direct Controls Versus Taxes." American Economic Review. March 19 75. C-56 Byrne, R.F. and M. H. Spiro. "On Taxation as a Pollution Control Policy." Swedish Journal of Economics . March 1973. Calabresi, G. "The Decision for Accidents: An Approach to Nonfault Allocation of Costs." Harvard Law Review . 1965. Chelius, James Robert. Workplace Safety and Health: The Role of Workmen's Compensation . American Enterprise Institute. 1977. Clotfelter, C.T. "Public Services, Private Substitutes, and the Demand for Protection Against Crime." American Economic Review . December 1977. Dales, J.H. Pollution, Property and Prices . Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1968. DeLucia, R.J. An Evaluation of Marketable Effluent Permit Systems . Washington: Office of Research § Development, Environmental Protection Agency, 1974. Dewees, D.N. and W.A. Sims. "The Symmetry of Effluent Charges and Subsidies for Pollution Control." Canadian Journal of Economics . May 1976. Dorcey, A.H. "Effluent Charges, Information Generation and Bargaining Behavior." Natural Resources Journal . January 1973. Elliott, R.D. "Economic Study of the Effect of Municipal Sewer Surcharges of Industrial Wastes and Water. Usage ." Water Resources Research . October 1973. Ferrar, I. A. "Progressive Taxation as a Policy for Water Quality Manage- ment." Water Resources Research . June 1973. Fishelson, Gideon. "Emission Control Policies Under Uncertainty." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management . October 1976. Freeh, H.E. III. "Pricing of Pollution: The Coase Theorem in the Long Run." Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science . Spring 1973. Freeman, A. Myrick III and Robert H. Haveman. "Clean Rhetoric and Dirty Water." The Public Interest . Summer 1972. Goldie, L.F. "Amenities Rights -- Parallels to Pollution Taxes." Natural Resources Journal . April 19 71. . "Pollution and Liability Problems Connected with Deep-Sea Mining." Natural Resources Journal . April 1972. Griffin, J.M. "An Econometric Evaluation of Sulfur Taxes." Journal of Political Economy . July/August 1974. Herzog, Henry W. "Economic Efficiency and Equity in Water Quality Control: Effluent Taxes and Information Requirements." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management . February 1976. Jackson, R. "Corrective Taxes and Pollution Control." Nebraska Journal of Economics and Business. Winter 19 72. C-57 Johannesson, M. "Dynamic Aspects on the Use of Prices for Protecting the Environment." Swedish Journal of Economics . June 1972. Kneese, A.V. and B.T. Bower. Managing Water Quality: Economics, Technology , Institutions . Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press for Resources for the Future, 1968. and Karl-Goran Maler. "Bribes and Charges in Pollution Control: An Aspect of the Coase Controversy." Natural Resources Journal . October 1973. and C. Schultze. Pollution, Prices and Public Policy. Washington: Brookings Institution, 1975. Kraus, M. and H. Mohring. "The Role of Pollutee Taxes in Externality Problems." Economica . May 1975. "Taxing Pollutees: A Comment." Kyklos , 1974. Krier, James E. and W. David Montgomery. "Resource Allocation Information Cost and the Form of Government Intervention." Natural Resources Journal . January 19 73. Lave, L.B. and E.P. Seskin. Air Pollution and Human Health . Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press for Resources for the Future, 1977. Lusky, R. "Optimal Taxation Policies for Conservation and Recycling." Journal of Economic Theory . December 1975. Mackintosh, D.R. The Economics of Airborne Emissions: The Case for an Air Rights Market . New York: Praeger, 1973. Mar, B.W. "A System of Waste Discharge Rights for the Management of Water Quality." Water Resource Research 7, 1971, pp. 1079-1086. Marshall, Harold E. and Rosalie T. Ruegg. "Cost Sharing to Induce Efficient Techniques of Abating Wastewater Pollution." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management . December 1975. Meade , J . E . The Theory of Economic Externalities: The Control of Environ- mental Pollution and Similar Social Costs . Geneva: A.W. Si jthof- Leiden, 1973, pp. 65-66. Montgomery, W.D. "Markets in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs." Journal of Economic Theory . December 1972. National Academy of Sciences. Air Quality and Automobile Emission Control , vol. 4, The Costs and Benefits of Automobile Emission Control . Report by the Coordinating Committee on Air Quality Studies, National Academy of Engineering, serial no. 93-24. Washington: Government Printing Office, 1974. Nichols, Albert L. and Richard Zeckhauser. "Government Comes to the Workplace: An Assessment of OSHA." The Public Interest . Fall 1977. O'Connell, Jeffrey. "Extending the 'No-Fault' Idea." The Public Interest . Summer 1974. C-58 Orr, Lloyd. "Incentive for Innovation as the Basis for Effluent Charge Strategy." American Economic Review . May 1976. Page, Talbot. "Failure of Bribes and Standards for Pollution Abatement." Natural Resources Journal . October 1973. Peck, A.E. and O.C. Doering III. "Voluntarism and Price Response: Consumer Reaction to the Energy Shortage." Bell Journal of Economics . Spring 1976, Pepper, H.W. "Taxing Pollution." Bulletin of International Fiscal Docu- mentation . May 1973. Peterson, G.E. and H. Galper. "Tax Exempt Financing of Private Industry's Pollution Control Investment." Public Policy . Winter 1975. Peterson, Jerold M. "Estimating an Effluent Charge: The Reserve Mining Case." Land Economics . August 1977. Roberts, M.J. and M. Spence. "Effluent Charges and Licenses Under Uncer- tainty." Journal of Public Economics . April-May 19 76. Rose, M. "Market Problems in the Distribution of Emission Rights." Water Resources Research 9, 1973, pp. 1132-1144. Rose-Ackerman, S. "Effluent Charges: A Critique." Canadian Journal of Economics . November 19 73. Ruff, Larry E. "The Economic Common Sense of Pollution." The Public Interest . Spring 1970. Russell, C.S. and W.J. Vaughan. "On Taxation as a Pollution Control Policy: A Comment." Swedish Journal of Economics . 1975. Schultze, Charles L. The Public Use of Private Interest . Brookings Institution. 1977. Smith, V. Kerry. "A Note on Effluent Charges and Market Structure." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management . April 1976. Stephenson, J.B., ed. The Practical Application of Economic Incentives to the Control of Pollution: The Case of British Columbia . Vancouver : University of British Columbia Press, 1977. Fox, I.K. "The Assessment of Pollution Control Policy Mechanisms: Some Basic Concepts," pp. 19-38. Lajzerowicz J. and P. Reilly-Roe. "The Technology and Economics of Alternative Control Mechanisms in the Smelting and Refining Industries," pp. 160-184. Nemetz, P.N. "Mining and Milling in British Columbia," pp. 105-159. Stephenson, J.B. "Alternative Pollution Control Mechanisms in the British Columbia Pulp and Paper Industry," pp. 213-234. . "Conclusion, Methodological Observations, and Key Issues," pp. 425-437, C-59 Taylor, C. Robert. "A Regional Market for Rights to Use Fertilizer as a Means of Achieving Water Quality Standards." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management . September 1975. Tietenberg, T.H. "Controlling Pollution by Price and Standard Systems: A General Equilibrium Analysis." Swedish Journal of Economics . June 1973. . "Specific Taxes and the Control of Pollution: A General Equilib- rium Analysis." Quarterly Journal of Economics . November 19 73. Tulkens, H. and F. Schoumaker. "Stability Analysis of an Effluent Charge and the 'Polluters Pay' Principle." Journal of Public Economics . August 1975. Tybout, R.A. "Pricing Pollution and Other Negative Externalities." The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science . Spring 1972. . "Pricing of Pollution: Reply." The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science . Spring 19 73. . "Pricing of Pollution: The Coase Theorem in the Long Run: Reply." Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science . Spring 1973. U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on Public Works and Transportation. Waterway User Charges . July 1977. U.S. Senate, Committee on the Environment and Public Works. Pollution Taxes, Effluent Charges, and Other Alternatives for Pollution Control : A Report . 1977 . Weitzman, W. "Prices vs. Quantities." Review of Economic Studies 4, 1974, pp. 477-491. Wenders, J.T. "Corrective Taxes and Pollution Abatement." Journal of Law and Economics . October 19 73. "Pollution Control -- Uses of Corrective Taxes Reconsidered." Natural Resources Journal . January 1972. . "Profit Maximization, Pollution Abatement, and Corrective Pollution Taxes." Journal of Economic Issues . September 19 72. Wertz, K.L. "Short-Run Effects of an Increased Effluent Charge in a Competitive Market." Canadian Journal of Economics . November 1974. White, L.J. "Effluent Charges as a Faster Means of Achieving Pollution Abatement." Public Policy . Winter 1976. World Bank. Environment and Development . June 1975. Yohe, Gary W. "Substitution and the Control of Pollution: A Comparison of Effluent Charges and Quality Standards Under Uncertainty." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. December 1976. IMPACT OF REGULATION ON INDUSTRIAL LOCATION DECISIONS Prepared for: U.S. DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE The Assistant Secretary for Policy Office of Regulatory Economics and Policy Prepared by: CONSAD Research Corporation 121 North Highland Avenue Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania 15206 Purchase Order No. 8-36343 August 1978 D-3 IMPACT OF REGULATION ON INDUSTRIAL LOCATION DECISIONS Summary Purpose of the Paper The purpose of this paper is to investigate, primarily through a review of the literature, the extent to which clean air requirements may affect industrial location decisions. Both industrial sectors, as those seeking site locations, and urban and regional jurisdictions, as those providing them — and the problems and opportunities occasioned for both by the clean air legislation and its implementation — are to be considered. The clean air legislation is viewed, here, as an important regulatory activity, one which can yield insights into regulatory activities generally, and their influence upon the regional allocation of jobs and output, the inter- regional migration of industry, and the national economy. Just as the availability of raw materials and labor is considered and integrated in industrial location decisionmaking, government regulatory requirements may also be increasingly integrated into the decision process. Regulatory requirements exist for health, safety, land use, accessibility, and pollution control. Many of these requirements are to a great extent uniform, but may still have differential impacts across regions. The EPA air pollution regulations have potential for signifi- cantly affecting regions, since they have been developed on the basis of air quality measurements which show that the air over the U.S. is not of uniform cleanliness. The current status of these regulations is reviewed. We first ask: Why does it matter whether air pollution regulations affect the location of economic activity? This paper views the issue broadly. We have an obvious interest in jurisdictions and their reaction to the consequences of the Clean Air Act(s) for their future prosperity and health. We also are interested in the industries which are most heavily impacted by the clean air legisla- tion, the actions which they take in response to the Clean Air Act (CAA) , and how resulting changes in productivity and employment affect the jur- isdictions in which they currently produce their output. While, apparently, only a small percentage of growth and change in urban employ- ment is the result of industrial migration, per se, we need to better understand the processes by which industry and jurisdictions grow and change together — movers and stayers, alike. Relevance of the Topic There are at least three reasons why this subject is of particular importance at this time: First, given the increasing interest in modifying and/or ameliorating those aspects of regulation which unduly constrain economic efficiency D-4 and/or foster "unproductive" inflationary consequences, it is clearly time to look across the board to facets of air pollution legislation, the weakening of which would not "unduly" harm air quality. Thus, we are likely to be entering a period of interest in trading off "unreasonable" and uneconomical cost changes relative to the resulting changes in environmental quality. Second, is the increasing interest in utilizing market-like price systems and a wide variety of economic incentives to replace the direct regulatory approach which utilizes set standards of behavior or maximum allowable amounts of discharge for particular pollutants and industries. Differentiated from subsidy-like incentives to induce investment in pollution control facilities (for example) , pollution charges systems have been recommended as a cost-effective means of achieving environ- mental quality goals because, with each charge, each source decides how much to control on the basis of its own control costs. Relative to locational decisions, either for movers or stayers, the possibility of a market for the "right to pollute" is becoming a more feasible alter- native, both legislatively and institutionally. The third reason is the interrelated set of structural and cyclical conditions affecting the Nation's urban areas in which — as stated by the President's Urban and Regional Policy Group ( Cities and People in Distress , 1978) : "... Far too many city residents . . . have no jobs and lack adequate incomes, housing, services and other amenities, and are isolated in deteriorated neighborhoods .... Net loss of jobs, especially foot-loose manufacturing jobs, threatens the economy and tax base of many large and small industrial cities which have thinned out . " The Urban and Regional Policy Group recognized that many, many factors have combined to create the 1970s outmigration, job losses, and fiscal imbalances of the Nation's center cities. Even environmental protection is viewed as fostering urban distress by alledgedly favoring the con- struction of new facilities over revitalization of old ones, unnecessarily constraining the use of urban sites, and unduly raising the costs (through inflexible standards) of doing business in center cities. State of the Art The profitability of business location decisions and the success of federal urban policy decisions depend upon the approaches to air quality taken by the various states and our knowledge about the impacts of air quality regulation on economic activity and the public. As stated above, air pollution regulations may have significant impacts across regions because the air over the U.S. is not of uniform cleaniness. Even if the air were uniform the variety of state approaches to achieving emissions control and air quality will cause differential impacts across states. Under the existing legislation there is still the basic D-5 requirement that states and regions make some decisions and set some policies about the type of growth they wish to experience and the types of firms they wish to attract. The existing variety of state approaches has presented a problem both to industries which desire to relocate and to each state industrial development agency which must be able to argue the pros and cons of their own state's approach versus that of every other state. Now more than ever the industrial development agency will be coordinating with the air pollution agency in each state, if for no other reason than the need to follow closely the monitoring data which tells them what is an attainment and what is a non-attainment area in their state . A state with a short timetable for achieving National Ambient Air Quality Standards (and/or air quality standards requiring cleaner air than NAAQS) would be a state with high potential regulatory costs, and one which a firm might hesitate to consider for relocation. The logic of the CAA favors selection among states with longer achievement time- tables. It also favors choice of very small sites which could involve only one monitor, possibly a monitor some distance from the proposed site. One activity in which the impact of regulatory action on regional growth should be discernible is in the decision process of individual firms. The question is: Did or did not the existence of the regulatory agency /mechanism play a role in the decision? If the location decision is made by a reasonably objective documented process, and regulations are considered to be a factor, then these regulations are, in fact, impacting on regional growth. In 1954 a survey of 350 manufacturers was taken in which respondents were asked to rank the importance of various factors in their location decisions. The table on the next page shows only one firm considered laws and regulations of primary importance. Apparently no comparable survey has been taken since, so that we can only guess at what the results would be today. More recent studies on the issue have not been able to reach definitive conclusions. Some results indicate that pollution control factors have had a marginal but significant effect on locational shifts of heavy polluting industries. Also, as one study found, there is a tradeoff between two categories of pollution control, technological abatement and locational choice. Cost savings are possible by finding the proper balance between the two. Nevertheless, it is still too early to know how the clean air require- ments will ultimately affect urban and regional economies. This will be determined by many decisions yet to be made. But it is certainly worth- while to speculate on the effects of clean air requirements on actual or prospective industrial location decisions. Firms seeking site locations and jurisdictions providing them will presumably be obliged to establish common ground with regard to these regulations before many other considerations can be weighed. D-6 Relative Importance of Factors in Industrial Location (from 350 Weighted Returns) Factor 1st 2nd 3rd 4th Total Percent 5th Points Weighted Market 118 44 35 24 13 928 18.9 Labor 33 78 45 34 31 711 14.5 Raw Materials 73 36 18 17 8 605 12.3 Building 26 28 29 15 9 368 7.5 Site 18 30 22 14 25 329 6.7 Transportation 14 32 32 31 22 378 7.7 Distribution 10 25 37 31 20 343 7.0 Living Conditions 14 11 29 35 35 306 6.2 Climate 11 8 11 22 25 189 3.9 Industrial Fuel 3 12 20 14 14 165 3.4 Water 3 7 12 10 8 107 2.2 Industrial Power 3 14 15 11 95 1.9 Financial Help 8 7 7 7 5 108 2.2 Taxes 5 5 3 14 22 104 2.1 Laws & Regulations 1 2 5 6 14 54 1.1 Miscellaneous 15 5 2 1 4 107 2.2 Source: Survey by Industrial Economics Research Division, Texas Engineering Experiment Station, Texas A&M University, October 1954. One important impact of the CAA could well be the discouragement of firms from going through the process of looking for new sites, since they will have to negotiate with a state or city on the site and then review their alternatives. Only after a firm has submitted a proposed emissions inven- tory will a state be able to identify definite sites which could be acceptable . The concern of municipalities over the 1977 CAA is partly a reflection of traditional struggles between city, suburban, and state level factors. Today, any plant which is thinking of leaving a central city must consider that the alternative costs of air pollution control would not necessarily be much lower even if the plant proposed to move to an attainment area. If the plant's emissions could cause the air quality elsewhere to degrade beyond the allowable increment, then the plant would be required to install best available control technology or to seek yet another site. While the complexity of environmental regulations could be a deterrent to a firm in deciding whether to move, the regulations are going to impinge on the firm whether it moves or not. Considerable flexibility may exist for tradeoffs or offset arrangements among movers and stayers, creating a new industrial mix within allowable constraints. There is no indication that air pollution requirements are going to be tougher for stayers than for movers. D-7 Concluding Remarks We have covered a variety of subjects in this paper and, unfortunately, have reached no definitive conclusions about the locational effects and further downstream consequences of the clean air legislation, particu- larly the CAA of 1977. The literature we have reviewed is, indeed, sparse as it relates to the specific question (s) of the treatment and control of the attendant costs of air pollution standards on "industrial location" (or, even more broadly, the geographical deployment of employment and output) . Why is the empirical data and analysis so sparse? Perhaps too short a period has passed. Perhaps the analytic problem is too complex and no one has been able to formulate it very well. Similarly for data bases: Which make the most sense? Many, many gaps in an "ideal" data system exist. This work has led us to the following conclusions: • This is an ideal time to begin to monitor the impacts of an important regulatory activity, i.e., the CAA and its implemen- tation. The logic of the CAA is such that we can anticipate that it will most likely have substantial locational effects — but we may never get to know these. We are not ready to measure, estimate, or project these consequences; the analytic concepts have not been fleshed out and the data bases are almost surely inadequate . • The work to date — by government agencies, academics and industry — on the consequences (on industrial location) of clean air and other environmental legislation, is: not convincing; difficult to assemble; and probably not useful for estimating the future consequences. • If industrial location is_ affected, in a substantial way for some sectors and in some places, as we expect it will, it will have both microeconomic impacts (i.e., on economic efficiency) and, possibly, macroeconomic effects (i.e., on jobs and output). Prices and costs would be affected in either case. • Even if the CAA has substantial locational consequences, we are unable to conclude whether benefits from the Act exceed its costs; however, it would be worthwhile to begin to measure these costs and, where benefits would not be affected, find ways to mitigate unintended locational misallocation effects. D-9 TABLE OF CONTENTS Page 1.0 SCOPE AND OBJECTIVES OF REPORT D-ll 1.1 Impacts on the Economy (Generally) and Location (Specifically) D-12 1.2 Potential Impacts of Air Pollution and Other Regulations on Industrial Location: Trans- portation Regulations as an Illustration D-15 1.3 Strategies for Location Decisions to Incorporate Regulatory Requirements D-17 1.4 Need for Better Theory and Data on Industrial Location Decisions: Why We Should Care D-18 2.0 POTENTIAL IMPACTS OF CLEAN AIR ACTS ON INDUSTRIAL LOCATION D-21 2.1 The Act and State Variations D-21 2.2 Concepts in 1977 CAA Which Are Relevant to Industrial Growth D-24 2.2.1 Significant Deterioration D-24 2.2.2 Attainment and Non-Attainment D-24 2.2.3 Enforcement D-26 2.3 Requirements for States and Other Agencies D-27 2.3.1 Designation of Classes of Areas D-27 2.3.2 State Implementation Plans D-27 2.3.3 Cost Analysis of Alternate Locations D-27 2.3.4 Meteorologic Modeling D-28 2.4 Probable Requirements for Firms D-28 2.5 Importance of Geographic Scale in Corporate Location Decisions: How to Compare Potential Regulatory Costs D-28 2.5.1 Comparison and Selection of Multistate Regions with Respect to Air Quality And/ Or Regulatory Stringency D-29 2.5.2 Review and Selection of Specific Sites With Respect to Pollution Control Costs and Other Costs D-29 2.5.3 Iterative Decisionmaking and Reconsideration of Alternatives: The Use of Decision Models D-30 2.6 How Serious Can the Impacts of These Regulations Be? D-31 3.0 USE OF ANALYTIC DECISIONMAKING LOCATIONAL MODELS D-37 3.1 Models to Examine Regional Economic Effects D-37 3.2 Use of Various Models to Build Regulatory Requirements Into Location Decisions D-48 3.3 Strategies for Adding Regulatory Constraints to Location Models, and for Model Applications D-50 D-10 TABLE OF CONTENTS (continued) Page 3.3.1 Improving the Decision Process by Extending Models and by Linking Models with Other Techniques D-50 3.3.2 Applications of Models by State and Local Agencies to Analyze Alternative Sites D-50 3.3.3 Applications of Models by Private Location Advisory Firms, Railroads and Private Industrial Site Developers D-51 3.4 Interindustry Models in Location Decisions and Their Potential for Incorporating Regulatory Requirements D-51 3.5 Normative Approaches D-51 4.0 PREDICTING THE IMPORTANCE OF FEDERAL REGULATIONS IN SPECIFIC LOCATION DECISIONS D-55 4.1 Review and Prediction of the Role of Federal Regulations in Location Decisions D-56 4.2 Consideration of Specific Types of Industry D-56 4.2.1 The Industry List from 1977 CAA D-56 4.3 Review of Cost and Impact Data D-57 5.0 CONCLUDING REMARKS D-64 APPENDIX: Annotated Bibliography D-67 INDEX D-175 D-ll 1.0 SCOPE AND OBJECTIVES OF REPORT The purpose of this paper is to investigate, primarily through a re- view of the literature, the extent to which clean air requirements may affect actual or prospective industrial location decisions. Both indus- trial sectors, as those seeking site locations, and urban and regional jurisdictions, as those providing them — and the problems and opportuni- ties occasioned for both by the clean air legislation and its implementation — are to be considered. The clean air legislation is viewed, here, as an important regulatory activity, one which can yield insights into regulatory activities generally, and their influence upon the regional allocation of jobs and output, the interregional migration of industry, and the national economy. We have placed our primary emphasis upon providing logical step-by- step procedures by which Federal regulatory requirements may be compared with and related to social, economic, and demographic factors in analyzing industrial location and development. The procedure will thus be described in the context of location decisions by industrial executives, i.e., the industrial location decision, as well as the decisions of those affecting the provision of available sites for industrial location. Many industrial siting factors are considered by the decisionmakers: even recognizing that the decision process for any firm and/or jurisdiction is never ideally "comprehensive" and "objective," we will study both normative ("ideal") approaches, as well as more realistic, verifiable industrial location decisionmaking. Just as the availability of raw materials and labor is considered and integrated in industrial location decisionmaking, government regulatory requirements may also be increasingly integrated into the decision process. Regulatory requirements exist for health, safety, land use, accessibility, and pollution control. Many of these requirements are to a great extent uniform, but may still have differential impacts across regions. The Environmental Protection Agency's (EPA) air pollution regulations have potential The specific contractual charge was that: The Contractor shall prepare a paper that will review the literature, specifically on the impact of clean air requirements on actual or prospective industrial location decisions. It will review and summarize significant problems encountered by specific urban areas and industries. The review of the analyses shall take the form of an annotated bibliography. It shall include descrip- tions of assumptions, methodology, and findings. Problems faced by regions, urban areas, and municipalities shall be documented in a separate section. Based upon this review, a narrative statement of the actual and potential effects of regulations on urban growth will be prepared as the text of the paper, with the bibliography and other materials as appendices. D-12 for significantly affecting regions, since they have been developed on the basis of air quality measurements which show that the air over the United States is not of uniform cleanliness (Morgenstern, et. al. , 1975).* The current status of these regulations is reviewed in Section 2.0. We first ask: Why does it matter whether air pollution regulations affect the location of economic activity? Sections 1.1 through 1.4 present some answers to this question. 1.1 Impacts on the Economy (Generally) and Location (Specifically) Ranging from being broadly villified as being at the heart of the decline of U.S. productivity and preeminence (Fowler, 1978; Weidenbaum, 1978) to being generously praised as producing "general economic benefits" (Bell, 1978) , almost every shade of opinion exists about the benefits and costs, advantages and disadvantages, and pros and cons of Federal legisla- tion dealing with the regulation of pollution and toxic substances (Clean Air Act, 1970, 1977; Federal Water Pollution Control Act, 1972, 1977; Occupational Safety and Health Act, 1970; Toxic Substances Act, 1976; Federal Food, Drug, and Cosmetic Act, "1958, 1962; Federal Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act and the Federal Environmental Pesticide Control Act, 1972; Safe Drinking Water Act, 1974; and the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act, 1976) . Focusing, primarily, on the Clean Air requirements, most of the commentators have been more selective in their appraisal of the Act(s) , both to date and as to prospective future effects: • "Macro" effects on national output, investment, productivity, price levels, and employment (Chao and Dossani, 1976; Chase Econometric, 1975; Council on Environmental Quality, 1974, 1975; Dolde, et al. , 1977; Kane, 1974; Petersen, 1973; Train, 1974; Senate Committee on Public Works, 1974); • "Micro" effects on the economic efficiency of industry, generally (Patrick, 1974; Speer, 1977; Wagner, 1974); • Effects on municipalities, other local and regional jurisdictions and geographical areas, as well as on "urban form" (Barro, 1977; Freund, 1975; Miernyk and Sears, 1974; Popper, 1978; Schuler, 1974); • Consequences for "small businesses" (National Association of Manufacturers, 1974; Joint Economic Committee, 1978); • Frequency of "controls-caused" plant closings and decreased jobs consequences (Freund, 1975; Mohr, 1978) ; * References cited in this manner are contained in the annotated bibliography attached to this paper (Appendix A) . D-13 • Income distribution/ equity consequences in impacted jurisdiction (Collins, 1974*); and • Consequences for industrial location industry issues related to energy-producing sites (Birch, 1978; Pennsylvania, Governor's Science Advisory Committee, 1976; Meyer and Leone, 1978; Nijkamp and Paelinck, 1973) . We shall see, below, how the last of these — the "locational" impact — can be of a sufficiently substantial concern, in "micro," "macro," and distributional terms. However, in order to portray the full (potential) impacts of the Clean Air Act, we need to consider "location" in its most comprehensive meaning. Not only shall location mean an employer's decision and act to initiate a new enterprise in a place and/or to relocate an existing one; in addition, we wish to consider the decision to expand and/ or contract output and employment in a place, as a decision — at the margin — to stay instead of moving. We are also concerned with the impact of the Act on the movement, mobility, and expansion/contraction of mobile factors of production (e.g., labor, population, entrepreneurs, capital, technology /know-how, etc.), since these impact, both directly and indirectly, on macro and micro, areal and sectoral, output and employment. Thus, we view our charter here broadly. We have an obyious interest in jurisdictions and their reaction to the consequences of the Clean Air Act(s) for their future prosperity and health. We, also, are interested in the industries which are most heavily impacted by the clean air legisla- tion, the actions which they take in response to the Act, and how resulting changes in productivity and employment affect the jurisdictions in which they currently produce their output. While, apparently, only a small per- centage of growth and change in urban employment is the result of industrial migration, per se, (Birch, 1978) we need to better understand the processes by which industry and jurisdictions grow and change together — movers and stayers, alike. An illustration of the complexity of the location process is the impact of the clean air legislation on the siting of generating stations, e.g., at fuel resource location versus near the area of consumption. Impacts both on coal production and utilization, as well as on co-sited production facilities, can be clearly seen. Another "locational" consequence, one alleged by the hard-liners to affect jobs and output, is the unusual impact of retrofitting of air pollution equipment on plants, with relatively short remaining lives, to meet emission standards. Other related "locational" impacts concern: the appropriate policy and its implementation regarding the siting of new plants in non-attainment areas; the integration of the implementation of air pollution policies with those of water pollution and land use; administrative techniques for easing the burden of nonperformance of new technologies utilized by industry; the encouragement of pollution control R&D which has different consequences by industry and region; and administrative methods permitting "reasonable and necessary growth" in the * This is a water pollution control-related study. D-14 utilization of coal, which is encouraged as part of the President's first National Energy Policy. There are at least three reasons why this subject is of particular importance at this time. For one, given the increasing interest in modifying and/or ameliorating those aspects of regulation which unduly constrain economic efficiency and/ or foster "unproductive" inflationary consequences, it is clearly time to look. across the board to facets of air pollution legislation, the weakening of which would not "unduly" harm air quality. Thus, we are likely to be entering a period of interest in trading off "unreasonable" and uneconomical cost changes relative to the resulting changes in environmental quality. A second and related reason is the increasing interest in utilizing market-like price systems and a wide variety of economic incentives to replace the direct regulatory approach, which utilize set standards of behavior or maximum allowable amounts of discharge for particular pollutants and industries (Anderson, Kneese, Taylor, Reed, and Stevenson, 1978; Blair, 1973; Bower, 1978; Comolli, 1974, 1977; Irwin and Liroff , 1974) . Differen- tiated from subsidy-like incentives to induce investment in pollution control facilities (for example) , pollution charges systems have been recommended as a cost-effective means of achieving environmental quality goals because, with each charge, each source decides how much to control on the basis of its own control costs. Relative to locational decisions, either for movers or stayers, the possibility of a market for the "right to pollute" is be- coming a more feasible alternative, both legislatively and institutionally, giving rise to our increased interest in this paper. A third reason for increasing interest at this time in the subject of locational impacts of environmental regulation concerns the interrelated set of structural and cyclical conditions affecting the Nation's urban areas in which — as stated by the President's Urban and Regional Policy Group ( Cities and People in Distress , 1978) : "...Far too many city residents. . .have no jobs and lack adequate incomes, housing, services, and other amenities, and are isolated in deteriorated neighbor- hoods.... Net loss of jobs, especially foot- loose manufacturing jobs , threatens the economy and tax base of many large and small industrial cities which have thinned out." The Urban and Regional Policy Group recognized that many, many factors have combined to create the 1970' s outmigration, job losses, and fiscal * EPA's proposed weakening of certain water pollution rules (August 10, 1978) , for industries which EPA has determined it would be economically "unreasonable" to require compliance, are alleged not to "harm water quality. " D-15 imbalances of the Nation's center cities. Even environmental protection is viewed as fostering urban distress by alledgedly favoring the construction of new facilities over revitalization of old ones, unnecessarily constrain- ing the use of urban sites, and unduly raising the costs (through inflexible standards) of doing business in center cities. Compounding this problem facing the vast majority of our urban jurisdictions is the increasingly apparent fact that the condition of the basic infrastructure, which is necessary for the economical operation of these areas and their industries, is in a very poor, undermaintained state. Billions of dollars of needed jnaintenance, renovation, and reconditioning is the bill facing thousands of jurisdictions, partly due to inflation, partly to the "political process" and other institutional factors, and partly to the very fragile state and local budget picture. The impact of air and water pollution requirements on the capital- raising capacities of local governments is one of the reasons for our interest, here, on the locational consequences of the environmental legislation. During the seventies, and preparatory to the next decade, a number of both macro- and micro specif ic market studies have set the stage by placing the state and local financing demand/supply situation within the context of the national capital market. Questions about capital availability, access, and costs have been raised, looking at components of this overall market, for specific types of securities, types of public investment, regions of the Nation, and other less macroapproaches (Petersen and Galper, 1970; Kummerfeld and Petersen, 1973) . Clearly, the role and use of tax exempts differs now from what it was a decade earlier: options for alternatives (e.g., Federal funding, use of own resources, etc.) are more available; "public" and "private" invest- ment and tax-exempt/ taxable debt are less clearly separable conceptually, legally, and institutionally; there is increasing privatization of the use of "public purpose" instruments; and forces and trends are changing within each of the public investment functional areas, as well as increasing interest in specific markets, e.g., private developer subdivisions, energy boom towns, depressed areas, and others. Thus, our interest in locational consequences is rooted in a variety of reasons, ranging from current pressing problems to opportunities and potential for the future. That environmental regulation can have locational consequences is not unique — since, as we shall observe in the next section, other forms of governmental regulation have already had far-reaching loca- tional consequences. 1.2 Potential Impacts of Air Pollution and Other Regulations on Industrial Location: Transportation Regulations as an Illustration One of the oldest forms of government regulation involves intervention in the transport industries: this regulatory activity serves, here, as an illustration that regulation can have important locational consequences . D-16 Federal regulations have had a continuing impact on industrial growth and where that growth takes place since the evolution of the control of rail freight rates during the post civil war period. Transportation regu- lations rapidly became so complex that there would be considerable difficulty in analyzing specific regional emphases within any commodity or group of commodities. Such analyses have been accomplished, however, with respect to the impact of rail freight rates and the impact of interline transfers and basing point pricing on regional growth. Thus, there is an historical record — albeit partial and very crude at best — of the impacts of certain regulatory activity on regional growth. Clearly, this record is continuing, so that it would be astonishing if new regulations which are based on geographic phenomena such as air pollution did not have some differential regional impact. The question arises of whether it is plausible to look at transpor- tation regulation in order to draw insights about air pollution regulation. The answer is that both transportation and air pollution are essentially geographic phenomena: they show regional diversity, and they are affected, to greater or lesser extent, both by underlying physical geographic features (mountains, rivers) , and also by preexisting development (cities, farms) . Regulatory decisions interacted with the evolution of transportation systems, and it is likely that air pollution regulation is now interacting with the location pattern of industry. The Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC), for example, has played a key role in approving rates which rail companies charge to their customers, and to each other. The Hoch-Smith Resolution in 1926 instructed the ICC to take into consideration, in "adjusting" freight rates, the economic conditions prevailing in industries subject to the rates. The rule of ratemaking adopted by Congress in 1933 instructed the ICC to give consideration, inter alia, to the effect of rates on the movement of traffic. Hence, there is a long history of ratemaking in which the ICC has explicitly considered economic conditions and ability to pay as major factors in prescribing rates. Although Congress has not (until the 3R (Regional Rail Reorganization Act of 1973, PL 93-236) and 4R (Railroad Revitalization and Regulatory Reform Act of 1976, PL 94-210) Acts) directly subsidized firms providing rail freight transpor- tation service, it has permitted large elements of cross-subsidy to persist in the freight rate structure. For rail passenger service, the ICC has depended heavily on cross-subsidy to sustain services which quite clearly have been unable to pay their own way. In regulating truck transportation, the Commission has applied its concept of balanced transportation to assure a wide geographic uniformity of service and rates, which has had much to do with the shift of industry away from downtown or near downtown to surburban locations or locations even farther away. Cross-subsidy and control over entry has made this possible. One may argue the economic soundness of such a policy but, clearly, it is consistent with (original) congressional attempts to afford opportunity to suburbs and to smaller and more remote communities to develop. D-17 However, despite the uses of regulation for developmental purposes and for equalizing growth opportunity over wide areas , there have been few efforts by the regulatory agencies to implement any overall economic schemes or plans, or even to study and assess the consequences of their decisions and activities. Each mode of transportation has been more or less dealt with sui generis , although the ICC has at times seemed to try to achieve a kind of division of labor among the modes which it regulates — rail, truck, inland and coastal water carriers, and freight forwarders. Ordinarily, however, this has more often resulted in duplication rather than coordination of service. Recognizing the importance of cross-subsidy to the continued provision of ubiquitous trucking service, the Commission has by its rate policies assured truckers access to high density flows. In turn, the Commission has hesitated to permit inland water carriers, which are the lowest cost carriers if only operating costs are considered, to make off with traffic which is lucrative to the railroads. But trying to strike a balance of revenues among the carriers and assuring small communities and small shippers transportation service is clearly not "coordinated planning," on the one hand, or the "invisible hand" of the market, on the other. Overall, there is much disenchantment with the complexity and obscurity of the rate system. The lesson to be learned by the new kinds of regulations is not that they have interregional impacts , but that these impacts could remain undiscoverable and unintended for many years. This need for foreseeing impacts brings us back to the main thread of this paper: impacts of current regulations, particularly environmental controls. 1.3 Strategies for Location Decisions to Incorporate Regulatory Requirements One activity in which the impact of regulatory action on regional growth should be discernible is in the decision process of individual firms. The question is: Did or did not the existence of the regulatory agency /mechanism play a role in the decision? If the location decision is made by a reasonably objective documented process, and regulations are considered to be a factor, then these regulations are, in fact, impacting on regional growth. It is neither desirable nor expected that the location decision be entirely objective and rational. Any given individual firm will have its own process for location decisionmaking, and the regulatory conditions will typically not be integrated in any standardized way across firms and across industries. The concept of an internalized formal environmental-economic benefit-cost analysis of alternative sites is, of course, a possibility but, in any case, such an analysis must still be fed into the decision process in some sense. The first question is: What effects will the regulatory con- straints have on the balance sheets for the facility if it is located at site A, site B, or elsewhere? And the second question is: How important managerially will these effects be relative to raw materials, markets, labor, business climate, and other factors? These are traditional questions, D-18 and each firm's approach to them is what distinguishes it from other firms. We are interested, here, in both these interfirm and intersectoral differences, as well as their similarities — and how these similar and dissimilar locational processes are being affected by the changing objectives and role of regulation, particularly that of air pollution control legislation. Approaching the location process in this manner clearly requires a "micro" decisionmaking perspective. 1.4 Need for Better Theory and Data on Industrial Location Decisions: Why We Should Care Another approach to discovering the impact of regulatory requirements on regional location, change, and growth is to study the data for regions on both regulatory requirements and their implementation, on the one hand, and industrial development on the other. There are substantial data on regional growth, but much less data exists on the degree of and/or direct impacts of regulations. Nevertheless, analyses need to be conducted as data supplies are improved, and these analyses should be performed to assist in our understanding of regional change experience, generally. One part of the present report (Section 3) will review some promising analytical approaches, and suggest some new ones . How can all of the multitude of factors which characterize a region, and which may enter very subtly into the corporate location decision, be compiled into a comprehensive regional industrial change analysis? The underlying structural connections among such factors are called regional growth theories. As might be expected, there are probably as many different theories as there are state industrial development commissions and agencies. In the present report, some general components of such theories, such as the attractiveness of environmental quality, the level of intergovernmental cooperation, and the "quality" of the labor force will be discussed briefly. These components should be developed by specific analyses, both at the industrial decision level, as well as at the statistical regional growth level. Then it would be possible to say more definitely whether and how regulatory constraints, such as air pollution regulations, help or hinder — or, at least, substan- tially affect — regional growth. The reasons we should care about these effects is, perhaps most impor- tantly, this: If these consequences are felt "regionally," that would mean that depending upon their magnitude, locational decisions by industry, which should be allocating resources to their highest valued uses (in time and place), would be interfered with and, in some cases, contravened entirely. How important this type of spatial misallocation is and/or could become — and whether or not it is even possible to measure the social costs of this misallocation — is a subject we shall only begin to discuss here. Hopefully, we will have initiated an important dialogue for, if the spatial misallocation is serious or could become serious, then what have become traditional environ- mentalist and EPA arguments that environmental regulations are not D-19 inflationary will have to be more critically reviewed. Apparently, the forthcoming National Commission on Air Quality believes the subject to be an open one because included in its agenda are these topics : ** • The extent to which maintenance (i.e., achievement) of air quality standards will "inhibit orderly growth" in non-attainment areas; and • The extent to which prevention of significant deteri- oration (PSD) of air quality will affect the growth and development of selected regions. These are issues both of economic efficiency and equity. A growing body of literature has developed relating improved — even "optimal" balancing — between industrial output, pollution controls and costs, and resulting community "real income," including the "value" of the cleaner environment to workers and the community at large (Blair, 1973; Ciriacy- Wantrup, 1971; Davis, et.al . , 1974; Forster, 1977; Kamien and Schwartz, 1977; Maler, 1977; Mathur, 1971; Nevers, 1977; Ogden, 1966; Walter, 1971; and Werczberger, 1974) . There are increasing numbers of attempts to formulate "enlightened economic development" policies for urban and regional jurisdictions, incorporating the social costs and benefits of pollution reduction along with traditional private sector costs and benefits (Nijkamp and Paelinck, 1973). Our interest, here, lies partly in assessing the operationality (measurability) of these, and similar, concepts, in the light of the new Clean Air Act and our experience with the legislation to date. We care about these potential locational effects also because there may be ways to provide additional impetus to the use of the "market system" to promote cost-effective behavior on the part of polluters and "equitable" sharing of the costs and benefits which arise from tradeoffs between environmental and economic efficiency effects, as these are affected by locational decisions. The system of marketable air emission rights, set in motion by an interpretative EPA ruling in 1976, has initiated a flexible, though limited, market mechanism process. Suggestions for improving this * E.g. , see remarks by EPA Deputy Administrator Barbara Blum before the House Banking Committee on Economic Stabilization, July 26, 1978. * * Prepared for the Congressional Research Service, U.S. Library of Congress, "Suggested Plan of Study and Administrative and Management Plan for the National Commission on Air Quality," July, 1978. ieick Non-attainment areas are those regions of the country which currently do not meet Federal ambient air quality standards. D-20 process are being made increasingly, economists finding this perhaps the most palatable procedure. However, to evaluate the utility of this and other approaches, we need to understand better the underlying concepts and processes at work. The connecting links between consequences of the Clean Air Act for industrial location and its effects upon spatial resource allocation, inflation, and growth management are still ambiguous. Nevertheless, if the Act does, or will, substantially affect location, then all of these "downstream" consequences would need to be studied, We do not do that here, but do provide some exploratory suggestions about ways in which these other consequences might: (a) occur, and (b) be studied. E.g., see Hugh H. Macauley and Bruce Yandle , Environmental Use and the Market, D.C. Heath, 1977. i _ D-21 2.0 POTENTIAL IMPACTS OF CLEAN AIR ACTS ON INDUSTRIAL LOCATION 2 . 1 The Act and State Variations The Air Quality Act of 1967 set the stage for "making air cleaner." This initial concept eventually produced the National Ambient Air Quality Standards (NAAQS) , a concept which was truly national in scope, i.e., the air everywhere in the United States was to be at least as clean as the standards. Thus, the approach taken, from the beginning, undoubtedly had locational and economic growth implications: some places already had dirtier air than others and many had air that was dirtier than the stan- dards. To some extent , unknown at the time and to a substantial extent still, some differential impacts were clearly to be experienced. Under the Air Quality Act, the states were allowed to have differing standards for air quality, to be set by an extensive intergovernmental procedure, as described by the Environment Reporter : * To set in motion the machinery for regional control of air pollution, the Department of Health, Education and Welfare first designates air quality control regions and issues air quality criteria and reports on control tech- niques. State -governments then are expected to adopt air quality standards for the regions and plans for implementation of the standards . The air quality standards and implementation plans must be submitted to the Department for review. After the standards and plans are approved, States are expected to prevent and control air pollution in accordance with those standards and plans. The divergence permitted among states was eliminated by the Clean Air Act of 1970, which provided the basis for issuance of national standards. These standards were first issued in November, 1971, and revised in 1976. Under 40 CFR 50, primary and secondary standards were issued for the following pollutants: Sulfur oxides, Particulates, Carbon monoxide , Photochemical oxidants, Hydrocarbons, and Nitrogen dioxide. ♦Environment Reporter, 31:1121, 1970. D-22 Thus, the period 1967-1971 saw a shift from national divergence to uniform air quality standards, but this spatial policy change was probably due more to the recognition that air pollution does not recognize state boundaries than to considerations of regional economic growth and change. Although air quality standards became uniform, the process for achieving the standards was left largely to the ingenuity of the states, each of which was required to submit an implementation plan to show how its air could be made cleaner. In a series of reports by EPA, the progress of each state was documented, and the reports showed that after initial gains, progress was slowing, and many states had failed to attain the clean air standards in one or more pollutant categories (Table 1) . Meanwhile, another concept was emerging which would have implications for industrial location decisions: the concept of "significant deterioration of air quality." Although this concept seems to have taken considerable time to work out, it reflects the intent of the 1970 Clean Air Act to prevent or elminate damage to the environment. The concept as developed by EPA and tested in court has now become a key component of the 1977 Clean Air Act. This significant deterioration concept is not new. It has been in the EPA program structure since 1975. Other concepts in the 1977 Act have also generally been in existence, including the enforcement procedure for fining firms which violate emission limits, either as a new source, a hazardous substance emitter, or an old source for which their state plan has set levels. It is important at this juncture to discuss variations in state plans. The plans approached emissions control from many different perspectives, including fuel content, production levels, Btu's generated, and emissions control devices. By 1975, however, EPA discovered that almost none of the plans had a component or feature to prevent significant deterioration. Therefore, the plans had to be revised to incorporate such a feature. Most states found themselves accepting the PSD plan which EPA had devised. Finally, this plan has been written into the new 1977 Act, so that some geographic uniformity has been established. The PSD requirements do not necessarily determine whether the individual state's approach to emissions control and reduction is to be considered "adequate." At least at a formal level, states still have substantial freedom to develop their own techniques and tactics for achieving emissions control and air quality. The EPA and Congress have struggled with the problem of pollution drifting across states, but the individual state plans have continued to be an important factor in the state's posture with respect to industrial growth. The variety of state approaches itself presents a problem both to industry which desires to relocate and also to each state industrial develop- ment agency which must be able to argue the pros and cons of their own state's approach versus the approach of every other state. For this reason, the industrial development agencies will probably find that the standard o> to T3 o X UJ S2 3 o '€ CO a. D-23 r- o °- c 'l c 'oO 2 S c* c.E 5 « «£ Sco *^.o o : o O 5 O O n ^ c E-^ c !5 i F C 3 c a) o c g| S >- 5 ; o «r 3 ? O a; in — u III i t k, »> fo m _ m .♦; x: w h- < I Q- o z « « *> 1 c - «J (0 CO CO .2 > c «- TO — l/l - oi o> '■55 S >i° jc o vi — c 4i o t — o z a o " 5 8 - gs g VI >■ >• 5 • . - • c 3 ■? <0 „ | E 5 - x: 3 3 O O a c E .2 3 «, E S H .2 o c " 3 ro 5: * O O m C -J . ,"? c ■ *; t> - o i x: o ra 2 . -i c » c o » c •» ! s - = 2 * ■ k_ <0 .- o : O o> ■ — — 1 — o c — - : **■ o s . a) iilill i E «3 - .^ J : 10 -C 3 £ 3 : H u m o o _ *> 5 SIS .2 o 5 5 5 s S c - O w o = Jt 41 - 5 u - -* o » 5 « S 5 Q. ■- ^_ i- — § 3 o .s ? | <0 J. 41 O. • O Q CO CO CO X _J $ o o CO 2 * 2 ^ i o c - o — &n .- >0 £ »• v. S C B i^ r: •> CO > 5 *• C T3 o£ >v 4) 4) Ol S 13 tl VI 3 ?! >, c 10 >, jt io in ■* O 3 C? "> c ai * - ft> v* - - ■■o 5 S 5J E ^ 10 4) £ ra * o = oi in C£ 5 «J VI (0 4) a,' S 5 « = - » » « ° Hcoioco — ^:uuoi CO w o o W O 4) c ■«- O w S. — 4) 00 CL U Li- Q in t>» co tv 0( , oiof^oocTiO'»cor~0'<'tt^.ooO"-'' , oinoocTiO' c\(^^^^uiincococoiocor^r~r^i^ivi^a)e»a)oocftehencftcnooO'-<-<'- > 41 E _ ^D £ 41 10 CB c 3 ? 3 - VI O «- ». (0 C •*- 01 41 - ° ^ E a g « * 4) 2 5 rt) tl ^ VI ii o cr — 3 U rr a ff3 < 10 c - *" 10 < - - c ra 01 ._ ^ 41 .- O O T3 O C U. w: ,,< - - c < a Z S3 • ♦* in ^ (/) ._ c O c 41 < 10 E < »- c z ° - c c ™ c o •- 5 s: « »" -^ 3 4> •> -s; TJ "J » £^5 41 CO C E < 41 « c£ (A o "cjuO 3 S Q) ' i5 T3 3 UJ __ co +~» c .o .21- W) »_ — CO S"g o? O c5 * H W £>c/)iS CO CO 3 C 0\2 <2 a CO 3 CO o CD CD •D c CO CD Q ?^ o ■*-> 3 •*-> CO +-> a -" c E VI „ .£ E O 3 '■P a o o — c CO o Q. j o tO «> 3 o ■ *s o m£ ^2 S = o -co • < o £* c o c 2 8£ O 3 cSiiln C ~. " E c •(> 01 < £ 41 c£ ?* c .^ O 0) o 6 a a 4) « •|H i-H > a a W a < r— i ,a •H 4-> u J3 tLO • r-l W c U c a; B • • >> 1—1 ■i-i r-H 2 O Q ^1 b «-l a a o i-H i— i • rj C 3 <» > rt c W C W 5 * D-24 definition of significant deterioration now written into the Clean Air Act will give them a more stable and uniform basis for at least part of what they can discuss with prospective new firms. In summary, the approaches which have evolved for cleaning up the air have been forced to recognize that air pollution spreads across states. EPA and the Congress have continued to try to reserve flexibility for the states in their emission control strategies, while preventing extreme conditions from existing in any state and requiring that every state work toward the national standards as a minimum. 2.2 Concepts in 1977 CAA Which Are Relevant to Industrial Growth 2.2.1 Significant Deterioration In 2 . 1 above, the concept of significant deterioration was introduced as having originated from general statements in the Clean Air Act of 1970. Another major event was the court case brought by the Sierra Club in 1972 which resulted in a decision that EPA must have a program for the prevention of significant deterioration. The EPA reviewed all state implementation plans after May 31, 1972, using the criterion of whether each plan had any provision for prevention of significant deterioration. Eventually, the concept of nonsignificant deterioration was defined by the pollutant amounts shown in Table 2 . Even though the annual amounts of deterioration allowed were precisely defined, some flexibility was reserved to the states in the concept of classes of areas. The Clean Air Act of 1977 sets forth ways in which states can define a given area as Class I, II, or III. First, the area defined can be any jurisdiction or part thereof, so that relatively small areas can be separated from larger areas. Second, areas can be redesignated in either direction of stringency. Areas of all classes may eventually deteriorate to the ambient air quality standards, but no further, and the deterioration can only involve particulates and sulfur dioxide as shown in Table 2. 2.2.2 Attainment and Non- Attainment As noted above, deterioration can only occur where the air is already cleaner than the NAAQS, and many areas of the United States are above these standard levels. These regions (that do not meet Federal ambient air quality standards) are called non-attainment areas. Although these regions must *National Ambient Air Quality Standards D-25 Table 2 __ Significant Deterioration and Classes of Areas 1 (1) For any class I area, the maximum allowable increase in concentrations of sulfur dioxide and particu- late matter over the baseline concentration of such pollu- tants shall not exceed the following amounts: Maximum allowable increase (in Pollutants micrograms per cubic meter Particulate Matter: Annual geometric mean 5 Twenty-four-hour maximum 10 Sulfur Dioxide: Annual arithmetic mean 2 Twenty-four-hour maximum 5 Three-hour maximum 25 (2) For any class II area, the maximum allowable increase in concentrations of sulfur dioxide and particulate matter over the baseline concentration of such pollutants shall not exceed the following amounts: Maximum allowable increase (in Pollutants micrograms per cubic meter Particulate Matter: Annual geometric mean 19 Twenty-four-hour maximum 37 Sulfur Dioxide: Annual arithmetic mean. 20 Twenty-four-hour maximum. 91 Three-hour maximum 512 (3) For each class III area, the maximum allowable increase in concentrations of sulfur dioxide and particulate matter over the baseline concentration of such pollutants shall not exceed the following amounts: Maximum allowable increase (in Pollutants micrograms per cubic meter) Particulate Matter: Annual geometric mean 37 Twenty-four-hour maximum 75 Sulfur dioxide: Annual arithmetic mean 40 Twenty-four-hour maximum 182 Three-hour maximum 700 ^Environment Reporter , 71:1135, D-26 progress toward attainment of NAAQS according to a timetable set in their state implementation plan, the Clean Air Act provides a way for such areas to change their industrial mix by exchanging emissions from an existing emitter for emissions from a new emitter (new plant) , if the result of the exchange will bring the area closer to the NAAQS. Such an exchange is called an "offset," and it provides the only way in which new plants or expansions can locate in a non-attainment area, unless their emissions are below the EPA minimum of 50 tons of all pollutants per year, the EPA dividing point between major and minor emitters. This discussion has been somewhat simplified, but the important point is that state development agencies are going to have to follow closely the monitoring data which tells them what is an attainment and what is a non- attainment area in their state. Now more than ever, the industrial develop- ment agency will be coordinating with the air pollution agency in each state. Once attainment areas are identified, their designation as Class I, II, or III will provide an indication, but not an absolute determination, of what types of plants can locate there. The location implications are significant both for the attainment concept and also for the area class concept. If a plant which wishes to locate in an attainment area, plans to install the Best Available Control Technology (BACT) equipment, it must still obtain a permit from EPA if its emissions will be over 50 tons a year even with BACT. Among the factors to be considered in deciding on a permit, air pollution computer models are noteworthy since they provide a link between the plant's emissions and their impact on the ambient air quality. When approaching EPA, it would seem advisable for applicants to have alternate sites identified, since EPA has indicated that shifts in location of as little as one or two miles can make a difference in the air pollution modeling results. 2.2.3 Enforcement The permit to construct procedure provides the major enforcement feature af the Clean Air Act. If the state implementation plan has not been approved by EPA, then no permits can be issued, although the state may approve locations of sources emitting less than 50 tons/year. Other enforcement features include the EPA's power to bring a civil suit or assess a civil penalty against any person whose facility is in violation of a state plan; power to prohibit construction of a major source in a state which is not implementing its state plan, and power to require posting of a bond if a plant is under order to cease polluting, which must be forfeited if the pollution continues. The enforcement powers are stronger than in the 1970 Clean Air Act, although most of them have come into use during the past three ; to four years of regulation and practice. D-27 2.3 Requirements for States and Other Agencies 2.3.1 Designation of Classes of Areas The 1977 Clean Air Act defines three classes of areas which may be used to subdivide attainment areas. Each of these classes has certain implications for industrial location. Most areas in Class I are likely to be parks or publicly-owned forests, so that there would be no industrial sites there anyway. A state may designate any area as Class I, however, so that some development is possible as long as the Class I increments are not exceeded (see Section 4.2 below). All other areas automatically become Class II under the Clean Air Act, but states can redesignate an area to Class III if they follow certain procedures. Industrial development agencies will need to become familiar with their own state's redesignation procedures, and it is very likely that EPA will be watching redesignation to Class III very closely. 2.3.2 State Implementation Plans Looking at a broader regional context, state implementation plans have undergone review and revision since 1973, especially with regard to the requirement for a PSD feature or component. The 1977 Clean Air Act required that plans be resubmitted with provisions for permit granting, designation of areas by classes, and the attainment of NAAQS in all Air Quality Control Regions (AQCR) . The states are put into the dilemma of whether to designate in their State Implementation Plans / (SIP) any area as a Class III, or whether to leave all AQCR' s as either Class I or Class II as specified by the Clean Air Act. Although most states will probably be tempted to get a few areas into the Class III category as soon as possible, they must face the possibility that such an attempt could slow the preparation of their revised SIP which is supposed to be submitted to EPA by January, 1979. A more feasible course of action would be to get the revised plan in quickly and at the same time to begin setting up an institutional structure for redesignating to Class III, any AQCR or other area which the state desires to set aside for faster development. 2.3.3 Cost Analysis of Alternate Locations Diffusion modeling is likely to be necessary before new plants are constructed (especially in non-attainment areas) , and such modeling could become a cooperative effort by states and industry. In testing alternative sites through use of a diffusion model, the firm viewing the locations will need to know the other cost factors which must be balanced against the air pollution restrictions. Most states will have data on alternative sites, D-28 and some will probably find it useful to model the diffusion features of each site as part of their site marketing approach. 2.3.4 Meteorologic Modeling The NAAQS are well specified with respect to monitoring and measurement procedures. The objective of diffusion and/or other meteorologic modeling is to analyze impacts of emissions on air quality. The choice of a model and the choice of input data on weather will always be subject to some judgment. Presumably, the states and individual firms would wish to develop data on site-specific weather conditions. 2.4 Probable Requirements for Firms In order to support a permit request, a plant or firm must have an emissions inventory or a "design emissions inventory." There has been some debate on whether this information would violate confidentiality and degrade the competitive position of the firm. The inventory is submitted first to the state level so that the confidentiality problem must first be solved there, and EPA must necessarily rely on state agencies to a considerable extent. An important impact of the Clean Air Act of 1977 could well be the discouragement of firms from going through the process of looking for new sites, since they will have to negotiate with a state or city on the site and then review their alternatives. Only after submitting a proposed emissions inventory will a state be able to identify definite sites which could be acceptable. For certain types of industries, each state could build a "site bank," based on assumptions about probable plant designs. 2.5 Importance of Geographic Scale in Corporate Location Decisions: How to Compare Potential Regulatory Costs Except in the smallest, most developed states, it is reasonable to assume that there will be a supply of sites in the Class II category, so that the preferences of firms can still be dominant in the industrial location process. The assumption is that an AQCR will be large enough to afford many plant choices and that once a plant has made a regional/ state location choice, the supply of sites will be numerous. Thus, the firm searching for a location would not automatically rule out a region or state because it had some no n- attainment areas. Although every region and state is likely to have some Class II areas, the sizes and configurations of these areas will vary from state to state and among various extremes . In other words , the variation in traditional site features will be much greater than variation in air pollution features, D-29 which will be limited to the class designation, and fundamentally, the ambient air quality. A given site can have many characteristics of accessi- bility and potential value, but with respect to air quality there are only four categories: Class I, II, III, or non-attainment. Thus, the problem of characterizing each state by the general avail- ability of attainment areas arises. If the location decision is approached incrementally, the industrial decisionmaker might well rule out some states or even regions if he were informed that "X percent of their AQCR's were non-attainment." Not only would a preliminary decision based on such infor- mation be of questionable validity, but it would also introduce a bias into the site selection process which would probably be undocumented and unmea- surable. In other words, the decisionmaker would be making a subjective judgment about the importance of the percent of non-attainment areas, when the main question before him is how suitable are the one or more sites which are available. 2.5.1 Comparison and Selection of Multistate Regions with Respect to Air Quality And/Or Regulatory Stringency The simplest way to compare states and regions on air quality is by looking at the number of Standard Metropolitan Statistical Areas (SMSA's) or AQCR's which are non-attainment according to EPA progress reports. This would be a simplistic measure, but it could be made more sensitive by measuring the percent away from attainment on one or more pollutants . There would still be some possibility of bias, but choice criteria could be made reasonably objective. A further indicator of potential regulatory costs would be some measure of the stringency of the state's SIP with respect to the level of air quality. A state with a short timetable for achieving NAAQS and/or air quality standards requiring cleaner air than NAAQS would be a state with high potential regulatory costs. Data are available on these features of SIP's for the 1972-1973 plans. Under the 1977 Clean Air Act, these SIP's must be revised by January, 1979, so that new analyses and comparisons will be required. 2.5.2 Review and Selection of Specific Sites With Respect to Pollution Control Costs and Other Costs As noted in previous Sections (2.3 and 2.4), both private firms, as well as public agencies, go through a site selection and analysis procedure from opposite sides of the site market. Both look for some optimal set of sites according to very similar criteria. Furthermore, they are operating at multiple geographic scales: multistate, state, multicounty, county, and subcounty. In assessing alternative site costs, including pollution regulation costs, they may choose alternative sites for comparison at various scales. For example, a regional commission (Appalachian, Coastal D-30 Plains, etc.) might choose two or more alternative states, or might choose a dozen sites among states, with the site size varying from one to a thousand acres. The application of a pollution control cost procedure to multiple sites will vary with the geographic scale of the sites, unless all of the sites have been reduced to a very small (e.g., one acre) size. The reason for such variation is that selection among larger areas requires some kind of merging or averaging of data on air quality, while selection among very small sites could involve only one monitor, possibly a monitor some distance from the proposed site (under the 1977 Clean Air Act, however, EPA can require monitoring to determine baseline air quality for a given site) . Thus, from an air pollution control viewpoint, it is convenient to narrow selection to a few very small alternative sites. But industrial decisionmakers must often make larger area (regional) decisions first. Under such conditions, corporate decisionmakers wish to optimize their chances of finding a suitable Class II or Class III site while making a regional-level decision on the basis of markets, raw materials, or other factors. The state agency which can offer credible assistance in such a task will be warmly regarded. 2.5.3 Iterative Decisionmaking and Reconsideration of Alternatives: The Use of Decision Models Credible assistance from a state agency which is actively working to attract industry means some logical, systematic (probably automated) proce- dures for comparing the many factors in the decision framework, including pollution costs, with each other. The state agency must be able to respond to the decision process of the firm and to present cost analyses using current data which are specific to the interindustry structure in its immediate region. In other words, the state must know the buying, selling, and operating costs the firm will face, as well as the regulatory costs. Admittedly, the precision of a typical input-output model would not show much difference in payments when two alternative sites which are two miles apart are compared. In any comparison, the model must first be adjusted to reflect different supply and market structures with respect to location, if such exist. An approach similar to that suggested above is described by Miernyk and Sears (1974) using the West Virginia SIP as a basis for assessing pollution control strategies, and also for assessing the feasibility of locating a coal gasification plant in West Virginia. The analysis performed used an input-output model, but the model is for the state-level economy and does not solve the problem of which of the ten AQCR's within the state would be the most suitable site. Although the study could be called an academic exercise, the report includes the following conclusion: D-31 What conclusions with respect to regional economic development can be derived from the simulation of coal gasification processes in West Virginia? First, when large sums of money are being expended for the development of coal gasification processes, simulation might provide useful guidelines for the allocation of research funds. Clearly, these allocations cannot be based entirely on economic analysis. The tech- nological feasibility of each of the processes must also be taken into account. But if there is no reason for choosing between the two processes simu- lated in this study on technological grounds, a strong case can be made for the f luidized-bed process on economic grounds. It would generate more new employment, and the end product — electricity — would be produced at lower unit costs. 2.6 How Serious Can the Impacts of These Regulations Be? In a recent letter (July 6, 1978) from Mr. John F. O'Leary, Deputy Secretary, Department of Energy (DOE) , to Mr. Douglas Costle, Administrator, EPA, relative to the potential inflationary, and other unintended economic consequences of EPA's proposed revisions of New Source Performance Standards (NSPS) for electric utility boilers, DOE's proposal which leads to "slightly higher overall emissions," is seen to offer these locational differences: One benefit ascribed to the EPA staff proposal is that it would allow more industrial growth to take place within the constraints of air quality standards. As we read the Clean Air Act, however, the purpose of NSPS is to establish minimum national performance standards. The PSD program is intended as the mechanism for allowing States to tighten emissions control requirements beyond this minimum where this is necessary to make room for growth. It seems to have been the clear intent of Congress that this be done by the States, through case-by-case determinations of BACT. For NSPS to require maximum feasible controls in all cases would essentially eliminate meaningful State discretion in making these BACT determinations. In our view, those who advocate that NSPS be used to minimize emissions everywhere without regard to local conditions appear to believe that States need to be protected against themselves. A costly side effect of providing this protection through stringent NSPS would be the preservation of unneeded growth potential in many areas — those where favorable terrain, meteo- rology, and current air quality would allow anticipated growth to take place at considerably higher emissions rates than those proposed as NSPS by your staff. D-32 In sum, we believe that the economic and energy savings of our proposal can be realized without sacrificing air quality objectives or other national goals. We therefore believe that the modifications we recommend would strike a better balance among the competing objectives which are affected by this rulemaking. We wish here only to recognize that significant industrial locational variations are likely to result from differing interpretations and imple- mentation of the Clean Air Act. Table 3 summarizes components of the Clean Air Act legislation, the responsible agency, and some possible impacts on energy programs.* Many if not most of these impacts are seen to have locational, developmental, and/or economic consequences more generally. The responsible agency and the "impacted" agency and function -- be it Energy, Interior, or Transportation -- are only beginning to evolve and coordinate interagency approaches to resolve the emerging conflicts. Modified from U.S. Department of Energy, Office of Technology Impacts, "Air Quality Regulatory Issues Impacting DOE Plans and Programs," July, 1978. D-33 Table 3 - CAA Actions, Responsible Agency, and Some Possible Impacts Ail tun Name/ IV script Ion AgKlKtf Hespnnalhle — ■ , , s 4* , C • *-» — = Po.slble kiutrgy-KcUted Impacts UACT r.tii.irH nes The IV77 Clean Air Act Amendment ■ require the ncv. sources loc.ttlng in clean air (Prevention of Significant Deterioration) areas use Heat Available Control Technolo- gy (IIACT). HACT i» to be determined on a ca«e-by-ca*e pollutant buM» for each iuurrr regulation jmlcr the I*rc* vcnilon of Significant Deter ioration (l*SD) provisions of the Act. 1 he applicable permitting agencies arc to conmder energy, environmental and economic impact* In making the ItACT determination. EPA The HACT requirement rrcHoi significant design con- straints early In the application prove**. If KPA ques- tions the ilt'Hicn decision, it may require the imircr to redesign it* control technology. The preliminary dculgn requirements for control lyitcnu will lengthen the time and increase the cd«t of the permit prorchi and of energy development, '1 he possibility of po*tt application redesign further heightens th;*se problems. CEO NFPA Regulations The Council on Environmental Quality (CFQl hag proposed regulations Implementing the procedural provisions of the National Environmental Policy Act (NEPA1, primarily the preparation of Environmental Impact Statements, These regulations are designed to achieve uniformity, to reduce paperwork and delays, and to produce better decisions. CEQ Class I Designation • The Department of Interior (DOl> was required to iden- tify mandatory Class I Federal areas (pristine areas under the PSD provisions of the 1°77 Clean Air Act Amendments) where visibility protection is impor- tant. The list was to be recommended to EPA for adoption. • DOI has recommended a list of National monuments, preserves, and "primitive" areas to EPA for redeeig- natlon to Class I PSD areas. DOI DOI In the April 10, 1078, listing in the Federal Register, it specifically states that a rcdesignation to Class I will affect all major emitting facilities (WKF) within 100 miles of the area. If tin* MEF would cause a violation of the increment the MEF may be subject to "relocation or redesign". The Federal Rccisterdocs state that the pub- lic interest will be addressed to see U it is better served by the redesignation to Class I or by the retention of Class II status so as not to affect the industrial and energ) development in the area.. Designation of Attainment Status EPA was required to publish all areas in compliance with the National Ambient Air Quality Standards (NAAQS) as well as those not attaining the NAAQS. Areas in compli- ance are designated PSD areas; those not in compliance are nonattainment (NA areas. Areas having insufficient data were classified as PSD areas. EPA The designations were based either on old (generally 197*1) data or on modelling. This status report reflects the discrepancies between modelling and real world monitor- ing checks. Far more areas appear to be nonattaining than were so designated by EPA. By designating the status on a state-by- state basis artificial boundaries were created. This resulted in an attainment area being surrounded by nonattainment areas in states with adjoin- ing borders. In actuality most of these areas are likely to be nonattaining. Modelling Guidelines . EPA has prepared a Guideline on Air Quality Models recommending the application of certain air quality modelling techniques to air pollution control strategy •valuations and to new source reviews. EPA has prepared a Workbook for Comparison of Air Quality Models, outlining mc;hods for determin- ing the comparability of models proposed by • source with the recommended EPA models. EPA EPA In September 1978, a mechanism for periodic review of the guidelines is to be set up by the American Meteoro- logical Society (AMS), The review will be subject to public scrutiny. The Comparison Workbook establishes the EPA models as the standard and then evaluates the assumptions with- out regard to actual performance. A challenge to EPA's modelling assumptions will result in delay in the review process. Monitoring , Under the PSD provisions of the Act and EPA's im- plementing regulations, there are requirements for ambient air quality and meteorological data to be col- lected In support of a permit application. EPA is pre- paring guidelines for determining the number of mon- itoring sites and the length of the monitoring period necessary. Criteria for siting of monitors *nd for quality assurance is also outlined. * The Act requires EPA to establish a uniform air qual- ity monitoring system throughout the U.S. EPA is developing regulations revising existing state and local air pollution monitoring networks with standard- Iced monitoring methods and quality control. EPA EPA Under present regulations wide latitude is given to EPA to determine when monitoring will be required for new source review. 1 be PSD regulations specify that moni- toring will only be required when modelling determines that there is a threat to the NAAQS. National Ambient Air Q-iallty Standards Under the |*)77 Clean Air Act Amendments, EPA Is re- quired to nuke any necessary revision* to existing Nation- al Arnhlent Air 0*i*llty SUmJafln (NAA(/S| (for SO , 'ISP, 1IC, CO, I'hotochrif.ictl oxidants, NO ) *f\'l to prot'nuluatr any new standards for additional poll^Tants of concern. M'A Is specific illy required to promulgate a NO (short- term) standard If m*f-dfff. EPA D-34 Table 3 -- CAA Actions, Responsible Agency, and Some Possible Impacts (continued) Action Agency Possible Energy-Related Name/ Description Responsible Impacts National AmMrnt Air <>■ *llly Si md.irdfl (continued) EPA . Lead; , Fhotnchemlc.il oxidants: EPA has pro- The relaxation was subject to Intense Internal FPA debate posed a revision to the standard origin* snd as proposed is Insignificant. In actuality the 0. 1 stan- •lly promulgated February Id, 1975; dard not to be exceeded more than 3 times In 3 years may be more stringent than the 0.03, 1 hr. average standard. The oxidant standard impacts all energy facilities. . NO, (short-term): The r.incr for the standard A PSD increment (due two years after the NAACS) could umfi-r consideration by EPA is 0. 25-0. 50 ppm or 470-940 ug/m , 1 hr. average, EPA lavs this be so small as to prohibit the construction of any norm- ally sized facility. will provide a margin of safety to protect the public, including sensitive individuals such as asthmatics. . NO (annual): EPA plans to revise the original Depending on the revision chosen it may result in sig- standard. nificant size limitations for energy facilities. a CO: F.PA plans to revise the original standard promulgated February 18, 1975, (9ppm, 8 hr. average; 35 ppm, 1 hr. average). • SO2: EPA plans to revise the original standard. Speculation continues as to whether the ultimate promul- gation of a sulfate standard will result in the dropping of the SO. standard. • TSP (particulates): EPA plana to revise the The TSP standard may be replaced by a "fine particulate original standard. standard". This could result in the need for a major re- design of control technology. NESHAPS Under Section 112 of the Act, EPA Is required to first list EPA any hazardous air pollutants for which it intends to estab- lish a standard and then to promulgate emission standards for their control. • Asbestos: EPA has revised the original standard. • Benzene: Benzene was listed as a hazardous air Any standard for benzene could be constraining for coal pollutant and ia under "Health Risk" assessment technologies leading, for example, to the regulation of by EPA solvent refined coal processes and coke plants. • Arsenic: Arsenic was listed as a hazardous air pollutant. • Sulfates (SO4): Sulfate was listed as a hazardous A sulfate standard would impact upon all fossil-fuel air pollutant and la under "Health Risk." assess- burning plants. ment by EPA. • Radionuclides: Radionuclides was listed as a Much of Western Coal is found in or near uranium areas hazardous air pollutant. resulting in the emission of radiation. These emissions arc currently uncontrolled. New Source Performance Standards (NSPS) The 1977 Clean Air Act Amendments require that EPA EPA promulgate standards of performance of new categories of stationary sources and that EPA review NSPS every four years and revise them when necessary. The NSPS will be an emission limitation except in the case of fossil fuel fired stationary sources where the standard must combine emissions limitations with percentage reduction in emis- sions. Both must be achieved through the application of the best technological system of continuous emission reductior taking Into account any energy, environmental and econom- tmpacte. • Petroleum Liquid Storage Vessels: EPA revised the original standards. • Petroleum Refineries: The original stan- dard of March 8, 1974, was amended March 15, 1978, to include Claus Sulfur Recovery Plants. • Fossil Fuel Steam Generators < Pollers): EPA Intends to apply this new standard to developing EPA Is required to revise the original energy technologies such as fluidlzed bed combustion Standard of June 14, 1974 (amended 11/22/76). boilers and boilers fired with synfuela. Depending on the stringency of the emissions limitations, the standard could affect Implementation of these technologies. The SO, standard applicable to Western coals could affect the choice of coal for new hollers hence coal markets. Coal may have to be exported great distances from the mine affecting oil usage in transportation. D-35 Table 3-- CAA Actions, Responsible Agency, and Some Possible Impacts (continued) Action N*mii«*/ Description Prrforw.incf St.iiularHs (continued) Stationary Gas Turbines: EPA has proposals tn this standard fur ►: » s turbin«*# to bo ustd in con- Junction with steam gorif rator». Internal Combustion Engines for Stationary Source*: EPA wilt proposv regul.ttionti to require the application of be*t demonstrated control tech- nology to control emissions iron* stationary in- ternal combustion engines. Sulfur Recovery in Natural Gas Fields: F.PA will propose this standard to control emissions of total reduced sulfur (IRS). Industrial Boilers: EPA's revision of this stan- dard for utility electric steam generators will not apply to industrial boilers in any size range. How- ever, EPA has studies currently underway, in preparation for a proposal of a companion NSPS whLxh will apply to individual boilers. Industrial boiler classes under consideration are typical fossil-fuel fired boilers, fludized bed combustion boilers. And waste-fired boilers. EPA Is required under the Act to prepare a prior- itized list of major stationary sources for which New Source Performance Standards must be pro- mulgated within four years. Included in an early version of the list are: • • Crude Oil and Natural Gas Production Plants; • • Mixed Fuel Boilers (Coal and Refuse}; Mixed Fuel Boilers (Oil and Refuse); and .. Uranium Refineries. Agency Responsible Possible Energy -Relate*! Impacts EPA Use of industrial boiler fuels and technologies will be directly Impacted by this standard. Depending upon the source category and the schedule for development of the regulation, this timetable may heavily impact on the development of specific energy technologies. Nonattainment EPA has provided SIP revision guidance establishing criteria for approval of plans for nonattainment areas in order to assure attainment. EPA la in the process of revising its Emissions Off- set Policy for Nonattainment Areas of December 21, 1976. Briefly, for new sources to obtain a construction per- mit In nonattainment areas they must: 1. Obtain offset emissions greater than one for one; banking of offsets to save lor future growth would be allowed. 2. Demonstrate reasonable further pro- gress toward attainment. 3. Comply with Lowest Achievable Emis- sion Rate (LAER). 4* Demonstrate compliance of all other sources owned by the applicant. Any NA regulations will affect all energy-related facilities New sources will need to obtain offsets while older sourc- es will have to develop ways of reducing emissions. These time and economic constraints could severely limit growth in NA areas. The energy industry may be constrained by state limits placed on future growth in particular regions. Prevention of Significant Deterioration (PSD) Under the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1977, EPA is re- qutrcd to promulgate regulations to prevent significant de- terioration of air quality in attainment areas. Final regu- lations and SIP guidance for PSD have been promulgated. Increments for SOj and TSP for allowable growth over baseline air quality have been established in three classi- fications of areas (I. U, III). There is a general exemption to this review process - when a source will have an increase in '* allowable" factual aftsr controls) emissions of less than SO tons/year. # The Act requires that EPA promulgate PSD regulations for all other pollutants for which there are NAAOS 77 Clean Air Act Amendments require EPA to pro- mulgate regulations implementing lite provUInn limiting tbc use. of taller stack* instead of pollution control equip- ment. EPA New source siting In rough terrain may be discouraged since allowable slack heights are not sufficient to over- come terraine impact. Visibility • EPA la required under the Act to prepare a report to Congrem discussing visibility protection. • EPA It required to prep. ire guidelines for states to address visibility problems in their SIPs. EPA If Congress intends to provide visibility protection for areas outside Class I regions that are visible from Class I regions, western energy development may be restricted. Those areas redesignated Class 1 areas may restrict energy development. The requirement for Best Available Retrofit Technology may lead to costly and lengthy delays. Visibility protection could lead to a fine particulates standard winch would require the re- 1 design of all air pollution control devices. D-37 3.0 USE OF ANALYTIC DECISION-ASSISTING LOCATIONAL MODELS We touch in this section upon three of the ways in which analytic models can assist in the locational decisionmaking processes which, we have seen, are likely to be made more complex as the result of air pollution control legislation and its implementing regulations: • Models to determine the regional economic effects, ex post / as well as ex ante ; • Ways to build regulatory requirements into locational decisions; and • Ways to include "normative" (value) considerations. These, by no means, exhaust the variety of models which may become increas- ingly useful. For example, there are a large number of site location models, both descriptive and optimizing in nature, which are used to determine preferred or "best" intra-areal locations. However, most of these other analytic modeling applications are variants of those discussed in this section. 3.1 Models to Examine Regional Economic Effects The assembly of data on specific case studies of the impact of environ- mental legislation on location decisions and urban growth is an important area of investigation that has been discussed elsewhere in this report (Sections 4.1 and 4.2, below). In this section, we examine broader, more analytical approaches to predicting the impact of environmental standards on urban and regional growth. The models examined in this section view the fluctuations in regional economic activity in continuous forms, rather than in the discrete terms that characterize individual plant closings and openings. They are, none- theless, important tools for analyzing the impact of pollution abatement regulations on urban and regional growth. There are several reasons for this. First, as pointed out earlier, there is evidence that plant decisions to expand/contract output and employment play a more important part in regional growth than the birth of new firms or decisions by existing firms to close down or relocate. And the variations in economic activity of different industry groups are quite susceptible to analysis using econometric and other modeling methods. Second, the use of a model enables one to see in a quantitative way the importance of abatement costs relative to other factor input costs, including labor costs, tax costs, and the importance of regional variations in climate and other factors (including the importance to environmental quality itself as an attractive force) . Another advantage of regional econometric models is their ability to assess impacts on present and prospective state and local government revenues D-38 and expenditures. The impact of the Federal Water Pollution Control Act Amendments of 1972 (PL 92-500) and the Clean Water Act of 1977 on state and local finances, through the need to develop additional wastewater treatment facilities, has been analyzed by Forbes and others. For example, Table 4, taken from Forbes and Peterson, shows the significance of the state and local share of capital expenditures on treatment facilities relative to current borrowing levels. The resulting impacts for thirteen selected states are shown in Table 5. The cost estimates by state were taken from the 1976 EPA Needs Survey and were based on the following assumptions : First, the average annual expenditure, implied by the total required outlays, was calculated for the twelve-year period. The federal grant share (75% of total costs) was subtracted to find the combined state and local share of expenditures. The state share (ranging from to 25% of the total cost) was then subtracted using the current formula for state aid. The resulting figure was the local share of construc- tion costs. /Total cost, state-local and local shares grouped by EPA region for_ Categories I through V are shown in Table 4 V The results in these tables suggest that significant upward pressure on interest rates in bond markets will be felt by local governments, especially in the thirteen states listed. ' To some extent, these pressures will be ameliorated by increased real growth in the regional economies, thus increas- ing the ability of the region to absorb new issues. Nevertheless, the results do suggest that environmental legislation have differential impacts directly on state and local finances. Similar analyses could be performed for munic- ipally-owned facilities subject to air pollution control legislation. More- over, changes in regional activity that result from firms' locational decisions (including decisions to change output and employment levels at an existing site) have important indirect effects on state and local finances. The over- all analysis of these is perhaps best handled by an econometric model which simulates the responses of different sectors of the economy to changes in factor costs (including abatement cost) . This production factor approach is discussed further in Section 3.2. * Forbes, R. W. , and J. E. Peterson, "The Costs of Clean Water," Parts I and II, Special Report, The First Boston Corporation, 1978. ** Categories I through V represent Secondary Treatment, Higher Than Secondary Treatment, Correction of Infiltration/Inflow and Sewer Rehabilitation, New Collection and Interceptor Sewers, and Control of Combined Sewer Overflow. * * * The inclusion of yet another category of costs, that of stormwater control and treatment, would increase the significance of the impacts. (See Forbes and Petersen, op. cit. ) D-39 Table 4: I976 Needs Survey Forecasts for Municipal Wastewater Treatment Facilities EPA Average Total Region Expenditure FY 1977—1988 Categories I through V (millions of 1976 dollars) Combined S&L Share Local Share S&L Share as % of Total Local Share as % of Total S&L Borrowing Local Borrowing I II III IV V VI VII VIII IX X Total' $ 648.9 1480.5 915.8 975.8 2036.9 392.1 392.8 114.4 585.0 345.5 $7887.0 $162.3 325.2 228.8 244.0 509.3 98.0 98.3 28.6 148.8 86.4 $1971.2 $ 60.6 178.3 178.3 196.3 424.9 96.5 61.7 25.1 80.3 52.5 $1354.3 8.38% 6.15 6.88 7.74 10.87 4.05 10.22 4.45 6.32 4.73 7.33% 6.07 8.85 9.16 12.80 5.16 7.12 4.63 4.78 4.55 7.27% 7.81% ■Excludes Puerto Rico and the Virgin Islands in Region II; District of Columbia in Region III and Samoa, Guam and Pacific Territories in Region IX. 2 Average borrowing 1973-1976 Source: Forbes and Petersen, op. cit. , (Vol. II, p. 7). D-40 Table 5: States Where State and Local Average Annual Share of Capital Expenditure Exceeds Ten Percent of Total State and Local Borrowing (Categories I through V) State Maine New Hampshire Rhode Island Vermont West Virginia Georgia Indiana Michigan Ohio Arkansas Iowa Missouri Idaho S&L Share Local Share EPA AS% OF AS% OF Legion S&L Borrowing Local Borrowing 18.2 16.2 23.2 8.4 14.4 11.5 16.8 24.1 HI 12.7 14.0 IV 10.2 14.9 V 19.1 14.6 V 12.1 12.4 V 17.3 26.9 VI 19.6 22.1 VII 12.7 14.0 VII 22.6 10.3 X 30.2 14.1 Source: Forbes and Petersen, op. cit. , (Vol. II, p. 8) D-41 Regardless of what the results of any econometric approach tell us, however, municipalities will have to face a series of institutional/organi- zational issues in order to counteract potential negative effects of pollution regulations. These effects could come either from air pollution or water pollution regulations. The NSPS both for air and water are likely to be more stringent than state laws have been. Thus, cities will face the treatment cost requirements described above for water and industries building or expanding will face requirements for scrubbers or other air pollution control equipment. The institutional/organizational issues arise from the municipalities' traditional role as growth centers. Industrial growth within central cities has led to many conditions including the typically higher costs of land in these cities, as well as their present status as non-attainment areas. It is possible to argue that the first of these conditions is a greater deter- rent to the location of new industry than is the second condition. The large area contained in the SMSA 1 s is an entirely different situation, where many counties may contain less expensive industrial sites and these sites may be within the NAAQS. These SMSA potentials for industrial growth may be of little immediate comfort to central city mayors in spite of the fact that some central city residents will benefit. These mayors may also observe a relative lack of concern for their plight, or at least a neutral view from state government development agencies who have an entire state full of industrial sites, many of which are within NAAQS, at their disposal. Thus, the concern of municipalities over the 1977 Clean Air Act is partly a reflection of traditional struggles between city, suburban, and state level factors. The problem of difficulty in attracting new industry to central cities could be alleviated if low cost land could be made avail- able for expansion of existing central city industry which is held to the immediate area by a large existing investment. The pollution regulation problem could be alleviated by identifying as soon as possible what firms are moving out, and by obtaining offset arrangements between the movers and the stayers. Here, the econometric analyses would be of help to mayors of munici- palities by assisting in identifying firms which have lost a source of supply or a market, or some production factor. If the sectors which are facing such difficulties are identified, then the municipalities can plan their public facility construction with plants in these sectors in mind. Thus, interindustry econometrics could be applied to aid municipalities, as well as states and regions. Any plant which is thinking of leaving a central city must analyze the costs of moving and staying, and the analytic models would also be useful for such a purpose. The alternative costs of air pollution control would not necessarily be much lower, however, even if the plant is moving to an attainment area. If the plant's emissions could cause the air quality to degrade beyond the allowable increment, or if the air in a Class I area could be affected, then the plant would be required to install BACT or to seek another site. D-42 Even if the plants in the East are tempted to move to areas of low sulfur coal, they may not escape installation of scrubbers. The following discussion is from a recent Federal Energy Administration (FEA) report (1977) The Clean Air Act Amendments of 1977 require new plant emission control which reflects Best Avail- able Control Technology (BACT) . In many instances, and particularly for S0 2 control on large coal- fired boilers, BACT will be more stringent than current NSPS. Therefore, it is likely that the applicable assump- tions for S0 X emission from new power plants will be "90% below NSPS" for areas where low sulfur coal is locally available (primarily in the West) , and "50% below NSPS" for high sulfur coal areas (Midwest and East) . The implications of BACT for other pollutants and industries are uncertain at present, but greater emission control than currently practiced will undoubtedly be required. The result will be a reduction in the constraints on plant size and colocation. What this report says is that even though so-called footloose urban indus- tries will still be able to leave central cities, they will generally gain few benefits in terms of reduced air pollution control costs. The types of regional location impacts due to air pollution regulation will be more complex than "scrubber versus non-scrubber, " and will probably involve institutional features and the interindustry connections mentioned above. The analysis of these connections is discussed further below. The annotated bibliography included in this volume contains several references to the traditional economic and regional science literature on factors affecting the location of industry (Dolde, 1977; Harris and Hopkins, 1972; Hekman, 1978; McMillan, 1975; Miernyk and Sears, 1974; and Neutze, 1967). The approaches have used a mix of the following techniques: • Economic base and shift share, • Input-output models, and • Econometric models. The discussion below first describes studies from the bibliography that have treated the locational consequences of environmental legislation more * See also report by Roger J. Vaughan, "The Urban Impacts of Federal Policies: Volume II, Economic Development," Rand Corporation, 1971. D-43 thoroughly than the others. The emphasis is on evaluating their strengths and weaknesses. Second, we outline some of the features of a model that would go beyond these approaches and capture the interregional aspects of regional growth and its relationship to national growth. Such a model would have important uses for analyzing the regional economic consequences of environmental policy. 4c Leitner and Emerson extend the traditional shift-share approach to explaining regional growth by including environmental factors as explanatory variables in an equation relating industry location shifts to traditional production cost variables (labor costs, tax costs, material input costs, agglomeration economies or diseconomies and market size) , as well as costs of complying with pollution abatement regulations. The primary measures of the latter are per capita air pollution control expenditures by each state, per capita water quality control expenditures by state, and the availability of public waste treatment facilities for use by industrial discharges. Additionally, the availability of state pollution control bonds to finance abatement expenditures was included as an explanatory variable. The cross-section data on states was analyzed over the period of 1968- 1972 using single equation least square techniques for the following indus- tries: Food and Kindred Products, Textile Mills, Paper Products, Chemical Products, Petroleum Products, Primary Metals and Fabricated Metal Products. The statistical results are fairly inconclusive, the most significant explanatory environmental variable being expenditures on water quality standards The study illustrates both the advantages, as well as significant drawbacks on this type of modeling. By keeping the model structure simple, all 50 states were analyzed with regard to the relative impact of environ- mental legislation by region. However, the weaknesses of the data base make it difficult to accept the validity of the results. In particular: The measure for stringency of standards is total pollution control expenditures by media for a single year, 1968 by state. Aggregate expenditures by state governments appear to have been used and not indus try-by- industry estimates. While one of the data sources cited had developed regional estimates of abatement costs on air industry-by-industry basis, r this study had used national abatement cost functions with regional estimates being developed using employment as a proxy for industry activity. If the data from this study * Leitner, K. R. , and M. Jarvin Emerson, "Effects of State Pollution Control Programs on Industrial Location" (undated mimeograph) . Environmental Protection Agency, The Economics of Clean Water 1972 , (1972) . The Environmental Protection Agency has done more recent studies of the same type but with air and water pollution abatement costs analyzed in a single study. D-44 were used, significant multicollinearity would have entered the regression, thus making it difficult to interpret the individual coefficients; • The measure of the availability of municipal treatment plants to industrial discharges — the number of treatment facilities per capita — was not adjusted for (a) differences in the size of the facilities from region to region, or (b) differences in use of the municipal systems from one industry to another. Moreover, indus- trial discharges that pretreat and use the system are required to pay "user charges" to the public system. This was not incorporated in the study; and • The importance of state pollution control bonds were entered as a dummy (0-1) variable without considering the extent to which such financing was in fact used. In summary, the study has attempted to introduce pollution control standards into a conventional regional growth model. The results are incon- clusive primarily because the data were lacking to discriminate important differences across regions and industries in the incidence of pollution abate- ment costs . More recent studies by EPA and others have significantly improved estimates of the industry detail but the regional differences have been examined only in a few industries where the existence of a few plants makes it easier to bound the abatement alternatives and technology options available. A promising econometric approach to assessing air pollution impacts has been taken in a study by Lakshmanan and Lo (1971) . An econometric model was developed for the 100 largest SMSA's and the impact of alternative air pollu- tion abatement strategies analyzed. A general view of the model is provided in Table 6. The model consists of three major blocks: • A production function block that uses cross-section data (on 100 SMSA's at the 2-digit SIC level to develop Cobb-Douglas production functions; • A Keynesian-type regional income determination block that models the relationship between industry activity, regional consumption, income and government expenditures; • A major element of the model is the link between regional and national activity. As with most models developed in the early 1970s, a top-down approach to regional modeling is considered. This approach has its origins in the export-base theory of regional development which relates regional manufacturing activity (and through its aggregate regional income) to fluctuations in corres- ponding national totals (below we comment on some promising new alternatives) . The link between regional and national activity is through a rational input-output model that determines national industry output as a function of final demand. These national industry levels of output are then D-45 o CO ■«-> cj CO 1 2 0> 3 C T3 ^ C 0) cu > a o x i a w 1 q o •I-t +J i— i ^ CI, iona ime iona sum bo « bo q P rt O CD q pL, u«2 1 c o •H +* w «» >s.™ ^ o dust epre ates 5Q« 4-> C CU £ >« CO o i—« a rt 8 ft cu q P D-46 allocated on a share basis to the SMSA's and enter the regional production function block, affecting regional income and employment. The model was used in a simulation of the impact of alternative air pollution control strategies. The air pollution control costs affect the (national) supply curves of high emission industries and cut down production levels in each SMSA; these generate a sequence of interregional effects. Several different assumptions are made about the extent to which different groups absorb the pollution control costs. As an example, under one simulation the high emission industries are estimated to absorb the costs; this affects profits which leads to changes in industry investment, regional income, and regional unemployment rates. The model is innovative, and, in a sense, still state of the art. Improvements have been made in the conceptual design of regional models since this study. The problem is that the data bases have not kept pace with these developments nor have the analysis of regulatory impacts been a particular concern of the regional econometricians. Before turning to a discussion of some of the promising approaches one could take here, it is worth summarizing the major weaknesses of the Lakshmanan-Lo model: • A static 1-0 model was used to forecast national industry activity changes; • A static regional share matrix was used to allocate national shifts to the SMSA's; • The tradeoffs between investment in abatement and facility investment were not explicitly considered; and • The impact of pollution abatement on inflation and the differential impact of this on regional activity was not considered. A review of the above and many of the other regional econometric models suggests that they are characterized by the following features: • They tend to be satellite models driven by a national model with a one-way causation from the national to the regional component. The structure of these models (e.g., Wharton, DRI) is, of course, highly complex and considerably improved over the early static approaches evident in the Lakshmanan-Lo model; • Despite significant improvement they still tend to be built around the economic base concept. There is, however, increasing recognition of the myriad of variables that affect the competitive position of the industry in the region. Examples include wages, tax incentives, and different policy instruments of Federal, state, and local governments . D-47 • They tend to be demand driven. In several areas (energy, metal resources, agriculture) , however, supply considerations are equally, if not more important; • Because of data considerations, the models focus around the output, employment, and personal income nexus. Regional inflation and investment are typically ignored in this analysis; and • They tend to be largely recursive because factors outside the regional economy have a major influence. There is little feedback from the region to the Nation and only in a few cases is there interaction with neighboring regions. What then are the prospects for developing a model that would adequately treat at an aggregate level the changes in regional activity resulting from changes in pollution control standards. The discussion below summarizes some of the main features of such a model. • An integrated national-regional modeling approach should be used. Variables like monetary sector variables, consumption, fixed investment, inventory investment, imports and exports are best handled at a national level. Likewise, the impact of abatement expenditures on capital shortages and the trade- offs between abatement and facility investment are logically treated on a national level. However, employment wages, personal income, retail trade and other variables are determined at a regional level and aggregated to derive national forecasts. • National outputs are allocated to industries by region through functions that include competitiveness variables, including the dual role of the environment — with stringent standards acting as a deterrent but a clean environment influencing a positive effect. Where feasible, the recovery of municipal abatement costs through user charges should be included in the industry cost structure. • Regional investment would be affected by national investment and by various local variables including taxes, pollution abatement regulations, etc. That affects distribution of national investment among regions. • Regional employment is influenced by regional industry output but also considers (a) the cost of labor relative to their labor costs, and (b) the need for labor to operate abatement facilities. (Income and wages would also be modeled together with employment at a regional level.) • Regional energy costs are important to integrate into the regional production function for two reasons. First, increasing energy prices and regional differences in them due to limited fuel resources are likely to play an important role in industry location decisions. Second, a significant share of pollution D-48 abatement costs falls on the electric utilities sector. The differences in fuel mix, as well as abatement standards by state (as evident in the SIP's) result in differences in the extent to which environmental regulations affect regional fuel prices thus affecting industry location decisions. These features are the bare outlines of the structure of a regional model that could adequately estimate the impact of environmental standards on regional growth and economic activity. Many questions remain to be answered. These include: the appropriate level of regional and industry detail, the availability of data, the appropriate national model to serve as a starting point, and, finally, the specific policy instruments that need to be explicitly included. 3.2 Use of Various Models to Build Regulatory Requirements Into Location Decisions Under the Clean Air Act of 1977, there is still the basic requirement that states and regions make some decisions and set some policies about the types of growth they wish to experience and the types of firms they wish to attract. Thus, analyses are required of capital support tactics (state supplied utilities, development bonds, etc.) and personnel and skills availability. Environmental requirements, however, are not expected to substantially affect the way a firm looks at these two factors in its search for a location. The location problem is sometimes reduced to the materials supply and market access level, which tends to leave aside labor, capital, and regu- latory spatial variations. Even where the multiplicity of factors is recognized, it is unlikely to find an explicit location decision structure which incorporates them (Table 7) . More traditional approaches to the development of location models have dealt with distances from suppliers and consumers, and weights for these distances which represent costs and prices (Isard, 1974; Isard and Liossatos, 1972; Kohn, 1974; Moody and Humphrey, 1974; and Revelle, Marks, and Liebman, 1970) . A review of this approach is provided by Webber (1972) , who presents a model of the type: m Z * J3 (w.d..) + w d where "n" possible production sites exist at a series of distances "d" from a series of raw materials sites "m," and there is One consumption location c. Thus d. . is a distance from a raw materials site to a possible production site and d. is a distance from a possible production site to the consumption center. The production site i must be chosen to minimize Z. The weight for each raw material w. varies but is characteristic for each raw material, and w c is the amount of product needed at c. D-49 Table 7 Control System direct and looped relationships be- tween decision-makers of various hierarchical levels and each of the elements of the decision environment SCALE LABOUR DECISION MAKER TRANSFER CONSTRAINTS AND INCENTIVES LAND CAPITAL DEMAND AND SUPPLY Source: P. Toyne, Organization Location and Behavior , New York: John Wiley, 1974, p. 15. D-50 Although such a model could perhaps solve a location problem for a given firm, it does not reflect many factors which are equally as important as materials and consumption locations, and it would require substantial development to achieve that level of complexity. The model nevertheless probably represents one portion of the decision process of relocating firms . 3.3 Strategies for Adding Regulatory Constraints To Location Models, and For Model Applications Substitutions are certainly possible in the definitions of the Webber model described above. For example, w- could be the weight of pollutant produced by the use of the raw material from location j for some typical amount used (e.g., sulphur oxides from fuel oil). Solving the optimization problem twice would present a choice between two suboptimal sites, and such a choice could be made by some other technique. Firms are not required, however, to minimize emissions, but to bring them within the SIP or NSPS requirements, and the pollution weights w. could not be set until the firm already had planned its emissions reduction strategy. 3.3.1 Improving the Decision Process by Extending Models and by Linking Models with Other Techniques The redefintion of the weights in the Webber model does not add any terms to the model and presumably would not add to the complexity of its solution. Such a substitution would not reflect the possible interaction of pollution control costs and other production factor costs within the location decision process. An example of a model -which relates pollution abatement costs to other production factors is in the reports by Comolli (1974) and by Werczberger (1974). These models do not have distance components, however, so that it is difficult to view them as location models. In order to extend these models to incorporate a location component, the production functions would have to be modified to contain the distance measures as cost factors. As noted above, location models can be used to generate more than one (nearly) optimal site and then other decision techniques are available. A location choice game is described by Webber (1972, pp. 96-116) but more subjective techniques which are available would include psychometric, as well as Delphi techniques. 3.3.2 Applications of Models by State and Local Agencies to Analyze Alternative Sites The extension of the models mentioned above would be more appropriate if better notions were available as to how they would fit into the decision D-51 process. Assuming that both private firms, as well as public agencies will be involved, each type of entity will use the models from its own approach. With regard to public agencies, a series of sites (in cities, industrial parks, rural areas, etc.) would be compared to obtain a series of site groups for different industries. The site list would then be available for reference when a firm appeared seeking a location. The data for each site would include factor costs, such as labor, power, and pollution control. 3.3.3 Applications of Models by Private Location Advisory Firms, Railroads and Private Industrial Site Developers A number of other users for location models exist, including advisors, banks, railroads, and real estate developers. Each of these has a different approach, but each one would use a location model to advise his clients (firms who wish to relocate) on the advantages of alternative sites. Thus, optimizing models would not actually be needed. 3.4 Interindustry Models in Location Decisions and Their Potential for Incorporating Regulatory Requirements The interindustry input-output model uses a series of coefficients to distribute payments among pairs of sectors. For any sector, the value of payments to each sector is calculated, and if such a matrix were defined for each of a series of regions or states, then interregional (interstate) advantages would become apparent. Although Isard has published a technique for incorporating pollution control costs directly into the input-output system, an alternative approach is to use the input-output coefficients to generate pollution amounts, and then to apply a separate set of cost factors to obtain control costs. A linked system such as that described could be used to assess the potential impacts of a single new firm, and would be of interest to the firm with respect to its pollution control costs and its raw material costs. 3 . 5 Normative Approaches In Section 1.0, above, we briefly touched upon why we should care about the locational consequences discussed in Sections 2.0 and 3.0 of this paper. W. Isard, "Activity- Indus trial Complex Analysis for Environmental Management, " Papers of the Regional Science Association , Vol. 33, 1974, pp. 127-140; J. H. Cumberland, "A Regional Interindustry Model for Analy- sis of Development Objectives," Papers of the Regional Science Associ- ation , Vol. 17, 1966, pp. 65-95; and W. H. Miernyk, "Some Regional Impacts of the Rising Costs of Energy," The Regional Science Association Papers , Vol. 37, 1976, pp. 213-227. D-52 We have described the logical reasons for believing there will be locational conesequences (Section 2.0) and some empirical findings (Section 3.0) , recog- nizing that the locational consequences of the Clean Air Act of 1977 will require some time to unravel. And a number of commentators have begun to examine the tradeoffs involved and the normative questions generally of the economic-environmental balance at the urban and regional levels (Blair, 1973, Davis, et. al, 1974; Forster, 1977, Kamien and Schwartz, 1977; and Walter, 1971) , particularly the dynamic, intertemporal aspects. In Table 8, we return again to this question: Why should we care? The Clean Air Act is portrayed in this Table as having three classes of "economic" consequences: macrolevel effects on investment, prices, output, foreign trade, and other national-level economic variables; designation of areas and corresponding abatement strategies; and effects, both national and regional, impacting on environmental quality, human health, property values, and other more "benefit-oriented" variables. Through the macrolevel consequences, a normative analysis would require an analysis of both the resulting economic efficiency and equity results, at the national level. The regional (locational) consequences are viewed as more complex, resulting, as economic logic has it, from three sources at least: the overall macro effects, the areal designation and regional-diverse abatement strategies, and the "benefit" variables (which impact both on the regional labor force, population, and migration patterns) . Picturing the regional decision to locate/expend/migrate in a regional setting as the consequence of (at least) these three forces, Table 8 next portrays the resultant effects on regional output and employment, and the inputs to an analysis of economic efficiency and equity at the regional level (as well as the interaction between these regional effects and efficiency/equity results) . Nor does this complete the normative analysis since the regional effects are seen to exert a "feedback effect" on national employment and both together — national and regional efficiency and equity effects — must be combined to provide inputs to the policy analysis, which examines the resultant benefit-cost issues, preferred sets of compensatory policies, and public sector budgetary implications. In turn, of course, the policy analysis results become a major input into evaluation and proposed revisions of the Clean Air Act. This is an idealized version of a normative analysis. Were we to flesh out the efficiency and equity issues further, we would need to delve into the normative implications of the well-known Tiebout hypothesis, which views the diversity of a nation's regions and jurisdictions as a positive contribution to economic welfare, operating much as the market mechanism does in a competi- tive private sector. Other subnational investigations of the efficiency- equity effects of locational decisions would need to be reviewed, particularly Charles M. Tiebout, "A Pure Theory of Local Expenditure," Journal of Political Economy , October, 1956; Dennis Epple , Allan Zelenitz, and Michael Visscher, "A Search for Testable Implications of the Tiebout Hypothesis," June, 1978. D-53 *2 -^ "J to o rt ™ "-* c ** CO £ >s O m ° d rt < a w (U > — — ^■^ s Oh o 4-> -r-> 4-> c o 4-> 5 g q CD o • r-< > r-l C o g c i— i G O o < CO -i r-H r-i nJ W •H LI i—i w cu * « c cu s to to CD to CO CO < ,G +-> CO rG G CJ -r-t rt -l-> o ri r- < u (I) a, « < O • r-l i— t s o o -r-1 +-> >> c o 1—1 o nj W a i < i— i *M +-> o c s 6 cd c 1M OU ^ Rl .r-l -i-i > Q G 5 w i—i h • i CO w « O fM O Hj< 00 O o co o ■t oo m f— 1 v£> 2 rt 2 i-H M o o m o O^ vO o co co r- m co r- oo in CO t- co O rt M *G~ m o r~ in FPA Senate House CAA Regs. Proposal Proposal 1977 15 15 20 20 100 100 91 91 700 700 325 512 o- t» — • CO 0"> 00 rt CO o o •-i CO o o rt CO EPA Senate House CAA, Regs. Proposal Proposal 1977" 2 2 1.6 2 5 5 7.3 5 25 25 26 25 CO 111 5 5 7.5 5 10 10 15 10 7J rt Ph W 4) u S .3 o W Q Annual 24-Hour 3 -Hour Total Suspended Particulat Annual 24 -Hour o in °V c rt a,t3 u o a, ° rt . « q M » J i-i 3 '" a o a o K - * « <0 U -c E . rt o c c *• o B~ <-» go N s >» c 2 09 M 3 oj 5* .3 W n o < a 2 -• (d © •" .2 -O l-l *» ^ rt fM CO C " U £ § CO Ti i-P t; o — ' y « c rj o ° S 5 5 • e s s ° "* M H-> i-i -3 C rt m rt O i-i 3 P.* 3 o -g o £S « ffi 6 c rt o 4> • _ ' rt •Cot! *> ~ rt ^ £ u O *j c •h rt « a X u *. ♦» C c +> o « Q. U E S < ti >- rt ^1 Tt C o • rH (J I-l V a. m in o r- >n a < < 4> X. a. 3 C o rt ■a rt i- eo 4) -o CO O ^ ^i a, a o in 00 MJ o a v U >s ti u ss h -I 4) rt D. « «) U s » c - 13 o *• c .H rt i. 5 s « ° In » O CO 6 2 "* -w rt i-l "O i-H 4> 3 t> w *o ~ O 4) >> *" "O L| 4-» >iH « 2 S •a a .2 g g^ o rt ** 4) 3 CO CO "M — T3 "3 O ^? W O rt rt C O rt «H U CO < w S- 1 0) CO rt Tl co t, m rt (j co £ o ■* js u i o CO "« u ** CU CO T3 4) -a rt XI rt o 2 rt O •o •H o <<-( rl J-» o a. .1-1 u T3 4) co c fM I . CO •-> i < «—l ■!-> f> c 4) £ X 4) 4-1 U o n rt a • I-l ill ■*-* M u 3 c o < c £ vm o o o •.-1 I-l -t-* <*-! 4) 60 rtj rt u o 4) C vi to i) rt rt 4-» a 4) 4-1 i-i Q O 4) -M 41 u < Ph W w o « 8 Q +-> q rt o a bfl • i-H CO > a; CO CO Z en i— i rt co O Oh o Oh 6 u • i-H < CD i-H rt o I I 0) E-i D-59 Table 10 -- Proposed BACT Definitions (House) Best Available Control Technology (BACT) was assumed to be equivalent to the following emission rates. (Note: The range indicates the use of different grade coals -- FGD on medium- sulfur coal in the East and FGD on low-sulfur coal in the West). Coal- Fired Power Plant Kraft Pulp and Paper Mills (with on-site coal-fired power generation) Gasoline Refinery Fuel Oil Refinery Oil Shale Plant Gasification Plant Copper Smelter 0. 12-0.46 lbs/million Btu 0. 12-0.46 lbs/million Btu 0. 3% sulfur content 0. 3% sulfur content Emissions from Colony EIS include controls on major emission sources. 0.2 lbs/million Btu on steam plant only; 99% control of TSP Stack emissions of 6.4 lbs/ton of concentrate plus 1% of input sulfur (captured fugitive emis- sions); Uncaptured fugitive emissions equal to 0. 5% of Input sulfur. Source : EPA Briefing on Impact of Significant Deterioration , July 20, 1978, Attachment D, p. 22 (unpublished). D-60 Table 11 -- Proposed BACT Definitions (Senate) Best Available Control Technology (BACT) = NSPS assumed the following emission rates. (Note: The letter (A) indicates that no NSPS exists and that a practicable fuel- sulfur content was assumed). Coal- Fired Power Plant Kraft Pulp and Paper Mills (with on-site coal-fired power generation) (A) (A) (A) (A) 1.2 lbs/million Btu 1.2 lbs/million Btu 0. 75% sulfur content (by weight) 0. 75% sulfur content (by weight) Emissions from Colony EIS include controls on major emission sources. 1.2 lbs/million Btu on the steam plant. Emissions from gasification process are derived from individual EIS. Stack emissions of 6.4 lbs/ton of concentrate plus 1% of input sulfur (captured fugitive emis- sions). Uncaptured fugitive emissions equal to o. 5% of input sulfur. BACT = Control Beyond NSPS was assumed to be equivalent to the following emission rates. (Note: The range indicates the use of different grade coals -- FGD on medium- sulfur coal in the East and FGD on low- sulfur coal in the West). Gasoline Refinery Fuel Oil Refinery Oil Shale Plant Gasification Plant Copper Smelter Coal- Fired Power Plant Kraft Pulp and Paper Mills (with on-site coal-fired power generation) Gasoline Refinery Fuel Oil Refinery Oil Shale Plant Gasification Plant Copper Smelter 0. 12 - 0.46 lbs/million Btu 0. 12 - 0.46 lbs /million Btu 0. 3% sulfur content 0. 3% sulfur content Not Applicable 0. 2 lbs/million Btu on steam plant only; 99% control of TSP Not Applicable SOURCE: EPA Briefing on Impact of Significant Deterioration, July 20, 1978, Attachment C, p. 19 (unpublished). D-61 The analyses suggested would be a useful preamble to analysis of regu- latory impacts on corporate location decisions. The preliminary survey development for inquiring into such impacts has been done both at EPA, the Department of Labor (EPA Economic Dislocation Early Warning System, a quarterly letter prepared by EPA and Labor Department regional offices) , and also at the Department of Commerce. A summary of the Department of Commerce-Bureau of Economic Analysis surveys appeared in the Survey of Current Business for June, 1978 (Table 12). Survey data on industry decisions is nevertheless likely to be difficult to obtain in detail because of firms' understandable reluctance to disclose planned expansions relocations prematurely. As noted by EPA in their analysis of possible impacts on kraft pulp and paper mill locations: The most ideal sites to analyze to determine the impact of proposals to prevent significant deterioration of air quality (NSD) are the ones currently under consideration by the major corporations in the pulp and paper industry. However, future site planning is a closely guarded secret and it has not been possible to gather this information from individual firms or the American Paper Institute (API) . An * alternative approach which is used in this report is to analyze historical data under the hypothetical premise that NSD regulations went into effect at the time the mills were proposed for construction. Locational decisions during this period actually ignored NSD consider- ations and it is, therefore, possible to isolate whatever impact NSD could have had in terms of capacity precluded and additional pollution control costs. This reluctance and the resulting lack of data place even more importance on a statistical analysis of regulatory impacts. One approach being investigated is the measurement of SIP's along such dimensions as: • Existing source emissions restrictions, • Ambient air quality standards (relative to EPA) , m Measurement of areas in Class I, II, and III designations, and • Record of enforcement and litigation. * Environmental Protection Agency, Analysis of the Impact on the Kraft Pulp and Paper Industry of Alternative Approaches to Significant Deterioration," June 4, 1976 (unpublished) , p. 3. cut C u z o nj "3 C « c o J! « 5 2 •o in m o ■-• «a* «* (M rj o r- cr- «»• Tf CO -+ o m a- *r co m CO •-» IM M x> co m o in co et c 2 u ID 3 c ft) 2 jj oo c *- ft CO CO I- — o o^ oo r- no — -i f- o* o f in o in 2 •ION CO -« ^* ^|l CO O^ *t c* no co in N M M 00 41 u a C < 4> CO C 1- c o» CtJ r-l rH •* co cm ^ ~i o^ CM r-i 00 CO *+ %o c- co co r*- vO o eg o ^o ^* «-< OJ •* -43 00 CO rr CO CM All actual closings 1974-77 CM — i CO co r< ^" co s co •-* Sample closings Permanent closings Establishment Facility within an establish- ment Temporary closings D-62 CO r- c*- <-* ■a %> o c It 3 60 & «3 ^ 0) •rH & 0) « q CD c m nj CO 3 « J3 a o 0) o h •H *-> u 5 ■o • r—i 4> > cy CO a co O r3« Oh c 41 11 c8 0- v Ok a Xl a. . • r-t 4> > ca co > i-H .c Li 4) o > >• 3 ° 6 z a> (A , * M i— < u~ q 01 .r-l DO "•3 CO o <0 O o i— i >- el S >* en .5 c +J •H n * 5 i— 1 a. E • 2. u Q Q « c u a ^ « U » u 1 1 5 ""o CN « •o >■ rH 01 41 (J 3 3 « w rH ♦^ ►4 co* Eh -1 r» It O 2. e i D-63 Any of these or other measures must then be analyzed with respect to the two other classes of data mentioned above: industrial investment and productivity data, and air quality and emissions data. At present, there is no well- developed theory to link the three data sets, but further analysis of a controlled experiment type of design will be necessary before any one of the classes can be ruled out of an air quality/regional growth theory. D-64 5.0 CONCLUDING REMARKS We have covered a variety of subjects in this paper and, unfortunately , have reached no definitive conclusions about the locational effects and further downstream consequences of the clean air legislation, particularly the Clean Air Act of 1977. The literature we have reviewed is, indeed, sparse as it relates to the specific question (s) of the treatment and control of the attendant costs of air pollution standards on "industrial location" (or, even more broadly, the geographical deployment of employment and output) . Why is the empirical data and analysis so sparse? Perhaps too short a period has passed. Perhaps the analytic problem is too complex and no one has been able to formulate it very well. No one, for example, has yet thought of it as a supply-demand problem, i.e., as a supply of industrial location land and infrastructure (physical, economic, and social) versus a demand for indus- trial locatable land (etc.). Simple multiple regressions just will not handle this level of complexity. Similarly for data bases: Which make the most sense? Many, many gaps in an "ideal" data system exist. We believe this, inexorably perhaps, has led us to the following conclusions : • This is an ideal time to begin to monitor the impacts of an important regulatory activity, i.e., the Clean Air Act and its implementation. The logic of the Clean Air Act is such that we can anticipate that it will most likely have substantial locational effects -- but we may never get to know these. We are not ready to measure, estimate, or project these consequences; the analytic concepts have not been fleshed out and the data bases are almost surely inadequate. • The work to date — by government agencies, academics, and industry -- on the consequences (on industrial location) of clean air and other environmental legislation is not convincing; difficult to assemble; and probably not useful for estimating the future consequences. • If industrial location is_ affected, in a substantial way for some sectors and in some places, as we expect it will, it will have both microeconomic impacts (i.e., on economic efficiency) and, possibly, macroeconomic effects (i.e., on jobs and output) . Prices and costs would be affected in either case. A preliminary framework for tracing these micro- and macroeconomic impacts, as these might result from regulation- induced changes in industrial location, is developed in this paper. Implementation of this framework is not, however, likely to be a simple research task. D-65 Even if the CAA has substantial locational consequences, we do not and cannot conclude that benefits from the Act do not exceed its costs; however, we do believe it would be worthwhile to begin to measure these costs and, where benefits would not be affected, find ways to mitigate unintended locational misallocation effects. Nor can we definitely assess with confidence alternative approaches, e.g., increasing the use of air pollution rights markets. Nevertheless, attention to matters discussed in this paper will increase our ability to make such policy decisions . D-67 APPENDIX: Annotated Bibliography • D-69 Title: Author(s): Source Title: Citation: Year: Subject: Environ mental Improvement Through Economic Incentives F. Anderson, A. Kneese, P. Reed, S. Taylor, R. Stebenson Resources for the Future, Washington, D. C. 1978 "Charge" strategies as a means for environmental control; economic incentives Abstract: This book examines the "charge" concept as an alter- native to past environmental control strategies that can be used instead of or in conjunction with direct regulation to control air and water pollution, noise, congestion, and other activities that degrade the environment. Environmental charges levied on polluting activities provide an incentive to discon- tinue or abate these activities by making the polluter pay while at the same time providing a cost-effective means of control. The authors cite advantages of this strategy: 1) given a legislatively determined level of environmental quality as a goal, the average costs of controlling environmental harms in various industries could be used to design a charge that achieves a high level of efficiency; 2) charge systems, are more cost effective than regulations; that is, since each source decides how much to control on the basis of its own control cost the sources with high control costs will control less and the sources with low control costs will control more, the net result being that the average cost of control per unit of pollu- tant would be lower than it would be under regulatory strategies; and 3) the EPA and state agencies could direct their administrative expertise to monitoring technologies instead of production and pollution control technologies. This book analyzes the dynamics of implementing charges, including the political, legal, and technical problems involved. The theoretical basis of the charge concept is outlined, and an extensive survey of existing and proposed charge systems is presented. D-70 Title: The Steel Industry: Problems and Solutions Author (s): Jules Backman Source Title: Challenge Citation: Year: Subject: July -August 1978 Recovery program for the steel industry Abstract: In the first part of this paper, Backman outlines the problems facing the U. S. steel industry. Included in his discussion are: lagging growth rate, import competition, slower increases in productivity, decline in employment, increases in labor costs, political price pressures and antipollution costs. It is pointed out that pollution abatement costs are mandated investments which do not yield additional output and contribute to a slower rate of productivity. Backman offers solutions in the form of: allowing industry more freedom to solve its own problems, holding down of steel labor costs, faster write-offs for anti- pollution costs, additional incentives for modernization and replacement of existing plants, the diversification of steel industry to broaden its industrial base and quicker enforcement of antidumping regulations on foreign imports. D-71 Title: Author (s): The Urban Impact of Federal Policies: Their Direct and Indirect Effects on the Local Public Sector Stephen M. Barro Source Title: Citation: Year: Subject: Small Cities in Transition; The Dynamics of Growth and Decline Ballinger Publishing Co. , Cambridge, Ma. 1977 Impact of regulations on urban areas Abstract: This chapter examines the effect of federal policies on urban areas using a three -sector system. The interacting sectors are 1) the private business sector, 2) the residential, or household sector, and 3) the urban public sector. Two general points about federal policy formation emerge. They are: the potential importance of indirect federal policies -- those that operate via linkages among the different sectors within the urban system -- and the finding that locational incentives ought to be central elements in the development of a comprehensive urban policy. D-72 Title: Author: Source Title: Citation: Year: Subject: Abstract: Statement Prepared for the U. S. House of Representatives Select Committee on Population David Birch Hearings, June 6, 1978 1978 Factors affecting industrial location Birch explores the "underlying causes" of the recent regional, urban and rural, metropolitan- non-metropolitan employment and population shifts; the "main course of net change is the differential rate at which constant (and high) losses are replaced". He forecasts that these causes are structural and relatively permanent so that public sector actions to reverse the decline of the North- east and Midwest are likely to be ineffective; rather, Birch suggests that declining areas better manage their conditions of negative growth. Picturing the "entrepreneur" as the key, somewhat footloose* factor in locational decisions, Birch believes the factors which have caused their southward and western move- ments will continue for the indefinite future. Prepared in a journalistic style for the Hearings, Birch only briefly cites the data bases used to reach these find- ings, including a file of 5. 6 million business estab- lishments describing, for each, its characteristics and status in 1969, 1972, 1974, and 1976, as well as a file of 1. 5 million members of the workforce over an 11-year period, including location of each job. As to firm migration, Birch finds that the physical mi- gration of firms from one state or area to another is relatively insignificant as a cause of change. "Al- though highly and widely reported in the press when they occur, the net effect of such migrations rarely exceeds a tenth of a percent of the job base in any particular place in any year. " There is little further analysis of this finding, except to conclude that "in- dependent entrepreneurs" (as opposed to headquarters, subsidiaries and branches) create almost 75% of al] the job replacement ("births") due to both the creation of new establishments and/ or the expansion of existing establishments. D-73 Title: Authors): Problems of Pollution Standards: The Clean Air Act of 1970 Roger D. Blair Source Title: Land Economics Citation: Year: Subject: Abstract: August, 1973, p. 260 1973 Critique of the Clean Air Act of 1970 The author advocates the use of taxation instead of regulation to achieve desired air quality. The government could levy a uniform per unit tax on all firms in an air basin, revising the tax in an iterative fashion so as to achieve ambient air quality standards, It is argued that a tax scheme will lead to a better allocation of resources among industries than rigid emissions regulations. The Clean Air Act of 1970 is also criticized for containing an ambiguous policy with respect to new sources of pollutants and not defining a policy for existing sources. The enforcement process for the Act is analyzed with regard to the expected behavior of the EPA Administrator, industrial groups and local governments. Finally, some methods for analyzing the tradeoff between air quality and the consumption of other goods are mentioned, but all of these have weaknesses. D-74 Title: Author(s): Source Title: Citation: Year: Subject: Regional Residual-Environmental Quality Management Modeling Blair T. Bower, Editor Resources for the Future, Washington, D. C, 1978 Environment management modeling Abstract: This research report provides an overview of regional residuals -environmental quality management and of the analysis necessary to generate information for de- cisions on such management. This volume helps to provide background for, and insights on, the analytical problems faced in developing useful information for societal decisions on residuals -environmental quality management. 3 D-75 Title: Author(s): Pollution Abatement Costs and Expenditures, 1976-MA-200 (76)-2 Bureau of the Census Source Title: Citation: Year: Subject: Current Industrial Report U. S. Government Printing Office, Washington D. C, 1977 Pollution abatement costs Abstract: This is the annual report on 1976 pollution abatement control capital expenditures and operating costs for the U. S. by SIC 4 digit industry and for the States and SMSA's by SIC 2 digit industry. Data are from the Pollution Abatement Costs and Expenditures (PACE) survey of 19,000 manufacturing establishments selected as a subs ample from the 70,000 establishments in the 1973 Annual Survey of Manufactures (ASM) sample. Tables include: pollution abatement capital expenditures and operating costs by (1) form of abatement and major industry group, (2) form of abatement and state, and (3) employment size class of establishment and major industry group. Other tables include quantities of pollutants removed and related statistics and pollution abatement costs and related statistics. D-76 Title: Author(s): Source Title: Citation: Year: Subject: Macroeconomic and Industry Impacts of Water Pollution Abatement Legislation R. Chao, N. G. Dossani; CONSAD Research Corporation Paper presented at the Western Economic Association 1976 Conference 1976 Impact of water pollution abatement legislation Abstract: This paper summarizes the principal results of a study of the impacts of PL 92-500, the Federal Water Pollution Control Act Amendments of 1972. The study focused on analyzing the impacts on major economic indicators as well as on prices, investments and other variables at the industry level. The results are summarized as follows: Under the assumption of a control baseline and adherence to compliance schedules the results indicate that abatement expenditures do serve as a stimulus to the economy initially; about midway through the forecast period real GNP dips below baseline and by 1985 is 3 percent below baseline. The impact on inflation is not insignificant in the same scenario. The inflation rate is about . 9 percent higher due to the abatement expenditures. The incremental impact of BAT (1983) expenditures are milder than the impacts of BPT (1977) standards. Results reported elsewhere (4) indicate that BAT standards involve significant additional removal of major pollutant categories. While a comprehensive benefit-cost assess- ment must await further analysis, the economic impact results obtained here could provide useful inputs to this analysis. D-77 Title: Author(s): The Macroeconomic Impacts of Federal Pollution Control Programs Chase Econometric Associates, Inc. Source Title: Citation: Year: Subject: The Status of Environmental Economics: A Report Prepared for the Committee on Public Works, U. S. Senate June, 1975 Economic impacts of environmental regulations Abstract: This anlysis is based upon CEQ/EPA estimates of incremental abatement costs associated with current federal air and water pollution control legislation . The analysis used the Chase Econometrics macro- economic and input/output models which were linked together into a single solution algorithm. The system allows analysis of both the impacts that different industries have on one another and on the interaction between pollution control expenditures and general economic factors. The cost estimated for abatement are based on the 1974 edition of The Cost of Clean Air and the 1973 edition of The Economics of Clean Water. The study concludes that pollution control expenditures for 1973 to 1982 will have a noticeable but modest effect on the over- all economy in terms of higher prices, unemployment and lower growth rate of the GNP, but goes on to state that by 1982 the differences gradually diminish and growth and employment will be at virtually the same levels which would occur in the absence of pollution control investment. D-78 Abstract Under a "low growth" baseline the impacts are compar- (continued): able to the control baseline if a compliance schedule and a "low" municipal spending scenario is assumed. How- ever, higher levels of spending result in stimulative effects that keep GNP above baseline till near the end of the forecast period. The stimulative effects of abatement spending are stronger and inflationary impacts milder if in-process (as opposed to end-of-pipe) technologies are used to comply. D-79 Title: The Economics of Environmental Policy- Author (s): S. V. Ciriacy-Wantrup Source Title: Land Economics Citation: February, 1971, p. 36 Year: Subject: Abstract: 1971 Welfare economics, benefit-cost analysis, and the ocean environment Systems of thought for assessing alternative environmental policies are described. These include the Pareto criterion, welfare economics and benefit- cost analysis. The weaknesses of these systems are pointed out. The Pareto criterion is often irrelevant since there are scarcely any policies (environmental or otherwise) which affect no one negatively. Benefit-cost analysis uses national income as a proxy for social welfare-- a scientific fiction which may become mere dogma if one is unwary. A three-level hierarchy of decision systems is described. Finally, implication of economic analysis for the ocean environment are presented. The need to distinguish between common resources and "fugitive" resources is stressed in this discussion. D-80 Title: The Distributive Effects of Public Law 92-500 Author(s): Robert A. Collins Source Title: Journal of Environmental Economics and Management Citation: Year: Subject: Volume 4, Number 4, pp. 345-354 1977 Distribution impact of Clean Water Act Abstract: Title II of the 1972 "Clean Water Act" provided for a potentially massive federal construction grant program for the construction of publicly-owned wastewater treatment plants. Part of this subsidy accrues to municipalities and the remainder to industry. The regulations for these federal grants are somewhat perplexing and it is not obvious who will benefit and by how much. The objective of this article is to quantify the subsidies received by municipalities and industry and estimate the effect on the distribution of income under certain assumptions. It is concluded that these federal construction grants are likely to redistribute income from the middle -income classes to primarily the very rich. D-81 Title: Pollution Control in a Simplified General-Equilibrium Model with Production Externalities Author0, then these constraints will result in a fall in production and a rise in price respectively, aQN and B 2 Po where (0 . . ., the profitability of the 1st, 2nd, . . . , nth sites, and nc is the discounted cost of sampling the (n + l)th site. The book is broadly theoretical and presents data only from the studies reviewed. The literature and concepts which are integrated into location theory are extremely diverse and provide for a complex theory covering location of cities, households, and firms. D-164 Title: The Costs of Government Regulation of Business Author (s): Murray L. Weidenbaum Source Title: Citation: Year: Subject: Prepared for the use of the Subcommittee on Economic Growth and Stabilization of the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States April, 1978 Abatement costs Abstract: This report examines the various costs that are incurred in the process of government regulation. Government regulation is described as a major growth industry supported by the taxpayer . Preliminary figures for the fiscal year 1979 show a total of $4.8 billion in federal expenditures to operate 41 agencies which regulate business. The author discusses the impacts of regulation on employment, small business, consumers, etc. as well as alternatives to regulation and changing attitudes towards regulation. D-165 Title: Author(s): A Mixed -Integer Programming Model for the Integration of Air Quality Policy and Land Use Planning Elia Werczberger Source Title: Papers of the Regional Science Association Citation: Year: Subject: Volume 23 1974 Pollution control costs in industrial decision models Abstract: Integration of air quality considerations into land-use planning requires two kinds of policies: 1) air-quality management, i. e. , control of the location and quantity of pollutant emissions to ensure maintenance of air-quality standards; and 2) locational policies which prevent pollu- tion-sensitive activities such as housing or hospitals from locating in high-pollution areas. The optimal allocation of resources is constrained by the various air-quality objectives applicable to any subarea. To simplify, assume that only one pollutant is relevant to the air -quality policy. The air -quality objective for each activity is expressed as: 2 << e i« ™.r)Xik.a ~ t^ir « (b, - q r Y (for all i, f) where: X jksa e. m sr number of units of activity j. the average emission rate of activity j when technology a is used; the contribution to the average pollutant concentration in area r which results from a pollution source of unit strength located in s; D-166 Abstract M = a very large number; (continued): b. = the air quality objective; this is expressed as the upper limit of the mean pollutant concentration which must be maintained in any area in which a unit of the ith activity is located, and this objective is set low enough that pollution costs incurred by activity i can be neglected; q = background pollution in area r resulting from sources which are outside the juris- diction of the planning agency. The net value of a shelter unit is then given by c^ ra which equals the present value of the difference between the rent activity that i is willing to pay for a shelter unit of type k in r, when it expects to use technology a, and the cost of providing the shelter unit. The objective function is then: Max L= 2 c ikra X ikra . i,k,r,a D-167 Title: Regional Growth and Industrial Location Author(s): Leonard F. Wheat Source Title: Citation: Year: Subject: Lexington Books, Lexington, Massachusetts 1973 Regional growth factors Abstract: This is a study of the forces influencing regional growth in the U.S. , and seeks to identify and evaluate the relative importance of factors that cause one region to grow faster than another. States are basic units examined. The study uses manufacturing employment to measure growth changes in manufacturing. The study outlines recent empirical studies of regional growth, absolute growth, per capita growth and percentage growth. The locational influences examined in this study are (1) markets, (2) climate, (3) labor, (4) thres' holds, or foundation levels of development, (5) resources, (6) the urban attraction, and (7) agglomeration. Wheat asserts that the findings leave no doubt that markets and climate are the leading influences affecting manufacturing growth in the U.S. Wheat concludes that the study findings have definite policy implications for governmental programs designed to assist distressed areas, and these agencies should try to bolster the assests of the cities in these areas in order to influence plant locations. Title: Author(s): D-168 Government Regulation, America's Number One Growth Industry- Source Title: Citation: Year: Subject: Notes from the Joint Economic Committee, United States Congress Newsletter Volume IV, Number 11, May 16, 1978 1978 Cost and effect of regulations on small business Abstract: This newsletter reviews the examination currentlv being undertaken by Congress of the high cost of excessive government regulation and its negative effects on small businesses. The article details examples of the costs of and conflicts between regulations arid demonstrates the effects of the laws on consumers, taxpayers, motorists, businessmen, homeowners, and investors using material taken from a study by Murray Weidenbaum for the Subcommittee on Economic Growth and Stabilization. * *An abstract of this report is included elsewhere in this bibliography. D-169 Title: Status Report: Other Environmental Impacts Author (s): Source Title: Citation: Year: Subject: The Status of Environmental Economics: A Report prepared for the Committee on Public Works, U. S. Senate June, 1975 Impacts of environmental programs Abstract: This section is a summary of direct and indirect positive impacts of environmental programs, exploring employment generation materials and resource conservation and new products. Estimates were obtained through manpower studies in state, federal and industry reports. The article states that with capital investments and operation and maintenance expenditures, the manufacturing, installation and operating of air pollution controls will become a major source of jobs during 1973- 1982. Title: Author(s): D-170 U. S. Industry Needs $24. 67 Billion to Bring Its Existing Facilities Into Compliance Source Title: Journal of the Air Pollution Control Association Citation: Year: Subject: Abstract: July 1974, Volume 24, Number 7, p. 682 1974 Results of McGraw Hill's seventh annual survey of pollution control expenditures Summary results of McGraw-Hill Publication Company's seventh annual survey of pollution control expenditures are presented. Actual spending for 1973 is reported, as well as planned expenditures for 1974 and 1977. Separate figures are given for air and water pollution control expenditures for 26 industrial and commercial sectors. D-171 Related Newspaper and Magazine Articles "Study Cites Firms' 'Flight' to 3rd World to Avoid Safeguards" Helen Dewar The Washington Post. Friday, June 30, 1978 The article discusses the study made by Barry I. Castleman which reports that many industries that produce hazardous products or pollutant emissions are moving these industries to third world countries to avoid the higher costs of meeting worker and environmental protection standards set both by the U. S. and other highly industrialized nations. Rather than paying for the high cost of installing expensive pollution abatement equipment, the industries move to less developed countries where protective rules are minimal and standard of living levels make the area vulnerable to exploitation. Because of bans on certain products, costs imposed on regulation equipment, and preferential tariff treatment given to certain companies, these industries can maintain a competitive edge on products exported and sold to the U.S. Castleman concludes that the U.S. could control this situation by revoking tax credits for offending firms, banning imports of the products or raising tariffs that would eliminate the cost savings the industries now have. "U.S. Sets Rules on Pollution Controls" Charles Mohr The New York Times , Wednesday, June 21, 1978 This article concerns the new governmental regulations that will affect pollution abatement of discharges into city sewer systems. This ruling will impose new investment and operating costs on businesses and could force the closing of small or old businesses that lack capital or space for installation of control equipment. The pretreatment plans that will result in both higher rates of usable water and sludge outputs are expected to offset the cost of pollution controls. Cost cannot be precisely estimated until the detailed standards for industrial categories are formulated. "The Capital Eye" Fred Popper Practicing Planner , June, 1978 The article concerns President Carter's urban policy message of March 27, 1978. Included in the release is a proposal specifically aimed at planning issues. The proposal is for an air quality planning grant program which will provide technical assistance to localities in managing conflicts between air pollution and economic development goals. D-172 "Reserve Mining Company to Remain in Minnesota" The New York Times , Saturday July 8, 1978 The article concerns Reserve Mining Company, one of the major componants in the economy of northeastern Minnesota. Compliance with state and federal environmental laws will cost the company $370 million for pollution controls. The emissions from Reserve have been water waste into Lake Superior and microscopic aebestos fibers released into the air. There had been concern that Reserve would not be able to meet the standards and would shut down, causing 3,000 workers to be laid off. "The Regulation Mess" Newsweek, June 12, 1978 David Pauly, Jane Whitmore, James Jones, Pamela Ellis Simons, Bureau Reports This article discusses efforts being made by the Carter Administration, Congress, and businesses to reduce bureaucracy and inconsistencies of governmental regulatory agencies. Problems such as cost factors, whether to keep forcing companies to obey rules or offer incentives, and whether to specify how to meet goals or allow companies to arrive at their own solutions f are discussed. According to companies, environmental impact statements are unclear, and the White House is calling for shorter, clearer statements in the future. There are moves being made that would allow industry a chance to react to regulations before they are adopted. The article also discusses the growing opposition to the EPA's emission offset policy that is currently in effect. "The Benefits of Regulation" Economic Scene /Carolyn Shaw Bell The New York Times, Tuesday, July 25, 1978 Bell discusses how the cost of government regulations concerning pollution control has been viewed as being inflationary. Regulations have been estimated to have raised the Consumer Price Index and to have reduced productivity growth. Bell argues that regulation should be recognized as a service, producing measurable economic benefits like those of other agencies. She goes on to say that if industrial output were properly calculated to include the benefits of increased safety and better health for employees that vigorous regulations would provide, both economic indicators and economic behavior would change, reducing the inflation spiral and leading to greater output. D-173 "Bottle Maker Cuts Costs, Pollution with Old Glass" Larry Kramer The Washington Post , Sunday, July 2, 1978 The article concerns the efforts of the Glass Containers Corporation of Dayville, Connecticut to rethink its production methods in order to meet environmental air quality standards. By using recycled glass the plant is more efficient, meets air quality standards, and does not have to put in costly abatement equipment. In addition to a new high in employment at the plant, more than $1.4 million has been poured into the local economy and at the same time that plant emissions have been lowered, the search for recycled glass has significantly reduced a large part of New England's litter problem. "EPA Approves Auto Plants under Emission Offset Policy" Environment Reporter - Current Developments Volume 8, p. 220 May 1, 1977 - April, 1978 This article concerns the opening of two auto plants. The GM plant in Oaklahoma City received approval from the EPA after several oil companies in the area were persuaded by the state and local governments to provide offsets by reducing the aggregate emissions of hydrocarbons by 5,280 tons per year. The GM plant will add more than 3,000 tons per year. The Volkswagon plant in New Stanton, Pennsylvania received approval after the state agreed to use low polluting asphalt in road maintenance to offset the estimated 900 tons of hydrocarbon emissions expected from the new plant. The asphalt will reduce emissions by 1,025 tons per year. D-175 INDEX 1. Anderson, F. , et. al. ; Environmental Improvement Through Eco- nomic Incentives , Resources for the Future: Washington, D. C. ; 1978. 2. Backman, Jules; "The Steel Industry: Problems and Solutions"; Challenge, July-August, 1978. 3. Barro, Stephen M; "The Urban Impact of Federal Policies: Their Direct and Indirect Effects on the Local Public Sector"; Small Cities in Transition: The Dyanmics of Growth and Decline; Ballinger Publishing Company: Cambridge, Mass. ; 1977. 4. Birch, David; "Statement Prepared for the U.S. House of Repre- sentatives Select Committee on Population"; Hearings, June 6, 1978. 5. Blair, Roger D. ; "Problems of Pollution Standards: The Clean Air Act of 1970"; Land Economics ; August, 197*3, p. 260. 6. Bower, Blair T. , ed. ; Regional Residual-Environmental Quality Management Modeling ; Resources for the Future, Washington, D.C., 1978. 7. Bureau of the Census, "Pollution Abatement Costs and Ex- penditures, 1976-MA-200 (76)-2"; Current Industrial Report ; U.S. Government Printing Office: Washington, D. C. ; 1977. 8. Chao, R. , and Dossani, N. G. ; "Macroeconomic and Industry Impacts of Water Pollution Abatement Legislation"; Paper pre- sented at the Western Economic Association Conference; 1976. 9. Chase Econometric Associates, Inc. ; "The Macroeconomic Impacts of Federal Pollution Control Programs"; The Status of Environ- mental Economics: A Report Prepared for the Committee on Public Works, U.S. Senate; June, 1975. 10. Ciriacy-Wantrup, S. V. ; "The Economics of Environmental Policy"; Land Economics, February, 1971, p. 36. 11. Collins, Robert A. ; "The Distributive Effects of Public Law 92-500"; Journal of Environmental Economics and Management , Volume 4, Number 4, 1977, pp. 345-354. D-176 INDEX (continued) 12. Comolli, Paul M. ; "Pollution Control in a Simplified General- Equilibrium Model with Production Externalities"; Papers of the Regional Science Association, Volume 23, 1974. 13. Comolli, Paul M. ; "Pollution Control in a Simplified General- Equilibrium Model with Production Externalities"; Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Volume 4, Number 4, 1977, pp. 289-304. 14. Council on Environmental Quality, Executive Office of the Presi- dent; "The Economic Impact of Environmental Programs"; The Status of Environmental Economics: A Report Prepared for the Committee on Public Works, U.S. Senate, June 1975. 15. Council on Environmental Quality; "The Economic Impact of Environmental Programs"; Hearings before the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, November 22, 1974. 16. Davis, R. M. , et. al. ; "Development of an Economic Environmental Trade- Off Model for Industrial Land-Use Planning"; The Review of Regional Studies, Volume 4, Number 1, 1974, pp. 11-26. 17. Dolde, W. , et. al. ; "Dynamic Aspects of Air Quality Control Costs"; Journal of Environment Economics and Management, Volume 4, Number4, 1977, pp. 313-334. 18. Downing, Paul B. , and Brady, Gordon; "Implementing the Clean Air Act: A Case Study of Oxidant Control in Los Angeles"; Natural Resources Journal, Volume 18, Number 2, April, 1978. 19. Engdahl, R. B. ; "A Critical Review of Regulations for the Control of Sulfur Oxide Emissions"; Journal of the Air Pollution Control Association, Volume 23, Number 5, May, 1973, p. 364. 20. Environmental Protection Agency, Compilation of Air Pollutant Emission Factors (Second Edition); Office of Air and Waste Management Research: Triangle Park, North Carolina; August, 1977. 21. Environmental Protection Agency; ,r EPA Economic Dislocation Early Warning System Quarterly Summary Report"; American Statistics Index 1977, 4th Annual Supplement, Congressional Information Service: Washington, D. C. , 1978. D-177 INDEX (continued) 22. Environmental Protection Agency; "1973 National Emissions Report, National Emissions Data System (NEDS) of the Aerometric and Emissions Reporting System"; American Statis- tics Index 1977, 4th Annual Supplement; Congressional Informa- tion Service: Washington, D. C. , 1978. 23. Environmental Research and Technology, Inc. ; "Impact of the EPA Class II Significant Deterioration Regulations on Multiple Industries: Size and Siting Limitations"; Prepared for Environ- mental Policy Office, Federal Energy Administration, Washington, D. C. , Unpublished report, September 1977. 24. Feldstein, Milton; "A Critical Review of Regulations for the Con- trol of Hydrocarbon Emissions from Stationary Sources"; Journal of the Air Pollution Control Association, Volume 24, Number 5, May 1974, p. 469. 25. Forster, Bruce A. ; "Pollution Control in a Two-Sector Dynamic General Equilibrium Model"; Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Volume 4, Number 4, 1977, pp. 305-312. 26. Fortune, Peter; "The Impact of the Federal Water Pollution Con- trol Act of 1972"; unpublished report, Data Resources, Inc., 1975. 27. Fowler, George; "How the Clean Air Law Can Choke Industry"; Nation's Business , Volume 66, Number 7, 1978, pp. 29-36. 28. Freund, James; "Plant Closures and the Regional Consequences of Water Pollution Control"; Unpublished report, 1975. 29. Ginn, J. R. , et. al. ; "The Economic Impact of the Federal Water Pollution Control Act, Amendments of 1972 on the Metal Finishing Industry"; National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. , for the National Commission on Water Quality, unpublished report, 1975. 30. Governor's Science Advisory Committee, The; "Criteria for Power Plant Siting in Pennsylvania"; Panel on Criteria for Power Plant Siting, Executive Summary Report for Governor Milton J. Shapp, 1976. 31. Granessi, et. al. ; "The Distributional Implications of National Air Pollution Damage Estimates"; Resources for the Future, Reprint 150, 1977. D-178 INDEX (continued) 32. Guntermann, Karl L. ; "Air Pollution Control in the Secondary Aluminum Industry"; Land Economics, August 1976, p. 285. 33. Harris, Curtis C. , Jr. , and Hopkins, Frank E. ; Locational Analysis; D. C. Heath and Company; 1972. 34. Hekman, John S. ; "An Analysis of the Changing Location of Iron and Steel Production in the Twentieth Century", The American Economic Review, Volume 68, Number 1, March, 1978, p. 123.. 35. Hellman, Darge A. , et. al. ; State Financial Incentives to Industry; Lexington Books: Lexington, Massachusetts, 1976. 36. Irwin, W. A., and R. A. Liroff; "Economic Disincentives for Pollution Control: Legal, Political and Administrative Dimen- sions"; Socioeconomic Environmental Studies Series, Office of Research and Development, Environmental Protection Agency, 1974. 37. Isard, Walter; "Regional Science and Research on Environmental Management"; Working Papers on the Use of Regional Science Techniques in Environmental Management, Regional Science Dissertation and Monograph Series #3, Center for Urban Develop- ment Research, Cornell University, June, 1974, pp. 1-46. 38. Isard, Walter, and Liossatos, Panagis; "Some Simple Air Pollu- tion and Urban-Regional Growth Models"; Papers of the Regional* Science Association, Volume 29, 1972. 39. Isard, Walter, and Parcels, Larry; "A Locational Analysis for the Petrochemical Industry"; Unpublished report, December, 1977. 40. Isard, Walter, and Parcels, Larry; "A Locational Analysis for the Aluminum Industry"; Unpublished report, December, 1977. 41. Isard, Walter, and Parcels, Larry; "Regional Pattern of Iron and Steel Production, 1985 and 2000"; Unpublished Report, Decem- ber, 1977. 42. Kamien, M. I. , and Schwartz, N. L. ; "Disaggregated Intertemporal Models with an Exhaustible Resource and Technical Advance"; Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Volume 4, Number 4, 1977, pp. 271-288. D-179 INDEX (continued) 43. Kane, Edward R. ; "Prepared Statement on the Economic Impact of Environmental Regulations"; Hearings before the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, November 21, 1974. 44. Kohn, Robert; "Industrial Location and Air Pollution Abatement"; Journal of Regional Science, Volume 14, Number 1, 1974. 45. Lakshmanan, T. R. , and Lo, Fu-chen; "A Regional Economic Model for the Assessment of the Effects of Air Pollution Abatement"; Presented at the Regional Science Association Fourth British Section Meeting, September, 1971. 46. Leintner, Keith R. , and Emerson, M. Jarvin; "Effects of State Pollution Control Programs on Industrial Location"; unpublished report, 1978. 47. Lundberg, Constance K. ; "Industrial Siting and the Clean Air Act"; Presented at the Environmental Law Institute: Conference on Energy and Public Lands, Utah, August 23-26, 1976. 48. Maler, Karl-Goran; " A Note on the Use of Property Values in Estimating Marginal Willingness to Pay for Environmental Quality"; Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Volume 4, Number 4, 1977, pp. 355-369. 49. Mathur, Vijay K. , and Yamada, Hiroyuki; "An Economic Theory of Pollution Control"; The Regional Science Association Papers , Volume 28, 1971, pp. 223-235. 50. McMillan, T. E. , Jr. ; "Why Manufacturers Choose Plant Location versus Determinants of Plant Locations"; Land Economics , Vol- ume XII, Number 3, 1975, pp. 239-244. 51. Meyer, John R. , and Leone, Robert A. ; "The New England States and Their Economic Future: Some Implications of a Changing Industrial Environment"; Sessions: Problems of Regional Economic Development, Proceedings , American Economic Association, May, 1978, pp. 110-115. 52. Miernyk, W. H. , and Sears, J. T. ; "Environmental Management and Regional Economic Development"; Air Pollution Abatement and Regional Economic Development , Lexington Books, D. C. Heath and Company: Lexington, Massachusetts, 1974. D-180 INDEX (continued) 53. Moody, Carlisle E. , Jr. and Humphrey, Craig; "Air Quality, Environment and Metropolitan Community Structure"; The Review of Regional Studies , Volume III, Number 3, pp. 92-101, 1974. 54. Morgenstern, P. , et. al. ; "Modeling Analysis of Power Plants for Compliance Extensions in 41 Air Quality Control Regions"; Journal of the Air Pollution Control Association , Volume 25, Number 3, 1975, p. 287. 55. National Association of Manufacturers, The; "Statement on the Economic Impact of Environmental Regulations"; Hearings before the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, November 21-22, 1974. 56. National Canners Association, The (Roger Huibregtse); "Comments on the Economic Impact of Environmental Regulations"; Hearings before the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, November 21-22, 1974. 57. Neutze, G. M. ; "Major Determinant of Location Patterns"; Land Economics , Volume XLII*, Number 2, May, 1967. 58. Nevers, Noel de; "Air Pollution Control Philosophies"; Journal of the Air Pollution Control Association - Reprinted in the Senate Congressional Record, February 25, 1977. 59. Nijkamp, P. , and Paelinck, J. H. P. ; "An Interregional Model of Environmental Choice"; Papers of the Regional Science Associa- tion, Volume 31, 1973. 60. Ogden, Delbert C. ; "Economic Analysis of Air Pollution"; Land Economics, May 1966, p. 137. 61. Patrick, Clifford H. ; "Pollution, Production and Compensation"; The Review of Regional Studies , Volume 4, Supplement, 1974, pp. 60-66. 62. Petersen, John and Galper, Harvey; "Financing State Capital Outlays"; State Government, Spring Issue, 1970, pp. 124-127. b3. Petersen, John, and Kummerfeld, Donald; "Are Taxable Municipal Bonds in Your Future?"; Nation's Cities, Volume III, Number 7, July, 1973. D-181 INDEX (continued) 64. Peterson, E. W. ; "Interaction of Population Growth, Industrial Growth, and Pollution Control"; Journal of the Air Pollution Con - trol Association, Volume 23, Number 1, January 1973, p. 11. 65. Power Systems Division, United Technologies Corporation; "National Benefits Associated with Commercial Application of Fuel Cell Powerplants"; prepared for the Energy Research and Development Administration, February 27, 1976. 66. Putman, Stephen H. ; "Intra-Urban Industrial Location Model Design and Implementation"; Paper presented at the Thirteenth U.S. Annual Meeting, Regional Science Association, St. Louis, Missouri, 1966. 67. Revelle, Charles, et. al. ; "An Analysis of Private and Public Sector Location Models"; Management Science , Volume 16, Number 11, July 1970, pp. 692-707. 68. Rose, Adam; "A Simulation Model for the Economic Assessment of Alternative Air Pollution Regulations"; Journal of Regional Science, Volume 17, Number 3, 1977. 69. ; "A Dynamic Interindustry Model for the Economic Analysis of Pollution Abatement"; Working papers on the Use of Regional Science Techniques in Environmental Management; Regional Science Dissertation and Monograph Series #3, Center for Urban Development Research, Cornell University, June, 1974, pp. 47-64. 70. Schuler, Richard E. ; "Air Quality Improvement and Long-Run Urban Form"; The Regional Science Association Papers, Volume 32, 1974. 71. Segel, Frank W. , and Dunlap, Betsy; "Capital Expenditures by Business for Pollution Abatement: 1976 and Planned 1977"; Survey of Current Business , Volume 57, Number 6, 1977 (U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis), pp. 13-15. 72. Speer, Edgar B. ; "Industry in the Hot Seat"; Business and Society Review , Number 24, 1977-1978, pp. 22-24. 73. Summers, Gene, et. al. ; Industrial Invasion Q f Nonmetropolitan America; A Quarter Century of Experience; Praeger Publishers: New York, 1976. D-182 INDEX (continued) 74. Temple, Barker, and Sloane, Inc. ; "Analysis of Economic Effects of Environmental Regulations on the Integrated Iron and Steel Industry: Executive Summary"; Unpublished report prepared for the Environmental Protection Agency, July, 1977. 75. Toyne, Peter; Organisation Location and Behaviour; John Wiley and Sons: New York - Toronto, 1974. 76. Train, Russell E. ; "Prepared Statement on the Economic Impact of Environmental Regulations"; Hearings before the Joint Eco- nomic Committee, Congress of the United States, November 24, 1974. 77. Vaughan, Roger J. ; The Urban Impacts of Federal Policies: Volume 2, Economic Development ; Rand Corporation, R-2028- KF/RC; June 1977. ^8. Wagner, Aubrey J. ; "Prepared Statement on the Economic Impact of Environmental Regulations"; Hearings before the Joint Eco- nomic Committee, Congress of the United States, November 21, 1974. 79. Walter, G. R. ; "Intertemporally Optimal Urban Pollution"; The Regional Science Association Papers , Volume 28, 1971, pp. 237-254. 80. Webber, Michael John; Impact of Uncertainty on Location; The M. I. T. Press: Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1972, p. 310. 81. Weidenbaum, Murray L. ; "The Costs of Government Regulation of Business"; prepared for the use of the .Subcommittee on Eco- nomic Growth and Stabilization of the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, April, 1978. 82. Werczberger, Elia; "A Mixed-Integer Programming Model for the Integration of Air Quality Policy and Land Use Planning"; Papers of the Regional Science Association, Volume 23, 1974. 83. Wheat, Leonard F. ; Regional Growth and Industrial Location; Lexington Books: Lexington, Mass. , 1973. 84. ''Government Regulation, America's Number One Growth Industry"; Notes from the Joint Economic Committee, United States Congress, Volume IV, Number 11, May 16, 1978. D-183 INDEX (continued) 85. "Status Report: Other Environmental Impacts"; The Status of Environmental Economics: A Report prepared for the Committee on Public Works, United States Senate; June, 1975. 86. "U.S. Industry Needs $24.67 Billion to Bring Its Existing Facilities Into Compliance"; Journal of the Air Pollution Control Association ; Volume 24, Number 7, July 1974, p. 682. 87. Related Newspaper and Magazine Articles "Study Cites Firms' 'Flight' to 3rd World to Avoid Safeguards" Helen Dewar, The Washington Post, Friday, June 30, 1978. "U.S. Sets Rules on Pollution Controls"; Charles Mohr, The New York Times, Wednesday, June 21, 1978. "The Capital Eye"; Fred Popper, Practicing Planner , June, 1978. "Reserve Mining Company to Remain in Minnesota", The New York Times, Saturday, July 8, 1978. "The Regulation Mess"; Newsweek, June 12, 1978, David Pauly, et. al. "The Benefits of Regulation:; Economic Scene/Carolyn Shaw Bell, The New York Times , Tuesday, July 25, 1978. "Bottle Maker Cuts Costs, Pollution with Old Glass", Larry Kramer, The Washington Post , Sunday, July 2, 1978. "EPA Approves Auto Plants under Emission Offsets Policy" Environment Reporter - Current Developments , Volume 8, May 1, 1977 - April, 1978. ftU.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE: 1979 O — 296-189 PE n'ii S i T ^ r . E 1 . U . N i VERSITY L| Bf ARIES ADDDD70a7Sa7D