llllllIIllIIITlllliIIIIllllllllllllllllllllllllIlllllllllllllllllllIIIIIIllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllIlllllllllllIIIllllIIIllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllillllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllll! TEXAS AGRICULTURAL EXPERIMENT STATION AGRICULTURAL AND MECHANICAL COLLEGE OF TEXAS BULLETIN NO. 278 April 1921 FARM TENANTRY IN THE UNITED STATES BY WILLIAM BENNETT BIZZELL President of the Agricultural and Mechanical College of Texas. SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILMENT OF THE RE- QUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY IN THE FACULTY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE IN COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY. TITlllllllITIllllIllllllllHIIllllllllllIllIlllllllllIllllITIIIIIITIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIlllIIIIIIIIIlIIllllllllllIIIIIllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllIIIIIIIlllllilIIIIIIllIllIIlllllllllllllIll!IIlllllllIIllllllIIlllllllIllllllllllllllllllllllllllll "I IllIIllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllNllllllllllllllllllllllllIlllllllllllIllllllllIllllllllllllllllllllllillllllllllllllllllllllllllllllillllllllllllllllllllllIlllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllillllllllllllllllllllllllllllIlllll||l|IlllllllllllllllllllllIIIll!llllllllllllIllIllllllIIIIIIllllllllllllllilllllllllllllllllllIllllllIllIlllllllllllllllIllllIlllIliIlillllliIllllllIIllIlilllIIllllllllillillllllllllllll El [Blank Page in Original Bulletin] TABLE OF CONTENTS PARTI. The Historic and Economic Background of Farm Tenantry in the CHAPTER I. II. III. IV. V. VI. VII. VIII. United States. PAGE The Genesis of Farm Tenantry : : : : : 13 The Historical Background of Farm Tenantry in the United States : : : : : : : : 29 The Physiocratic Conception of Farm Tenantry : : 43 Adams Smith’s Views on Farm Tenantry : : : 50 The Views of the Early Classical Economists on Farm Ten- antry : : : : : : : : : : 58 John Stuart Mill’s Views on Farm Tenantry : : : 65 The Economics of Farm Rent : : : : : 80 Practical Aspects of Farm Rent : : : : : 95 PARTIL An Analysis of the Economic Aspects of Farm Tenantry in the IX. X. XI. XII. XIII. XIV. XV. XVI. XVII. United States. The Problem of Farm Tenantry in the United States The Increase and Distribution of Farm Tenants in the Ilnited 107 States : . . . . 117 The Farm Tenant’s Labor lnconwe : : : 128 The Influence of Land Values on Farm Tenantry : 146 The Influence of Crop Production on Farm Tenantry . 162 The Influence of the Size of Farms on Farm Tenantry : 175 The Lease Contract Between Landlord and Tenant ' 187 Social Justice in the Provisions of the Lease Contract : 197 Methods of Financing Tenant Farm Operations 211 PARTIH. An Analysis of the Social Aspects of Farm Tenantry in the XVIII. XIX. XX. XXI. XXII. XXIII. United States. Social Factors Contributing to Farm Tenantry 225 The Influence of Immigration on Farm Tenantry 238 The Negro Farm Tenant : : : : : 257 The Housing of Farm Tenants : : 273 The Intellectual Interests of Farm Tenants : 288 The Religious Interests of Farm Tenants : 298 PARTIV. Social and Economic Factors in the Solution of the Farm Tenan- XXIV. XXV. XXVI. XXVII. XXVIII. XXIX. XXX. try Problem in the United States. The Place of Tenantry in an Ideal System of Land Tenure 309 Land Nationalization and Farm Tenantry : : : 320 Taxation of Land Values as a Means of Promoting Farm Ownership : : : : : : : : : 337 Rural Credit as an Aid to the Tenant Farmer 352 Land Settlement Policies and Farm Tenantry : : 363 Other Land Reforms Relating to Farm Tenantry : 371 Summary and Conclusio : : : : ' 381 Bibliography : : : 394 Index : : : 405 DIRECTOR’S FOREWORD. This is the first publication of note, dealing with rural eco- nomic social problems, to be issued by this Station. The Director believes that the general Welfare of Texas is best conserved when the Work of the specialists in the physical and biological sciences is supplemented, and, in fact, properly guided, by research and instruction in the social sciences, includingagricultural econom- ics and rural sociology. He believes, further, that the people will be in better position to demand, and have enacted, suitable rural economic and social legislation, after they have arrived at an understanding of the nature and scope of these problems. In order, therefore, to better serve the agriculture of Texas as an industry, and the people as a Whole in their relations to rural problems, this Station is conducting fair and accurate scientific researches into the fields of farm and ranch economics and rural sociology, and is publishing its findings for the good of the people of the State. The Director takes pleasure in presenting “Land Tenantry,” which is the result of several years’ reflection and inquiry on the part of President W. B. Bizzell, as the type of information pre- requisite to an understanding and a solution of the tenant prob- lems of Texas. Signed, B. YOUNGBLOOD, Director. April 30, 1921. PREFACE. The problems of rural life are attracting increasing atten- tion. Opinions differ widely as to the causes and remedies for existing conditions in the open country. But the fact remains that all is not well with our basic industry and the living condi- tions of those identified with it. The census figures of 1920 show that for ,the first time in the history of this country the urban population now exceeds the rural population by approximately four million people. Just a century ago more than eighty-seven per cent. of the population of the Nation was classed as rura1.The continuous change in the ratio of rural to city dwellers is not without significance. For, after all, this situation implies a sim- ilar change in the ratio of production to consumption. After mak- ing due allowance for increase in man-power efficiency due to the use of labor-saving machinery and scientific methods of cultiva- tion, the fact remains that the present tendency in the shift of the population from agriculture to commerce and industry must eventually result in under-production of agricultural products. The equilibrium between population elements and resources has not been reached in this country. We are in the midst of a period of transition. The evidence of this is to be found in the rapidly increasing prices of agricultural and grazing lands and a corresponding increase in farm tenantry. Press summaries of census figures for 1920 show that tenantry continues to increase in many agricultural section of the country. Typical agricul- tural counties in the South and West show abnormal increases in farm tenantry in recent years. The Fourteenth Census also shows that the total number of farms in the United States only increased 88,496 or 1.4% during the period from 1910 to 1920. Twenty-five, or more than one-half the total number of states, actually have now fewer farms than were reported in 1910. This fact may be accounted for in two ways. It may indicate that the high price of land has resulted in the consolidation of farm areas under capitalistic management where cultivation is in the hands of tenants or laborers; or, it may indicate that the number and area of abandoned farms have increased within the ten-year period. There is reason to believe that both factors enter into the explanation. It is also obvious that extensive rather than 7 8 Farm Tenantry in the Zlnited States. intensive methods of cultivation are still the prevailing system of cultivation. The forces tending to establish equilibrium between vocational groups and resources cannot be properly adjusted until the full effect of intensive cultivation has been experienced. Considerable diversity of views exists with reference to the significance of all these influences. For example, a writer in a recent issue of a widely read agricultural paper contends that farm tenantry in thiscountry is perfectly normal and that the absentee landl.ord is a very much abused person. On the other hand, many students of rural economic and social problems con- tend that there is no place for farm tenantry in a sound system of rural economy. The Writer finds it impossible to agree with either view. That many farm tenants are thrifty and successful farmers, and that many landlords are just and considerate of the welfare of their tenants is well known to the writer. But it is believed that the prevailing system of farm tenantry as prac- ticed in this country does not contribute, on the whole, to an efficient system of production or wholesome and normal living in the open country. But it is the deliberate conclusion of the Writer that there is a place for farm tenantry in our land tenure policy. However, much needs to be done to make farm tenantry a normal process of production and to secure to the tenant farmer reasonable assurance that he may expect to acquire a farm home after a few years of conscientious effort. ‘ It should be explained that considerable time has elapsed between the writing of the first and last chapters of this book. The fact is, the world war has intervened. Prices of agricul- tural commodities and likewise agricultural incomes were greatly disturbed by war conditions. Therefore, it has not been deemed advisable to rely upon abnormal prices and correspondingly high agricultural incomes as a basis for conclusions. It is believed that the statistical data collected before the war are more re- liable than that of the war period. The material for this volume has been drawn from many sources. Questionnaires have been sent out and data have been collected from many sections of the country. Many letters have been written and received from specialists in the field of rural economics and sociology. Farm demonstration agents through- out the country have cheerfully supplied much first-hand infor- Preface 9 mation. Rural surveys, farm management studies, first-hand investigations and unpublished reports made by my own asso- ciates who have kindly made their material accessible to me, and all available books and official reports have been fully drawn up- on for authoritative information. While assuming all responsibility for errors of judgment or other mistakes, the author wishes to acknowledge his sincere ap- preciation to everyone Who has in any Way assisted in the prepar- ation of this volume. W. B. B. College Station, Texas, May 1, 1921. [Blank Page in Original Bulletin] % :7 The Historic 3ndQEcdnomic Ba¢ikgP01:1I!*$1_ ; Tenantry in‘ j ~ V ' v',¢1~-_S,tates, i“ A ‘ ' CHAPTER I. THE GENESIS OF FARM TENANTRY. Those who seek a solution of the agricultural problems of to- day will often find it profitable to review the historical back- ground and the social development out of which these problems arose. The nearer the student can approach to the sources of those conditions out of which our agrarian problems have arisen and the more systematically he can trace the steps in the tran- sitional stages, the safer will be his conclusions and the surer will be his deductions. The farm tenantry problem in the United States is no exception to this rule, for it had its source in the so- cial structure that developed in Western Europe during the Mid- dle Ages. In its fragmentary beginnings it might be traced to sources even more remote} The history of rural life may be said to have begun with the conflict of two elements of society——those who possess power through the control of the land and those who were controlled as a result of this power. The struggle between these groups began in very early times, and in one form or another it has persisted until the present. Sometimes the struggle has assumed the form of conflict and violence, at others it has been characterized by the smouldering discontent that grows out of the conscious- ness of social inequalities and unequal opportunities. The peas- ants revolt in England against the land-owning class during the fourteenth century, is one of several illustrations of the more vi- olent expressions that have resulted from unsatisfactory rural conditions. While this is an exceptional manifestation, the struggle has gone on between land owners and farm tenants with varying degrees of intensity throughout the history of Western Europe. More than one political upheaval can be traced to the discontent of farm laborers and tenants and the unequal burdens that have been placed upon them. Genesis Traceable to Feudal Organization. For all practical purposes, we may seek the source of farm tenantry in the feudal organization. Farm tenantry is essen- lFor example, in The Code of Hammurabi (Khammurabi), the oldest code of laws now in existence, ante-dating both the laws of Moses and Manu, several sections are given to defining the relative shares of produce, under different conditions, that are to be ap- propriated by the owner of land and the cultivator. 13 .14 l Farm Tenantry in the United States tiallg a feudal product. The student of sociology finds many feudal survivals in the present-day social organization. Farm tenantry is one of the most obvious of these. The organization of the manorial estate during the period immediately following the death of Charlemagne,gives us a picture of farm tenantry in evo- lution} The origin, antiquity, and extent of manors previous to the Norman Conquest is an unsettled question of history. See- bohmz traces the origin of the feudal manor to the Roman villa. There was undoubtedly some similarity in the organization of the manor and the Roman villa. But a study of the descriptions of the Roman villa in the works of Cato3 and Varrot does not reveal the complexity of rural society or the existence of the same form of organization as that found in the descriptions of the man- orial estates of the Middle Ages?’ There is nothing to indicate anything analogous to our farm tenantry situation in the Roman villa. Prothero explainsthe organization of a manor as follows: “The land comprised in a thirteenth century manor was generally divided into four main portions, and, speaking generally, was cultivated on cooperative prin- ciples; the demesne of ‘Board’ land, reserved for the lord’s personal use, surrounding the manor house, and forming the smaller portion of the whole; the free land, occupied by the freemen holding by military service, or by some form of fixed rent in money or in kind; the un- free land, occupied by various classes of bondmen, hold- ing by produce-rents and labor services, which varied with the custom of the manor; the common pastures and untilled wastes on which the tenants of the manor and the occupiers of certain cottages, in virtue of their holdings, fed their livestock. The right of pasture must be clearly distinguished from those rights, which, at certain seasons of the year, were exercised by the asso- ciated partners over the cultivated arable and meadow lands of the village farm. Thus the lord’s demesne, using the word in its narrower sense, might be kept in hand, or let on lease to free or unfree tenants, or thrown into the village farm, or dealt with as to portions in each of these three ways. But Whether the land was treated as a compact whole, like a modern home-farm, or whether the landlord, as a shareholder in the village 1Ernerton‘s Mediaeval Europe, page 480. 2The English Village Community, Chapter 8. 3de Agricultura 4Rerum Rusticarum Libri Tres. 5Compare Roman Farm Management by A Virginia Farmer, Book III, Chapter 11, p. 273, with Protherds English Farming—Past and Present, Chapter 1- The Genesis of Farm Tenantry 15 association, allowed it to be cut up into strips and inter- mixed with other holdings, the demesne was mainly cul- tivated by the labor services of the unfree peasantry. The rest of the land of the manor, forming the larger portion of the cultivated area, was farmed by village partners, whose rent chiefly consisted in the labour, more or less definite in amount, which they were obliged to perform on the lord’s demesne. “In this method of cultivating a manorial estate, there are many contrasts with the modern system. The three-fold division of the agricultural interests into land- lord, tenant farmer, and wage-earner labourer was prac- tically unknown?“ . Labor Elements on the Manorial Estate. Prothero’s description of the manorial organization may be regarded as typical. The chief economic features of every manor were essentially alike. The gradual transformation that took place through successive centuries that resulted in the emer- gence of a farm tenantry class, in the modern conception of the term, is one of the most interesting developments in economic history. A brief description of the labor elements on a manor- ial estate will be given before tracing the influences that re- sulted in the disintegration of the manorial organization and the appearance of the modern type of farm organization. The land of a manor was cultivated by two general classes of tenants: (1) free tenants, (2) villein tenants. Seebohm makes the interesting observation that “in the Domesday Survey for the greater part of England there is no mention of free ten- ants, whether ‘liberi homines’ or ‘libere tenentesl” But he calls attention to the fact that “throughout those counties of England most completely under Danish influence there were plenty of liberi homines and of the allied class of sochmasoni, but nowhere else.” It would appear, therefore, that in those sec- tions of England far removed from Danish or Norman influences, the demesne lands were not let out previously to the Domes- day Survey to permanent free-holding tenants. The three classes of tenants in villenage actually mentioned in the Survey are: (1) Villani, (2) bordarrifi and (3) 10p. Cit, page 7. See also Ashley's History and Theory, Vol. 1, Chapter 1. ‘ZThis word is probably derived from the Saxon "Board”, meaning a cottage. The term is not very common in the literature of the period, but it does appear occasionaly in the ‘Liber Niger’ of Peterborough Abbey. 16 Farm Tenantry in the United States servi.‘ _ The Servi comprised a relatively small portion of the Whole population of England (approximately 9 per cent.) and were most numerous in the southwest of England. They were less numerous in the Danish sections and were absent alto- gether injYorkshire, Lincolnshire, and bordering districts. They could hardly be classed as tenants in villenage as they seemed to have held no land. The real tenants in villenage were confined almost ex- clusively to the two other classes, viz: the villani and the bor- darii or cottagers. The latter were rather uniformly scattered over the whole country. These cottiers, as a rule, possessed no oxen, and for this reason they were usually allotted relatively small acreage in the open fields. They, therefore, occupied a po- sition inferior to that of the villani proper. The villani at the date of the survey were the most important and typical tenants in villenage. They were also more numerous at that date than the cottiers. They embraced 38 per cent. of the population, while the cottiers numbered only about 32 per cent? The land holdings of the villani consisted of hides (120 to 240 acres), half-hides, or virgates (20 to 40 acres), and bovates (10 to 20 acres), allotted on the basis of the number of oxen that were available for plowing on the demesne land of the lord. The normal holiiing was the virgate, comprising on the average about 3O acres, in scattered acre or half-acre strips. These holdings of the villani were transferifecl loy the lord from one generation of serfsvto another in unbroken regularity to a single successor, which was either the oldest or the young- est son according to the prevailing custom on each manor. “They possessed all the unity and individuality of an entailed estate, and were sometimes known apparently for generations by the family name of holders.“ But the reason for this custom was not the preservation of family integrity, but of the ser- vices due the lord of the manor for the use of the land. The sources of the several classes and their social trans- formation are difficult to trace and to analyze. It is still a ques- 1Seebohm, Op. Cit" Chapter 3, page 89. 2Ibid, Chapter 3, page 90. 3Ibid, Chapter 2, page 77. The Genesis of Fair/m Tenant/m; 17 tion of dispute Whether the early social history of England be- gan with the population of freemen or a population of serfs} Seebohm maintains that the English manor had its origin in servitude and that the mass of the people had slowly passed from servile conditions through serfdom into freedom. Perhaps this is the most satisfactory explanation of this intricate problem. At any rate, it is aside from the purpose of this discussion to re- view the argument pro and con with reference to the origin of the manor. Besides, the literature relating to both sides of the controversy is available to anyone who wishes to pursue this question further. Assuming the correctness of Seebohm’s theory, his ex- planation of the sources of the elements in the manorial organi- zation is rather satisfactory. “The community in serfdom on a lord’s estate was both by Saxon and Continental usage recruited from above and below.” Freemen, by voluntary agreement with the lord, could become serfs and receive the lord’s protec- tion. On the other hand, by the donation of oxen to a slave by the lord, which enabled the slave to have a part in the plowing, he could rise out of slavery into serfdom. This dual process seems to have been going on continuously. It offers, at least, a partial explanation of the grades of serfdom. However, the sources seem to indicate that a distinction was made between the man who voluntarily became the holder of a yard-land by. his own surrender or by willing submission to semi-servile ten- ure, and the man who rose to the class of serfdom from the status of slavery. Different processes, however, tended to simplify greatly the manorial organization by actually reducing the number of classes on manorial estates. Ashley says, “When we com- pare the comparative simplicity of Domesday Book, in which, over the greater part of England, villeins, cotters or bordars, and slaves make up the whole of the population, with the elabor- ate division into six, eight or even ten classes in the custumals of the later part of the thirteenth century, the changes seem bewildering in their complexity and variety. But it will be found that most of them may be grouped under four heads: (1) the 1See the writing of Mitchell Kemble, George von Maurer, George Hanssen, Nasse, Vino- gradoif and Sir Henry Maine, especially his Village Communities in the East and West (3rd edition, 1876), for discussions of the theory of the free village community. The opposing view is well illustrated in the writings of Seebohm. 20p. Cit, Chapter 10, page 405. 18 Farm Tenantry in the United States growth of a large class of free tenants; (2) the commutation of the Week-Work for pecuniary payments; (3) the commutation of the boon-days and other special services; and (4) the appearance of a class of men dependent wholly or in part on' the Wages they received for agricultural labour.“ It seems desirable at this point to discuss the nature of ser- vices and rentals that the several classes on the manorial estates were required to render or to pay before proceeding with the discussion of the influences that transformed these several classes into farm tenants of the modern type. The Manorial Services and Rentals. The nature of the land rental Went through an evolution on the manorial estates by virtue of changing social, economic, and political conditions. The relationship of lord and oassal origi- nated in this unstable condition of society. An organization had to be devised that possessed sufficient strength to preserve life and give security to property. In the beginning the vassal was expected to fight for his lord when necessity required. The vas- sal also needed protection. Out of the mutual necessities of the situation came the cohesiveness that made the system secure. But as society became more stable the rental for land assumed a new form. Thatcher and Schwill make the following comment on this point: “The rents due from the vassal were of various kinds. Generally a certain sum was due for the land, another for the house, sometimes another for the fire (chimney), and ordinarily a small tax for each head of stock (cattle, sheep, hogs, etc.). Of course the lord received a certain share of all that was produced on the soil, of the Wheat, hay, wine, chickens, stock, honey, beeswax, and in fact, of everything. A charge was also made for the privilege of pasturing the stock in the for- ests or fields of the lord, for obtaining firewood from his forests, and for fishing in the streams which were regarded as his property. The peasants were forbid- den to sell their grain for a certain length of time af- ter the harvest, or their wine after the vintage, in order that the lord might have a temporary monopoly in these articles. They were compelled to bake their lAn Introduction to English Economic History and Theory, Volume I, Chapter 1, page 20 ' The Genesis of Farm Tenantry 19 bread in his oven, grind their corn at his mill, and press their grapes in his Winepress, for all of which a suit- able toll in kind was charged. The lord could also » seize the grain, Wine and other produce of his tenant, paying him what he chose, either in cash or at the end of a certain time, The tenant was required to labor also for his 10rd a certain number of days in the year. He must till his fields, care for his crops, make his wine, furnish horses and Wagons on demand, haul his Wood for the fires in the house, stones for building purposes, keep his castle and other buildings in repair, build de- fences, repair the roads and bridges, and render a multitude of other services.“ Montague Fordham classifies services and rentals under the manorial system as follows: “For their holdings the peasants, whether free or bond, rendered various agricultural services or rents. These services and rents fall under three main head- ings: (1) Week-work, an obligation which compelled the peasant to Work a certain number of days per Week on the lord’s land. (2) Boon-work, which com- pelled him to undertake special work, as, for example, carting corn to market for the lord. (3) ‘Gafol’ a trib- ute in cash or kind, such as a hearth penny per year, or a dozen eggs at Easter, or corn or honey, or young stock, fish or fowls. Bondsmen had also sometimes to pay, in addition, taxes at the lord’s direction.” The nature of the services and payments that were required by the lord is of great significance ‘as indicating the relative freedom of those who rendered the service or made the pay- ment. The boon-work, for example, was a more restricted ser- vice than week-work, and indicated a relatively greater degree of freedom. The payments in money or kind, to which the word “gafol” was applied, indicates not only a different method of payment but a larger degree of independence. The fact that these distinct services and payments are clearly differentiated on the manor in the early Saxon period, gives great Weight to the theory of Seebohm and others that free village communities, similar to the German “Mark”, did not exist in England. 1_General History of Europe, page 114. 2A Short History of English Rural Life, Chapter 3, page 43. Cp. Seeb0hm’s: The English Village Community, Chapter 2, pages 58, 59, 60, 67, 78 and '79. 20 Farm Tenomtry in the United States The transition implied by these changes in manorial prac- tice marks tlie course of social development during the Middle Ages. The manorial system organized human labor by “using the working man (1) as a chattel at will, (2) as a subordinate whose duties are fixed by custom, (3) as a free agent bound by contract. These landmarks probably indicate molecular changes in the structure of society scarcely less important than those political and intellectual revolutions which are usually taken as the turning points of ancient medieval, and modern his- tory.”1 It is this thought that causes Vinogradoif to say in an- other connection that “one of the greatest movements in the so- cial life of the thirteenth and fourteenth centuries is the move- ment towards the commutation of services for money rent.“ It is the opinion of Professor Ashley that the practice of commutation began before the Conquestfi but the process was greatly accelerated after this event as a result of the greater security, cheaper labor, and increasing population which the Norman rule brought to England. “Hired troups took the place of feudal levies,” says Vinogradoff, “kings easily renounced the mil- itary service of their tenants and took scutages which gave them the means of keeping submissive and well-drilled soldiers. The same process took place all through the country on the land of secular and ecclesiastical lords. They all preferred taking money which is so readily spent and so easy to keep, which may trans- form itself equally well into gorgeous pageants and into capital for carrying on work, instead of exacting old-fashioned unwieldy ploughings and reapings or equally clumsy rents in kind.“ The peasants were glad to be relieved of the customary ser- vices. The old system necessarily involved many annoying ex- actions and inconveniences. The change in policy gave to the peasants greater personal freedom and economic advantage. The transformation, therefore, was mutually satisfactory. But we must not confuse this system of commutation with economic rent of a later period. The basis of payment Was radi- cally different. In the eleventh and twelfth centuries, the pay- ments depended upon the relation in which the occupier stood to IVinogradofFs Villainage in England, Chapter 1, page 43. 20p. Cit, Chapter 6, page 179. 30p. Cit, Part 1, Chapter 1, page 22. 40p. Cit, Chapter 6, page 181. The Genesis of Farm Tenantry . 21 his lord. These occupiers were not tenants in the modern sense of the word. They were, in reality, land owners and their hold- ings descended to their children. But ownership did not carry with it the right to dispose of their holdings or to move at will from the manorial estate. It is easy to see that this is a radically different thing from the system of tenant farming as we know it today. Payment in kind or money instead of services did not transform the practice on the manorial estate into economic rent as interpreted by our modern economists. Transition from Status to Contract. The transition from status to contract, from commutation of labor service for money payments to the modern system of rent- ing land, has been the direct result of famine and pestilence and other influences that disturbed the farm labor situation. Fam- ine resulted from the bad harvest of 1314. This was followed by . the Black Death that swept over Europe from the East from 1348 to 1350. These influences produced rapid disorganization on the manorial estates. The old feudal system, which was or- ganized on the basis of status and sanctioned by tradition, rap- idly gained fluidity through increased freedom of movement. As a result, farm labor competition developed and free contractual rights began to appear. It was at this stage and under these conditions that leases were provided as a method of establishing contractual relations between landlord and tenant. The number and variety of farm leases developed rapidly. “Leases that were first applied to the demesne”, says Johnson, “were subsequently extended to the _ lands on the common field. These leases wereusually those known by the name of ‘stock and land lease’, a system under which the landlord supplied the implements and the stock as well as the land, the tenant paying a certain share of the produce in return.“ In these particulars this type of lease was similar to those we often see today. But there were important differences be- tween the leases of that period and those used at the present time. For example, the duration of the lease was in marked con- trast to modern practices. They were sometimes drawn for a 1The Disappearance of the Small Land Owner, Ford Lectures, 1909, page 19. 22 Farm Tenantry "in the United States fixed number of years, sometimes for life, sometimes for a suc- cession of lives, and sometimes at will. In this respect all types of leases were superior to the short term lease that is almost uni- versally used in this country, with the possible exception of the lease at will, which sometimes resulted in hardships to the ten- ant when the lease was held by an unscrupulous and selfish landlord. The fourteenth century was characterized in England by much disorder and rapid change. All of these changes produced more or less effect on rural conditions. The gradual develop- ment of sheep farming modified the economics of agriculture. The system and policy of enclosures had its beginning in this situation. Larger acreage could now be cultivated profitably with fewer tenants and farm laborers. The relation between landlords and tenants -was greatly modified by this system. The hardships that were experienced by the changes in economic conditions resulted in the rapid development of self- consciousness in the minds of the tenant class. The number of social reformers multiplied rapidly and their influence began to be felt. Notable among these in the latter half of the four- teenth century was John Ball. He was a priest who raised his voice in the interest of the landless man. His social agitations began immediately after the great plague. An oft quoted sen- tence illustrates the burden of his message: “They (the lords) have pleasure and fine houses; We (the peasants) have pain and labor, the wind and rain in the fields; and yet it is of us and our toil that these men hold their state.” He thought that the fruits of labor belonged to the pro- ducers and should go to them rather than to the lords whose control of manorial estates he would have destroyed. Perhaps the voice of this man was the first to be raised in the interest of agrarian socialism. This doctrine was preached through the south of England as opportunity presented on the country side and by the roadside to eagerly listening peasants, who were keenly sensative to the hardships and inequalities that existed at the time. Another voice that was raised in the interest of this class was William Langland, a popular poet of his day, who voiced The Genesis of Farm Tenantry 23 the feeling of the peasant for social justice in lines that have been frequently quoted: “O’er tax thou no tenant, save truth will assent! And though thou amerce them let mercy be taxer!” The peasant’s revolt in 1381 was the result of rural social and economic inequalities and the privations that they produced. This revolt resulted in setting aside old customs that had prevail- ed through generations and the establishment of a better econom- ic system. The practice came into general use of permitting the peasant to pay a definite money rent for his land. It should be clearly understood that the peasants had not assumed the posi- tion of modern lease-hold tenants.‘ The rents paid did not repre- sent the economic value of the land, or attempt to approximate it. The money rent was based on the approximate value of old compulsory services or obligations which sustained the ideals of the social feudal order. Previously to the beginning of the fif- teenth century there Were many contrasts between rural organ- ization on a manorial estate and the modern system. In the earlier stages of development of the manorial estate, the land owners and tenant laborers possessed the land and lived on the land. Their interests were common interests. Their points of view were not very dissimilar. But in the evolution of the system two tendencies developed. (1) The laborer’s tenure of the land was gradually relaxed. (2) The tenant farmer emerged between the landlord and the agrarian laborer. It is not until about the beginning of the fifteenth century that we begin to see in Eng- land the three-fold organization of agricultural interests into landlord, tenant, and farm laborer as we know them today. It is Well to keep in mind that when we speak of tenants as a factor in this old manorial system, we are speaking of a different eco- nomic unit from that which we know today. The Effect of Enclosures on the Tenant Farmer. The status of the tenant farmer from the fifteenth to the nineteenth century in England is largely determined by the in- fiuences of the system of enclosures to which reference has been made. Changes in agricultural production, especially that of sheep raising, and industrial development were responsible for 24 Farm Tenantry in the United States this policy. The system of enclosures is described by Montague Fordham as follows: “As used in rural history the word ‘enclosure’ indicates the enclosing of the land within new pas- tures, when any part of an estate is converted from property subject to common control or common use to private ownership; it contains two items: the fencing in of the land and the withdrawing of it from common use.”1 If the contemporary literature and legislation can be relied upon to indicate the rural situation subsequent to the middle of the fifteenth century, we are compelled to conclude that the ef- fects of the enclosures resulted in social dislocation and serious distress to the rural classes. ' The enclosures of this period were for the most part that of the common open field and not of the waste or commons, and the land so enclosed was used for sheep pastures rather than for a tillable purposes. This is the policy that received most of the de- nunciation of the contemporary writers and social reformers. “Surely,” says Sir Thomas Moore, “they may make men as soon v believe that there is no sun in the firmament as that . decay of tillage will not follow enclosure in our inland countries.” In the Utopia Moore says: “Therefore, that one covetous and insatiable cor- morant may compass about and enclose many thou- sand acres of ground together with one pale or hedge, the husbandmen be thrust out of their own, or by vio- lent oppression they be put beside it, or by covin and fraud they be so wearied that they be compelled to sell all by one means, therefore, or another, either by hook or crook, they must needs depart away, poor, silly, wretched souls, men, women, husbands, wives, father- less children, widows, woeful mothers with their young babies, and their whole household, small in substance and much in number, as husbandry requireth many hands . . . ' . and when they have wandered about till that (the little they have got by sale of their goods) be spent, what can they then else do but steal, 10p. Cit., page 67. 2Sc1-ipture Words Against Enclosure, page 6. The Genesis of Farm Tenantry 25 and then, justly, pardy, be hanged or go about beg- ging.”1 Latimer denounced the policy of enclosures in one of his sermons as follows: “Where there were once a great many house- holders and inhabitants there is now but a shepherd and his dog.” The literature of the period is full of passages expressing similar protests against the evils produced by this policy. As the number and extent of the enclosures continued, the smaller owners were gradually reduced to tenants, and the tenants were often dispossesssed of the lands they cultivated. It is easy to imagine the grave consequences that resulted from such a radi- cal reorganization of rural economy. It is not surprising that protest after protest is heard from ministers and social reform- ers of the day. The nature of the grievances caused by the policy of en- closures is carefully summarized by Mr. Arthus H. Johnson as follows : “To appreciate the nature of the grievances caused by this process of enclosure, we must clearly grasp the character of the offenses complained of. And here let it once more be noted that we are dealing chiefly with the commonable or open field, not with the enclosure of the waste or common. “The offences then were (1) engrossing or ac- quiring difierent holdings not necessarily contiguous or in the same manor; (2) consolidating, that is joining two or more holdings or strips on the common field; (3) decaying houses, which would be natural of con- solidating, and also might be done with regard to cot- tagers’ houses who had no land on the open field, and only a small plot, if any, on the demesne and some right of pasture on the waste; (4) putting down ploughs; (5) converting areable land to pasture; (6) emparking for purposes of keeping deer or warrens of conies, and ! 713 such ‘vaine commodities . 1Robins0n’s Translation, page 41. ZSermon VII, page 101. It is interesting to observe that a similar protest was raised centuries before by the prophet Isaiah in the following language: “Woe unto them that join house to house, that annex field to field, and ye are left to dwell alone in the midst of the 1and." Isa. 5, 8. See the writer's Social Teachings of the Jewish Prophets, Chapter 7, page 91. a 30p. Cit., page 54. 26 Farm Tenantry in the United States While the evil effects of the system of enclosure were very obviously harmful to a class of agricultural workers, it should be observed in passing that the policy marked a necessary transi- tion in the agricultural development of England. It was in- evitable that the old manorial system should break down under the weight of the industrial and economic conditions that were beginning to appear in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. Enclosures were the means adopted of advancing from primitive to a more scientific and profitable system of agriculture. The enclosing of the strips on the common field ultimately broke up the manorial economy, which had become a handicap to agricul- tural production. Consolidation resulted in more systematic pro- duction and more diversified farming. Hasbach, however, con- tends that the real motive for enclosure was not the desire to in- crease production, but that it was fostered for purely financial rea- sons} By enclosing the waste and renting the land, the income to the landlord would be substantially increased. By consoli- dating the farms after enclosure, it was found less expensive to collect rents from a few large tenants than from many smaller ones. There can be no doubt that economic considerations were the predominating motives in the policy relating to enclosures. But the effects were beneficial in increasing production. Arthur Young in his Northern Tom", advised the landlords to increase rents as a means of stimulating tenants to greater endeavor. “If you would have vigorous culture, throw fifteen or twenty (small) farms into one as soon as the present occupiers die off.” This was characteristic of much of the rural economic reasoning in the lat- ter part of the eighteenth century. J ustification for higher rents and larger acreage to a single renter was urged on the ground that it would stimulate the tenant to increase his skill and energies as a means of meeting his obligations, which, indirectly, resulted in increased production. It is not without significance that the same argument is used in the present day in j ustification of pre- vailing rents of land on American improved farms. By 1820 the processes of enclosure had become so general that rural England had become a country of landlords who owned the land and the tenant farmers who cultivated it. Here and there lDie Englishen Laxndarbeiter, page 39. ZNm-thern Tour. Vol 2, page 84. It is interesting to contrast the views of Young with those of William Cobbett in his Rural Rides (1825-1832) who severely condemns the landowner for rural life conditions. He bitterly declares that “the baseness of the Engiish land-owner surpasses that of any other men that ever lived in the world. The Genesis of Form Tencmtry ’ 27 an old manorial estate persisted under its primitive organization, but these estates had ceased to be typical in any part of England. Generally, the rural population adjusted themselves to the new order of things. The new system was accomplished by the grad- ual adoption of a farm lease that prescribed a fixed rental for the land and outlined the conditions under which the land was to be cultivated. The subsequent history of farm tenantry in England has been merely a variation in rent prices and conditions of cul- tivation. Important adjustments have been made from time to time between landlords and tenants, but in recent times England has been remarkably free from serious conflicts of interests be- tween the two classes. “Farmers and landlords,” says Fordham, “the modern representatives of the two classes that were almost at war in the fourteenth century, generally stand together in the nineteenth?“ The Agricultural Holdings Act. But inequalities between landlord and tenant have persisted down to the present day Fortunately, England has appreciated the importance of adjusting the relationship between landlord and tenant as a means of maintaining agricultural production. The nation has realized that the landless class was at a disad- vantage in negotiating with the landlord on the basis of free com- petition. As early as 1875, parliament passed what has been known as the Agricultural Holdings Act, which marks an epoch in the history of rural economy. The original act proved to be ineffective, but it attempted to protect the interest of the tenant in certain improvements he had made on the land. The new act of 1908 is much more comprehensive and effective. The scope is indicated by J. T. Jackson, a barrister-at-law, in his volume on “The Agricultural Holdings Act”,2 as follows: 1. Compensation for: (a) Unexhausted improve- ments. (b) Unreasonable disturbance. (c) Damage ' by game. (d) In case of a tenancy under a mortgagor. 2. Fixtures and their removal. 3. Landlord’s remedies for breach of covenant, including the law of distress. 4. Determination ‘of tenancy by notice to quit. 5. Freedom of cropping and disposal of produce. 10p. Cit., page 135. 2 page 6. 28 Farm Tenantry in the United States 6. Miscellaneous matters: (a) Landlord’s right to view the holding. (b) Resuming possession of the whole. (c) Penal rents. (d) Record of the holding. (e) Market gardens. 7. Arbitration and the procedure in assessing compensation. Conclusion. The present organization of rural economy in England may be traced to the feudal system of the Middle Ages. Farm tenantry as practiced in England today is an evolution of the old manorial type of agriculture. Every nation has devised some system by which land ownership has been concentrated in the hands of the few. The process has advanced only a few steps when the power that ownership of land bestowed, enabled the landlords to secure the passage of legislation that made their titles secure and increased their opportunity for acquiring larger possessions. The feudal system was fostered with this end in _ view. Counter-legislati.on is the late fruit of a landlord system that has been secured through social pressure and wide-spread discontent caused by hardships and oppressions from those who control the land. The history of land tenure in many countries is largely an account of conflict of interests between the class that owns the land and the class that cultivates it. The history of English rural life gives us one of the best illustrations of this conflict -under varying conditions resulting from war, disease, famine, and political agitation. The English government in recent times has manifested a commendable attitude and intelligence toward this situation. Other countries can well afford to profit by English legislation that has been passed in the interest of the tenantry class as a means of giving it a better chance to negotiate on_ equal terms with those who own the land. An effort will be made in the follow- ing chapters to describe the means by which tenantry has develop- ed in the United States. The influence of rural conditions in Eng- land in the seventeenth century on American colonial policy will be traced for the purpose of indicating its influence on the early land policy of the United States. CHAPTER II. THE HISTORICAL BACKGROUND OF FARM TENANTRY IN THE UNITED STATES. English colonization in America began With the granting of the Royal Charter, April 10, 1606, to two English com- panies—the Plymouth and the London companies. Both grants bestowed rights to occupy and to settle the regions in- definitely known as Virginia. The first colony of emigrants, consisting of one hundred and twenty people, arrived at Ches- peak Bay. on May 3, 1607, and selected a location on the James River, which they called Jamestown. For the next half cen- tury (1603-1660), the English were very active in the estab- lishment and development of their colonial possessions in Amer- ica. The preceding chapter has briefly outlined some of the rural conditions in England during this period. The era of English colonial settlement in America was almost exactly con- temporaneous with the period from the accession of James I to the Restoration. The policy of inclosures had begun un- der the Tudor sovereigns in the fifteenth century. It had gone on with increasing rapidity to the time of Queen Elizabeth (1558-1603). When James I ascended the throne, the suffering and the discontent of the agricultural population of England were very general. But the policy of consolidating estates went on without interruption. Social pressure and financial need were the influences that compelled the small owners to sell their farms, and tenants were subjected to harder and less advantageous conditions. The period may be characterized by two tendencies: (1) In the first place, many of the poor- est and some of the middle class farmers were driven from the soil; (2) and in the second place, the land was rapidly chang-. ing hands under the impulse of more profitable farming meth- ods and the increase in the number of farm crops. But there began to appear certain tendencies in England at this period that were destined to have an influence both directly and indirectly on colonial life in America. The more prosperous merchants and successful professional men of the cities began to purchase land. “Competitive rents, competitive prices, competitive wages”, says Johnson, “were coming in, and the modern capitalist had already appeared; men who 29 30 Farm Tenantry in the United States treated land as an investment and agriculture as a source of profit. The English squire had taken the place of the medi- aeval baron. The successful manufacturer, merchant, and the lawyer were forcing their way into the land market and fast rising into the position of the squire. Hence an intense land hunger was a characteristic feature of the Tudor and early Stuart times.“ The effects of this movement on agriculture were incal- culable. Thought and initiative were brought to the aid of agricultural production. New crops were introduced, improved methods were applied, and improvement of agricultural implements was devised to make cultivation more effective and efficient. It was during these remarkable agarian changes that American colonization developed. The system of inclosures had dispossessed many tenants at a time when land-owner- ship was holding out its greatest promise to the rural popu- lation. The possibility of acquiring land almost for the ask- ing in a new country of boundless possibilities, was a compell- ing appeal to the landless class just at the time that English colonial policies were developing. “The desire to own land”, says Professor Bassett, “was the impelling consideration of most of the early migration to America.“ It was natural to expect that an attempt would be made to establish the manorial land system of England in the new country. History reveals the fact that the feudal plan of or- ganization was uppermost in the minds of the holders of col- onial grants. This plan was transplanted in Virginia, but it had to give way before the impelling force of the land-hungry immigrant. “Nothing short of actual ownership in the soil”, says Miss Coman, “suffered to attract and hold immigrants.” The London company in the beginning adopted the policy of retaining the ownership of the land and providing for its cul- tivation by farm laborers or tenants. Sir Thomas Dale, true to his feudal conceptions, assigned to each new-comer a three- acre garden lot and twelve acres of forest land. All the cul- tivators were mere tenants at will. The system aroused in- tense opposition. It became necessary to recall Governor lThe Disappearance of the Small Landowner, page 75. 2A Short History of the United States, Chapter '7, page 135. 3Industr1at History of the United States, Chapter 2, page 32. The Historical Background of Farm Tenantry 31 Dale and give to the colonists larger powers of control of their own affairs. It is not without significance that the first representative body that ever assembled upon the Western continent at- tempted to liberalize the land policy of the country by de- stroying its feudal characteristics and by establishing in its place an agrarian organization that would make home-owner- ship the basis of social organization. The House of Burgesses in its first session (1619) legalized the title to the lands oc- cupied and tilled by each colonist, and provided that each shareholder in the stock company be allotted one hund- red acres of land for each share he held in the company} Some of the stock holders under this provision of the statute came into possession of great tracts of land by virtue of the amount of stock held. John Martin and his associates, for example, acquired eighty thousand acres in this way? A unique method of acquiring additional land was through a system known as “head right.” Each shareholder who pro- vided funds for transporting an able bodied man or woman was awarded one hundred acres of land. This opportunity of increasing land possessions was soon extended to all resi- dents of the colony and soon became the usual method of ac- quiring land or increasing the acreage already possessed. The plan worked admirably for land was abundant and labor scarce. By the close of the seventeenth century, the size of a Virginia estate was approximately seven hundred acres, and the total area under cultivation was approximately equal to the total area of cultivated land in England?‘ Thus we see the beginning of a system of land tenure developing in the South that required a system of cultivation that would include the employment of farm laborers and some form of farm ten- antry. Land Policy of New England. The system of land tenure in New England was strikingly different from that of Virginia. There were several reasons for this. In the first place, the motive that led to the settle- ment of this section was essentially different from that of Vir- ginia. In the second place, the conditions o1 soil and climate lSee Coman’s Op. Cit. ' 2Bruce’s Economic History of Virginia, V01. 1, pages 502-506. 3Bruce’s Op. Cit., Vol. 1, page 519. 32 Farm Tenantry in the United States made a different policy necessary. Plymouth colony was a co-operative enterprise. Each member of the colony was credited with a share in the venture. Every man, woman, and child received a share of stock and twenty acres of land when the first distribution was made} The original colonists who settled in Salem received a house and lot, ten acres of farm land, the right of pasturage on the basis of the number of cat- tle possessed? The promoters of Massachusetts Bay colony adopted the Virginia principle of “head right.” The colonist was entitled to fifty acres for each person transported into the colony. However, this policy did not result in the building up of large estates as in Virginia. The reasons are obvious. Arable lands were limited. The severity of the climate as well as soil conditions did not encourage agriculture on a large scale. The Massachusetts Bay company extended its land policy to all the settlements made by it. But the size of allot- ments varied in the different towns, depending on local con- ditions and the number of proprietors who were to share in the land allotments. The Massachusetts plan spread to Rhode Island, Connecticut, and New Hampshire. This land policy resulted in New England’s becoming a land of small farmers where each possessed his land in fee simple and each farm was cultivated by its owner. The far-reaching effect of this sound beginning has largely eliminated the problem of farm ten- antry in this section of the country. Farm tenantry is not a serious problem in New England at the present day. New York, like Virginia, adopted the feudal system of land tenure in the beginning. The Dutch West Indian com- pany by a Charter of Privileges assigned great tracts of land to Dutch “patroons”. The “patroons” established a land system similar to the manorial system of Western Europe. Many of the great estates established by them were continued under English rule. Some of the royal governors bestowed tracts of thousands of acres upon favored friends or associates. “The manorial system, however, was restricted to the Valley of the Hudson,” says Professor Bogart, “and the large estates of from fifty thousand to even a million acres lay, in the large part, uncultivated until they were broken up into small hold- ings.”3 As in Virginia, serious protests were raised against fiiohris of Captain John Smith, pages 782-784, ZAdams’ Villa-ye Communities 0f Cape Ann and Salem, page 20. 3Economic History of the United States, Chapter 3, page 49. The Historical Background of Farm Tenantry 33 the system that had caused the colonists t0 leave their native country. One protest is expressed as follows: “The gran- tees themselves are not, nor never were in a capacity to im- prove such large tracts, and other people will not become their vassals or tenants, for one great reason for people (the better sort especially) leaving their native country, was to avoid the dependence of landlords, and to enjoy lands in fee to descend to their posterity that their children may reap the benefit of their labor and industry?“ The settling of the province was retarded by this system. “Immigrants deliberately chose New England instead of New York as a place of settlement where land might be acquired in fee simple and on terms of equality with their neighbors.” The effect of these influen- ces began to be felt in time. We are told by Weeden that “when by the treaty of Fort Stanwix (1766) the Mohawk Val- ley was purchased of the Iroquois Confederacy, land offices were opened and farms were made over in fee simple to actual settlers on the easy condition that five acres out of fifty should be cleared within three years? Both the royal and proprietary colonies possessed all the possibilities of an unendurable tenantry situation. This was particularly true of the proprietorship, which was the com- monest form of colonial grant. “The proprietorship”, says Muzzey, “was a sort of middle theory between the royal pro- vince and the self-governing colonies!“ The colonial pro- prietors, by the terms of their agents, held their respective pos- sessions as manorial estates. Their motives were economic gain resulting from commercial enterprise. Under the au- thority of their grants they could sell or lease land on such conditions as best suited their purpose. William Penn adopt- ed the policy of selling land for a reasonable sum in five-thous- and-acre tracts and reserving a quit-rent of one shilling per one hundred acres. He also offered bonuses for each servant and five hundred acres for each family transported and lo- cated on the land? These terms offered opportunities for the acquisition of large estates and opened the way for a system of land cultivation by peasants and farm tenants. The con- lDocumeritary History of New York, Vol. 1, page 377, ZWeederVs American Husbandry, Vol. 1, page 192, 3Weeden’s Op. Cit., Vol. 2, pages 15-17. 4American History, Chapter 2, page 53. 50sgood’s American Colonies, Vol. 2, Part 3, Chapter 2. 34 Farm Tenomtry in the United States ditions of soil and climate were not favorable to a feudal or- ganization of this kind in Pennsylvania. Here, as in New England, the necessities of the situation, resulted in a fee sim- ple ownership of small farms carved out of the large estates. The plan of land settlement in Pennsylvania was as follows: A group of settlers would buy jointly a large tract of land and then sub-divide it into small farms on a basis of mutual agree- ment. In this way there were established communities of _ English, Welch, and German farmers, each of whom became an actual owner of the farm he cultivated. The proprietors of East and West Jersey also resorted to a system of land bonuses as a means of attracting settlers. Every man who possessed a musket and supply of ammuni- tion and provisions sufficient to meet his needs for six months was given one hundred and fifty acres of land. For each wo- man seventy-five acres were allotted. One hundred and fifty acres were allotted for each servant or slave imported. The attractive- ness of this" offer drew settlers from the large estates of New York. “What man,” Wrote the Earl of Bellmont, “will be such a fool as to become a base tenant . . . . . when for crossing Hudson’s river that man can for a song purchase a good free hold in the Jerseys ?”1 The estates of New Jersey under this plan never became large. Ownership of small farms prevailed over large proprietary estates owned by landlords and cultivated by tenants As a general proposition the proprietorship of New York, Pennsylvania, and New Jersey failed to develop a feudal land system in this country. The conditions of soil and climate Were largely responsible for this failure. But in the South, where physical conditions were different, the feudal type met with better success. In Maryland, for example, where the same plan was followed in land allotments as that adopted by the proprietors to the North, exactly the opposite land tenure system developed. The bonus system gave to each proprietor who brought over a number of laborers a liberal donation of land. “The intention of the proprietors”, says Miss Coman, “was to create manors after the mediaeval type. Each ad- venturer sublet his lands to the man whom he brought over, and these, like feudal tenants, paid rent in money or produce and presented themselves at the call of the lord of the manor lDocumentary Colonial History of New York, Vol. 4, page 791. The Historical Background of Farm Tenantry 35 fully equipped with inuskets, powder and bullets for services against Indians. Sixty such manors of three thousand acres each were established by 167 6.”1 Maryland more completely re- produced the old manorial system of Western Europe than did any other American colony. The proprietors of Carolina (1668) and Georgia (17 32) adopted a different policy from that of Mary- land with reference to the system of land tenures. In both of these colonies an effort was made to prevent the development of manorial estates of a feudal type. The intention in each case was to parcel out the land to settlers in tracts commensurate with the settler’s ability to cultivate the land by his own efforts. But again soil and climate were controlling forces in the develop- ment of the land system. Experience soon taught the settler that there was economy in cultivation on a large scale. The vast tracts of fertile soil and the large yields of staple crops of cotton, Wheat, rice, and tobacco encouraged an organized system of pro- duction. The proprietors had to yield to local demands to apply the Virginia plan of larrd settlement. Land accession by “head right” made large estates easy to acquire. Two processes op- erated against the original plan,--the combination of small farms into larger estates, on the one hand, and on the other, the addition of contiguous land on the basis of the principle of “head right.”_ So we find that both royal and proprietary colonies south of the Mason and Dixon line alike ultimately came to the manorial system, even when established from different motives and orig- inally organized on a different basis. The problem of a farm labor supply was partially supplied by the admission of slaves, and gradually the landlord acquired vast estates of cultivated land operated by an overseer and cultivated by slaves and free farm laborers. Previously to the Civil War, the question of farm tenantry did not enter into the farm labor situation. But free- dom of the slaves left these estates dependent upon a new type of rural organization. Farm tenantry was the natural and log- ical method that Was to follow the passing of land cultivation by slaves. In passing it should be observed that the English law of primogeniture and the application of the principle of entail were adopted practically throughout the American colonies. This law was strictly followed in New York and the Southern Colonies 10p. Cit., Chapter 2, page 37. 36 Farm Tenantry in the United States in the interest of preserving the large estates, while in ‘New England the application of these laws was modified by local con- ditions} However, it should be observed that the law of primo- geniture was not the controlling factor in the preservation of the large estates. No doubt the laws of primogeniture and entail were established for the purpose of preserving the larger estates in England, but they have not been effective in accomplishing this purpose in this country. Economic and social conditions have played a larger part in determining agrarian organization than arbitrary laws of this character. Influence of the Revolution on Land Tenure. The colonial land policy as outlined continued with varying details in organization until the Revolution. It was natural to expect that the revolutionary spirit against England would pro- duce marked changes in the social structure of colonial organi- zation. We would naturally expect that the first attack would be made on the legalistic and political systems adopted on the basis of English custom. Therefore, we are not surprised that one of the effects of the Revolution was to sweep away all traces of a feudal land tenure based on the law of primogeniture? The new nation promptly took steps to validate property rights by declaring that the disposition of land up to that time would be recognized and laws were passed to that effect. The unapportioned land passed into the control of the national gov- ernment and constituted the vast public domain of the United States. The social consequences of this national policy have never been completely or adequately appraised by any American writer. Henry George has more nearly expressed the signif- icance of, the importance of our public lands and the consequence of our land policy than any other American writer. “This public domain,” he says, “has been the transmuting force which has turned the thriftless, unambitious European peasant into the self-reliant Western farmer; it has given a con- sciousness of freedom even to the dweller in crowded cities, and has been a well-spring of hope even to those who have never thought of taking refuge upon it. The child of the people, as gogardEconomic History of the United States, page 50. 2Bogard, Op. Cit., page 48; also Cyclopedia of American Agriculture, edited by L. H. Bailey. Vol. 4, page 17, article by J. L. Coulter on The Ownership of Land. The Historical Background of Farm Tenantry 37 he grows to manhood in Europe, finds all the best seats at the banquet of life marked ‘taken’, and must struggle with his fel- lows for the crumbs that fall, Without one chance in a thousand of forcing or sneaking his way to a seat. In the American, whatever his condition, there has always been the consciousness that the public domain lay behind him; and the knowledge of this fact, acting and reacting, has penetrated our whole national life, giving to it generosity and independence, elasticity and ambition. All that we are proud of in the American character; all that makes our conditions and institutions better than those of older countries, we may trace to the fact that land has been cheap in the United States, because new soil has been open to the emi- grant.“ The Land Policy of the United States. The land policy of the United States has presented one of the most complex problems connected with our national develop- ment. From the beginnning it has perplexed our statesmen and been responsible for many difficult problems of administration. Nationality was threatened in the very beginning by this prob- lem. Colonial charters had given seven of the states that composed the Union a claim upon Western lands. These were Massachu- setts, Connecticut, New York, North Carolina, South Carolina, and Georgia. The possibility that these states might be able to dominate the Union through the power of wealth that would be acquired through the vast landed areas caused some of the states to hesitate to enter the Union. Maryland, for example, declined to accept the Articles of Confederation unless these states would agree to relinquish their claim to these Western lands. Finally, these seven states agreed to surrender their claim to the land beyond the Alleghanies, and Maryland signed the agreement on March 1, 1781. By 1786 the legal transfer of all these claims of the states had been made and the policy agreed upon that as rapidly as this vast region was settled it would be divided into states and incorporated into the Union? The statesmen of the day began almost immediately after the formation of the Union to work out a land settlement policy. Ilirogress and Poverty, V01 2, page 388, edition of 1898, published by Doubleday and McClure Company. 2Bassett’s A Short History of the United States, Chapter 10, page 232. 38 Farm Tenantry in the United States Jefferson, when a member of Congress, was the chairman of a committee appointed to prepare such a plan. The report of this committee, known as the Ordinance of 1784, designated the num- ber of states to be formed from the regions west of the Alle- ghanies and outlined a system of laws for the government of these territories pending their admission into the Union. The Ordinance of 1787 modified the previous ordinance to some ex- tent, and Congress adopted it as a law that should be applied to the government of these territories. Previously to the adoption of the ordinance of 1787, Congress formulated a plan for the sale of the western lands. It provided that the territory should be laid out in townships six miles square consisting of thirty-six sections in a township. Each sixteenth section was reserved to the territory as a land en- dowment for the support of the public schools. The plan pre- sented many advantages, and it was generally followed in the West. Alexander Hamilton had an unusually clear conception of the proper use and settlement of our vast public domain. His plan was formulated in a public statement as follows: “In the formation of a plan for the disposition of the vacant lands of the United States there appear to be two leading objects of consideration: One, the facility of advantageous sales, according to the probable course of purchase; the other, the accommo- dation of individuals now inhabiting the western country, or who may hereafter emigrate thither, the former, as an operation of finance, claims pri- mary attention; the latter is important, as it relates to the satisfaction of the inhabitants of the western country. It is desirable, and does not appear im- practicable, to conciliate both. Purchasers may be contemplated in three classes: Moneyed individuals and companies who will buy to sell again; associa- tions of persons who intend to make settlements themselves; single persons or families now resident in the western country or who may emigrate thither hereafter. The two first will be frequently blended, and will always want considerable tracts. The last will generally purchase small quantities. Hence a plan for the sale of the western lands, while it may have due regard for the last, should be calculated The Historical Background of Farm Tenantry 39 to obtain all the advantages which may be derived from the two first classes.”1 The land policy of the American government was expressed in many congressional acts between 1785 and 1862. The states- men of the first two decades of our national history worked on the public lands “as an asset to be cashed at once for payment of current expenses of government and extinguishment of the national debt.” At the same time the problem of national fin- ance was paramount to all social considerations. The foreign debt, due to the war, was very large considering the national wealth of the country at the time, and this had been greatly in- creased by the Federal government assuming‘ the debts of the various states when the Union was formed. This situation caused Congress to overlook the necessity of providing proper safeguards in the sale of public lands in the interest of home ownership. The various acts of Congress clearly indicate that the main consideration was to secure as much available cash as possible to supply the needs resulting from government obliga- tions. The haste of Congress’ to dispose of land for cash led to its sale in large tracts. The ordinance of May 20, 1785, authorized the sale of Western lands consisting of as much as a whole town- ship of thirty-two sections of six hundred and forty acres each. The price was as low as one dollar per acre. A subsequent Act (May 18, 1796) increased the maximum price to two dollars and restricted the acreage to a maximum of eight sections of six hundred and forty acres each. Under the provisions of these Acts, one million four hundred and eighty four thousand and forty-seven acres of the public domain were sold, for which the government received $1,201,725.68? The public land policy was modified with the beginning of the nineteenth century. The preemption system, which gave preference in the sale of land to actual settlers and encouraged them by making sales at a minimum price, began with an act of Congress in 1801. Sixteen special acts relating to this policy were passed within the first forty years of the nineteenth cen- tury. In 1841 an act was passed which, with minor modifica- lQuoted by J. L. Coulter in Cyclopedia of American Agriculture, V01. 4, page 176. 2See Dewey's Financial History of the United States, pages 92-96. 3See Cylopedia of American Agriculture, Vol. 4, page 177, article by Coulter on Land O’Zl;1l€7‘8hl1) and Tenancy. 40 Farm Tena-ntry in the United States tions, continued in force until 1891. Under the provisions of this act settlers were permitted to take up as much as one hundred and sixty acres and not less than forty acres. Public sales of the land were not authorized until after settlers were given an op- portunity to make purchases. The law provided that the pur- chaser was required to reside on the tract, cultivate a certain part of it, and provide certain improvements in consideration of the preferential advantages in the way of choice selections. The act of 1841 Was the forerunner of the Homestead Act of 1862, which consumated the policy of public land for bona fide settlers. This act Was the result of the agitation of the Free-Soil Democrats, who declared “that the public lands of the United States belonged to the people and should not be sold to individ- uals, or granted to corporations, but should be held as a sacred trust for the benefit of the people and should be granted in lim- ited quantities free of cost to landless settlers.” This act Was more definite in provision than the previous acts relating to land settlement. The act enabled the landless man to acquire title to a quarter section of land on condition of his maintaining residence thereon continuously for a period of five years and cultivating and improving a portion of it. The Wisdom of this policy is self-evident to those who have studied the effects of our land policy. It was necessary for officials to think in terms of internal development before this policy could be formulated into law. None of the party platforms of the great political parties during the first half of the nineteenth century raised the issue of public lands for the landless man. The early political platform announcements relating to this subject turned on the importance of the sale of the land as a means of raising revenue for governmental purposes. But since the Civil War both of the great parties and some of the minor parties have adopted the principle that “the public domain should be held sacred to actual settlers.“ Similar language is used in other platforms of both the parties since that time. The Effect of Our Land Policy on Farm Tenantry. The student who has the patience to trace historically our colonial development and the land policy adopted by the Federal lSee the Liberal Republican Platform of 1872. The Historical Background 0f Farm Tenantry 41 government, is compelled to see that in certain sections of the country agrarian problems of great importance were certain to arise. In the beginning, the vast undeveloped regions seemed to offer the promise of landed possessions for all who wntald seek them. But for this very reason social and legislative policies were developed Without taking into account this aspect of our national life. The effect that these policies have produced is well summarized by Henry George, the ablest critic of our land policy. In an address delivered in 1871, he says: “The best com- mentary upon our national land policy is the fact . . . . that of the 447,000,000 acres disposed of by the government not 100, 000,000 acres have passed directly into the hands of cultivators. If we add to this amount the lands which have been granted, but not delivered, we have an aggregate of 650,000,000 acres dis- posed of, to but 100,000,000 acres directly to cultivators—that is to say, six-tenths of the land has been put into the hands of peo- ple who do not want to use it themselves, but to make a profit, (that is, to exact a tax) from those who desire to use it.”1 As we naturally expect, Henry George explains the failure of the policy of preemption and homestead laws on the grounds of our defective revenue system. “We are not only putting large bodies of our own new lands in the hands of the few; but we are doing our best to keep them there and to cause the absorption of small farms into large estates. The whole pressure of our rev- enue system, national and state, tends to the concentration of wealth and the monopolization of land.” The explanation is probably not as simple as Henry George thought. Land specu- lation and the large special grants that were made by the Federal government were other important factors that made permanent development difficult. Both the land policy as represented by legislation and the methods of administration tended to dis- courage bona fide settlement and home ownership. As we look back through the pages of our national history, it is now easy to see that social forces were operating here, just as they did in England, to promote the concentration of land. As population became denser and wealth accumulated, the advan- tages of land ownership became more apparent. The possibilities lOur Lind and Land Policy, Vol. 9, page 11, Doubleday and McClure edition of Henry Georgds Works. 20p. Cit, Volume 9, page 95. " 42 of a land tenantry situation were first foreseen in New England, Where farm tenantry has never become as serious a problem as. in other parts of the country. A writer in the North American Review, in 1859, comments on this situation as follows: Farm Tenantry "in the United States “Our farms in older States instead of being divid- ed and subdivided as they ought to be, are growing larger and more unwieldy. The tendency of the times is unquestionably towards immense estates, each with a manorial mansion in the center and a dependent tenantry crouching in the shadow.” By 1870 the effects of the conditions referred to began to become apparent to thoughtful observers in almost every sec- tion of the country. Henry George rightfully pointed out that “the custom of renting land is unmistakably gaining ground.” This, in itself, Was not an alarming condition; but, connected with absentee landlordism, the problem at that time began to present a serious aspect. The rapidity with which farm tenantry has in- creased at the expense of permanent agricultural development will be outlined in succeeding chapters. CHAPTER III. THE PHYSIOCRATIC CONCEPTION OF FARM TENANTRY. Political economy has accepted the problems of agricul- ture as a part of the content of the science since its beginning in the eighteenth century. The Mercantilists ignored agricul- ture, but they did not attempt to outline a system of economic science} Beginning with the Physiocrats in the latter part of the eighteenth century, economists have constantly recognized agri- cultural production as an aspect of economic science. The stages and history of production have been described and the ex- act position of agriculture in the economic life of mankind has been carefully determined? Production has meant different things to different schools of economics. But all have recog- nized agricultural production as essential and fundamental. In the analyses of the factors of economic production, expressed or implied, recognition has been given to the relation of landlord and tenant. The Physiocrats may be considered the real founders of the first system of political economy. They were certainly the first to grasp the conception of a unified science of society?’ In their economic analysis, the Physiocrates regarded the raw material produced as the only true production. The manufacturers mere- ly transformed the material that Was extracted from the earth, and commerce did nothing more than transport the raw material or the manufactured articles from one to anotheri The Physio- crats classified all producers of raw material under the head of the “productive classes” and they designated those engaged in man- ufacture, commerce, and craftsmanship as “sterile” classes. Th-e Marquis of Marabeau, the forerunner of Quesnay, appreciated the importance of maintaining an efficient rural farm organi- zation as a means of increased food production. He insisted that the small cultivator should be encouraged, and the idle consumer should be viewed with reprobation. He saw the dangers of an absentee landlord system. “Great land owners should live upon 1Conrad, J. Politische Oekonomie, Vol 1, page 354. 2The stages in the history of production in the order of their historical development are: (1) the hunting and fishing stage; (2) the pastorial stage; (3) the agricultural stage; (4) the handicraft stage; (5) the industrial stage. See Ely and Wickar’s Elementary Principles of Economics, page 22. 3Gide and Rist’s History of Economic Doctrines, Book 1, page 2. '4Ingram’s A History of Political Economy, page 62. 43 44 Farm Tenantry in the United States their estates and stimulate their development-mot lead an ab- sentee life of pleasure in the metropolis?" Mirabeau was certainly the first economist to see the peril of this system, and his observation was remarkable for his time. Itshould be observed, however, that he was concerned with only two aspects of the problem. (1) In the first place, increased food production was the supreme need of France at that time. War and the expulsion of the protestants had greatly reduced the pop- ulation. Mirabeau understood in a general way what Malthus was to formulate into a doctrine at a later date—that popula- - tion tended to increase more rapidly than the available food supply would sustain. That this thought Was in Mirabeau’s mind is indicated in his book L’ Ami des H ommes, Whose sub-title was Traite de la Population. It should be observed that he had de- rived his conception of the relation of population to food produc- tion from Cantillion. (2) In the second place, the age was char- acterized by the existence of a large parasitic leisure class that was tending constantly to increase. The rural population was gradually being depleted as a result of the movement of the rural population into the cities. There was an imperative need, there- fore, to maintain the agricultural population on the farms as a means of safeguarding and increasing the food production of the nation. Mirabeau, it should be observed, was not thinking of a problem of social justice as it related to the elements in the rural population, but he was rather developing’ his economic doctrine from the viewpoint of consumption. It is necessary to remember this fact in order to prevent giving too large a significance to the implications of production that appear in the literature of the Physiocrats. Francois Quesnay, the greatest of the Physiocrats, was pro- foundly influenced by the views of Mirabeau. His first economic Writing Was in the form of two articles contributed to the Encyclopedie of Diderot—one on “Fermiers” (1756), the other on “Grains” (1757). In the first of these articles a careful compar- ison is made of the relative advantages and disadvantages of us- ing horses and oxen in farming. After a brief introduction on the importance of agriculture to the nation, he begins his argu- ment with a general statement that “Les terres sont commune- ment cultivees pa?" des fermiers avec des chevaiix, on par des 1Higg’s The Physiocrats, page 21. The Physiocratic Conception of Farm Tenantry 45 metayers avec des boufs.”1 He proceeds to show‘that fern/tiers who cultivate the land with horses have the advantage and that they are more prosperous than the metayers? Quesnay shows that France was suffering great loss in production due to the fact that under the metayer system the share of the tenant was too poor to purchase horses as a substitute for oxen? He did not seem to be concerned about the problem of poverty as it af- fected this class, but their producing ability was a matter of seri- ous concern to him. That Quesnay was not influenced by any conception of the relation of the landlord to the tenant, is also revealed in his at- titude toward large and small farm acreage. He thought that grande culture was preferable to petite culture. He had in mind a farm system with a large acreage in the hands of one landlord in which larger capital could be used in carrying on the farming enterprise. It is obvious that such a plan would neces- sarily have greatly increased farm tenantry and greatly decreas- ed the number of landed proprietors. In his article on “grains” he makes an argument for large farms cultivated by metayers under the management of an entrepreneur. Quesnay gives figures to show the losses sustained due to poor farm equipment and a small farm system.‘ The article on “grains” represents a more profound and sci- A entificdiscussion of agricultural economics than his fermiers. But much of the contents relates to aspects of agriculture not germane to this discussion. In December 1795, Quesnay printed his Tableau Oeconomique. He has here summarized in brief form the views of several of the members of the school, especially the Esai of Cantillion. This analyse is a direct contribution to the subject of farm tenantry as it was practiced in France at the time. He begins his dis- cussion with the classification of the citizens of the nation. “La nation est reduite a trots classes de citoyens: la classe produc- 1“The lands are usually cultivated by farmers with horses, or by the metayers with oxen.” Quesnay’s Oeuvres cconomique et philosophiques, page . 2The Metayer was a. share tenant who received stock, tools, and seed from the landlord. The Metayer system was common in England and Continental Europe during the time of Quesnay. However, it had almost ceased to exist in England by the time of Adam ' Smith. 30p. Cit., page 177. _ _ 40p. Cit, page 206; Cp. H1gg’s Op. Cm, page 30. 46 - Farm Tenautry in the United States tive, la classeldes proprietaries et la classe sterile} He then defines each class. By the “productive” class he has in mind the metayers---those who cultivate the land and pay therefor an annual rent to the landlord and Who, by their efforts, enrich the nation. The class of proprietors or landlords includes the sovereign, the owner of the land, and the tithe-owner. ‘Cette classe subsiste par le reuenu ou produit uet de la culture, que lui est page auuullemeut par la classe productive.” All those who do not belong t0 one or the other of these classes are assign- ed to the classe sterile. While there are serious defects and inaccu- racies in this broad classification, it should be. observed that it served the purpose of emphasizing the importance of agricul- tural production as an essential industry. Quesnay no where raises the question of social justice be- tween landlord and tenant. He assumes the status of each class as being good for society. His only thought was that of a relationship that would yield the maximum production. He im- plies that an economic motive is essential to make this possible. He traces the productive problem of France to an insufficiency i of capital. France has boundless natural resources, but the pro- ductive capital is insufficient to develop it. The source of capital is agricultural production. If surplus derived from this source is consumed in non-productive endeavor and not applied to better agricultural equipment, the nation is doomed to sterilty. On this assumption Quesnay proceeds to discuss the distributive process between the three classes. It is evident to him that lux- ury and extravagance were absorbing much of the nation’s in- come that should go back into future production. He attempts to impress this fact upon the minds of the people by designing a chart or table showing the prevailing distributive processes. This is the very core of the Tableau Oecouomique and the essence of his doctrine of net product. 1“The nation is reduced to three classes of citizens; the productive class, the landlord class and the unproductive class”. Op. Cit., page 305. 2“That class lives 0n the income from the net product of cultivation, that is paid an- nually by the productive class”. Op. Cit, page 308. The Physiocratie Conception 0f Farm Tenantry v 47 Quesnay arranged his table in three parallel columns as fol- lows :1 Classe Productive Classe Classe Sterile Des Proprietaries Under each of these classifications he shows how the income is distributed. Extravagant claims have been made by the admirers of Quesnay concerning the value of his chart. Its value, however, consists largely in the fact that it is a concise presentation of the most definite contribution that the Physiocrats made to political theory. Produit Net. This relates to the prodnit net, or net profit, theory that was advocated by this school of economic thinkers. Quesnay follows his table with a rather full discussion of this subject. He assumes that agriculture yields a prodnit net, or net profit, over and above the cost of production. In the table he attempts to show hypothetically what becomes of this net product year by year. He assumes that the net profit on production is one hundred per cent. In other words, on the basis of 300 livres of capital under normal conditions the returns in product will amount to 600 livres. The landlord receives 200 livres, of which one-half is spent in agricultural produce and one-half in other expenses (dispenses steriles). Considering the distributive process from the middle table (Classe des proprietaries), one-half the total. goes to the left and is again applied to agriculture as a means of producing another rent, while the other goes to the right and is consumed in some form of luxuries, such as manufactured goods, housing, clothing, etc. This process is supposed to go on indefinitely. This theory of the prodnit net has given the Phys- iocrats their best claim to respect as economists. Not that the ‘ application of the theory to agriculture is sound, but the impor- tance of the recognition of large returns to agricultural endeavor has been a valuable incentive as a means of encouraging produc- tion. The influence of this theory on rent will be discussed in an- 10p. Cit., page 310. 48 . Farm Tenantry in the United States other connection. The influence of this theory was Widespread in France and it was constantly being emphasized by the members of the school. Dupont de Nemours, for example, declared that “the prosperity of mankind is bound up with a maximum net pro- duct.”1i The Physiocrats, of course, were mistaken in contending that this net product was confined to agriculture alone. We know now that manufacturing and commerce have continually yielded a larger net return on the capital invested than agricul- ture, but we must remember that at the time the Physiocrats lived "manufacturing and commerce had not developed to that ex- tent that it was possible for them to evaluate the returns on cap- ital in such enterprise. Gide and Rist offer the following ex- planations as to how the Physiocrats happened to make this error: “Their luxurious lives would have been impossible if the earth did not yield something over and above the amount consumed by the peasant. It is curious that the Physiocrats, while they regarded the arti- sans as nothing better than servants who depended for their very existence upon the agriculturalists, failed to recognise the equally complete dependence of the worthless proprietor upon his tenants. If there had existed instead a class of business men living in ease and luxury, and drawing their dividends, it is quite possible that the Physiocrats would have concluded that there was a net product in industrial enter- prise.” The Physiocrats deserve the respect of the students of rural economics. They did not always determine accurately the economic facts relating to agricultural production, but they were thinking constructively about very essential problems. The distinction between agriculture and industry was not found in the theory of the Physiocrats, but they determined the lines of approach to important economic theories that were later to be formulated into scientific conclusions. Adams Smith and Ricardo were greatly indebted to them for important theories that have stood the test of time. The former developed his social economics relating to landlord and tenant and approach- lOrigine d’une Science Nouvelle, page 846. 20p. C-it., page 16. The Physiocratic Conception 0f Farm Tenantry 49 ed a sound theory of rent, While the latter made his most definite contribution to economics in his theory of rent through a study of the “net product.” “Let us remember”, says Gide and Rist, “that despite some glaring mistakes, agriculture has never lost the pre-eminence which they gave it.”1 It is Worthy of note, in conclusion, that the Physiocrats were more nearly the found- ers of the science of rural economics than that of general eco- nomics. They have not yet received due credit for their con- tribution to a permanent agricultural productive system and to rural social organization as a means of making this system ef- fective. 10p. Cit., page 17. CHAPTER IV. ADAM SMITH’S VIEWS ON FARM TENANTRY. Adam Smith has been recognized as the logical succes- sor tothe Physiocrats. He had traveled in France in 1764-66 and had become acquainted With several members of this school of economic thinkers. While credit has been given to the Physiocrats for systematizing the study of economics, Adam Smith has received the credit for raising this study to the dignity of a science and establishing a new school of eco- nomic thought. The Wealth of Nations appeared in 1776. The advancement that this volume makes over its French predecessors is well summarized by Gide and Rist as follows: “Smith has been successful in borrowing from his prede- cessors all their more important ideas and welding them into a more general system . . . . . . A true social and eco- nomic philosophy was substituted for their fragmentary stu- dies, and an entirely new value given to their contribution. Taken out of their isolation, they help to illustrate his general theory, becoming themselves illuminated in the process.“ No better illustration of this point can be found than in that part of the Wealth of Nations in which Smith discusses the relation of distribution to rural farm organization. Some writers have attempted to present Smith as the prophet of the approaching industrialism rather than the successor of the proponents of the “natural order.” Depont de Nemours was responsible for the name given to the French school of economists. Physiocracy meant to him “the rule of nature.” But we should recall that the Industrial Revolution had scarcely had its beginning when Smith wrote his monu- mental work. The Wealth 0f Nations is based primarily on agrarian economics rather than industrial economics, and Smith’s point of view is not widely different from that of his French predecessors. Like them, he emphasized the importance of production. The introduction to the Wealth of Nations re- veals a deep concern for the improvement of the productive processes. Chapter I of Book II on the division of labor has lHistory of Economic Doctrine, page 52. C . S 1' ’ . ' ' ' - introduction to the Everyman Library editign frlilllgnvi/ezllhlmfiltfiillidlilé? pomt m hm 50 Adam Smithis Views 51 this same object in view and only differs from Phys- iocratic literature in the angle of approach. Like his predecessors, he saw the relation of production to consumption and it is quite obvious that he saw it more clearly. Adam Smith discusses the economics of farm tenantry in his chapter on “The Discouragement of Agriculture?“ This chapter may appropriately be compared to the Tableau Oeconomique of Quesnay, although, of course, the approach and the illustrative material are quite different, but both au- thors were thinking of the same problem and thinking of it in terms of the same effects. However," it must be admitted that the relation of landlord to tenant was more accurately described by Smith, and the interest of the tenant was more sympathetically considered. As We have seen, landlordism was far less a problem in France than in England. Its char- acteristics were also very different. France,'even before the Revolution, had been a country of small proprietors. On the other hand, landlordism was the accepted order of things in England and tenantry of a certain type was the prevailing method of cultivation. This contrast in conditions is respon- sible for the different treatment of the subject of farm tenan- try by these two representative thinkers of their respective schools. ~ Smith begins with an historical statement of the origin of the greater estates in Europe. a He describes the confusion and unsettled conditions resulting from the invasion of the Germanic and Scythian nations. He explains, how, in the midst of these conditions, the chiefs acquired and usurped the greater part of the lands. Even the uncultivated lands were appropriated. To preserve the integrity of these estates, the law of primogeniture was promulgated. He says, “This orig- inal engrossing of uncultivated lands, though great, might have been but a transitory evil. They might soon have been divided again, and broke into small parcels either by succes- sion or by alienation. The law of primogeniture hindered them from being divided by succession: the introduction of entails prevented their being broke into small parcels by alienation.” 1Book S, Chapter 2, Everyman Library edition. 20p. CZL, Book 3, Chapter 2, page 341. 52 Farm Tenantry in the United States Smith explains the departure from the Roman law of descent, where no distinction was made between male and female in the inheritance of land, on the grounds that “when land was considered as a means, not of subsistence merely, but of power and protection, it was better that it should descend undivided to one,” But he hastens to explain that “laws frequently continue in force long after the conditions which. first gave occasion to them and which could alone render them reasonable are no more.“ This is true of the laws of primogeni- ture and entail. He declares that “in the present state of Europe when small, as well as great estates, derived their security from the laws of their country, nothing can be more completely absurd. They (laws of primogeniture and entail) are founded upon the most absurd of all suppositions, the supposition that every successive generation of men have not an equal right to the earth and to all that it possesses; but that the property of the present generation should be re- strained and regulated according to the fancy of those who died, perhaps, four hundred years ago.” This very sig- nificant statement was probably the first authoritative attack made upon the legal restriction that had grown up in Europe, as a means of preserving landed estates. Whatever may have been the original justification for such enactments, - the time had come when the people preferred an equitable and just system of land distribution. While Smith’s voice was not heard very far, it should be recognized that he had lifted it in a worthy cause, and, historically, those of us who can look back and see what Wisdom he was giving expression to should give him recognition for his efforts even if those efforts were in vain. A modern view of the situation is implied in Smith’s criti- cism of the landlord. “It seldom happens,” says he, “that a great proprietor is a great improver.” He explains this on two grounds. (1) In the first place, during the disorderly times all the energies of the landlord were consumed in de- fending his territories, and he had no time to think of improv- ing his estates; (2) in the second place, when law and order were established, the landlord had usually lost both his 10p. Citj, Book 3, Chapter 2, page 342. ' 20p. Cit., Book 3, Chapter 2, page 343. Adam Smith/s Views 53 incentive and requisite abilities in this regard. The effects of this situation are best described in the words of Smith as follows: “To improve land with profit, like all other commercial projects, requires an exact attention to small savings and small gains, of which a man born to a great fortune, even though naturally frugal, is very seldom capable. The situation of such a per- son naturally disposes him to attend rather to orna- ment which pleases his fancy than to profit which he has so little occasion. The elegance of his dress, of his equipage, of his house, and household furni- ture, are objects which from his infancy he has been accustomed to have some anxiety about. The turn of mind which this habit naturally forms follows him when he comes to think of the improvement of land. He embellishes perhaps four or five hundred acres in the neighborhood of his house, at ten times the ex- pense which the land is worth after all his improve- ments; and finds that if he was to improve his whole estate in the same manner, and he has little taste for any other, he would be a bankrupt before he had finished the tenth part of it. There still remain in both parts of the United Kingdom some great estates which have continued without interruption in the hands of the same family since the times of feudal anarchy. Compare the present condition of those estates with the possession of the small proprietors in their neighborhood, and you will require no other argument to convince you how unfavorable such ex- tensive property is to improvement?" There is not to be found in any recent literature relating to farm tenantry a more accurate statement of the evils con- nected with absentee landlordism. These expressions are especially applicable to the plantation system of the United States, where feudal forms still persist after the legal restric- tions have passed away. Smith follows his criticisms of the landed proprietors with a discussion of the other aspect of the problem. He goes minutely into the relative advantages of land cultivation by slaves, metayers, and ordinary tenants. Cultivation by slaves is regarded as the least satisfactory. Experience demonstrates 10p. Cit., Book 3, Chapter 2, page 344. 54 Farm Tenantry in the United States that work done by slaves, though it costs only the mere main- tenance, in the end, is the most expensive of all. A person who has no hope of acquirng property has no incentive to work. Slave labor on farms is the result of love of power over others rather than the expectation of economic gain that such a system of cultivation provides. The matayer system, according to Smith, is the successor of cultivation by slaves. This system is a species of tenantry. He explains it as follows: “The proprietor furnished them with the seed, cattle, and instruments of husbandry, the whole stock, in short, necessary for cultivating the farm. The pro- duce was divided equally between the proprietor and the farmer, after setting aside what was judged necessary for keeping up the stock, which was restored to the proprietor when the farmer either quitted, or was turned out of the farm.”1 There is one essential difference between cultivation by slaves and metayers: “Such tenants, being freemen, are capable of acquiring property, and having a certain propor- tion of the produce of the land, they have a plain interest that the whole produce should be as great as possible in order that their own proportion may be so.” This consideration insured a better system of cultivation and increased production over that conducted by slaves. The most serious defect of the metayer system, which is applicable to any system of share tenantry, is described by Smith as follows: “It could never, however, be the interest even of this last species of cultivation to lay out, in the further improvement of the land, any part of the little stock which they might save from their own share of the produce, because the lord, who laid out nothing, was to get one-half of whatever it produced. The tithe, which is but a tenth of the produce, is found to be a very great hindrance to improve- ment. A tax, therefore, which amounted to one-half must have been an effectual bar to it. It might be the interest of a metayer to make the and produce as much as could be brought out of it by means of the stock furnished by the proprietor; but it could never be his interest to mix any part of his own with 10p. Cit., Book 3, Chapter 2, page 346. 20p. Cit. Book 3, Chapter 2, page 346. Adam Smith? Views 55 it. In France, where five parts out of six of the Whole kingdom are said to be still occupied by this species of cultivators, the proprietors complain that their metayer take every opportunity of employing the master’s cattle rather in carriage than in culti- vation; because in the one case they get the whole profits to themselves, in the other they share them with their landlord. This species of tenants still subsist in some parts of Scotland. They are called steel-bow tenants. Those ancient English tenants, who are said by Chief Baron Gilbert and Doctor Blackstone to have been rather bailiffs of the land- lord than farmers properly so called, were probably of the same kind.”1 This species of tenantry was gradually succeeded by the tenant lease system, which Smith regarded as defective, but a great improvement on the metayer system. Under the lease system the farmers cultivated the land with their own stock and provided their own seed and implements. A definite fixed rent was paid to the landlord. The lease for years en- abled and encouraged the tenant to make certain improve- ments on the farm. He was usually inclined to do this for he had a reasonable expectation that he would receive full benefit therefrom before the expiration of his lease. The advantages of a long lease policy were fully under- stood by Smith. It was the only plan that encouraged the tenant to take a personal interest in the land he cultivated and to provide improvements at his own expense. Under English law a lease for life entitled the lessee to vote for a member of parliament. This political recognition was helpful in negotia- tions with the landlord. Smith regarded the long lease as a great social achievement, and he took pride in the establish- ment of this policy in Great Britain. “The law which secures the longest leases against successors of every kind is, so far as I know,” says he, “peculiar to Great Britain.” It is worthy of observation that both in Great Britain and con- tinental Europe it was necessary to protect tenants by law against heirs and purchasers. The tenants’ rights Were still insecure when a change of ownership occurred. The pro- prietor of the land whose political power gave him great in- fluence was constantly trying to restrict the rights of tenants. 10p. Cit., Book 3, Chapter 2, page 347. 56 Farm Tenantry in the United States The method adopted to accomplish this purpose was through the restriction in the number of years of the lease. That this was a shortsighted policy was very clearly foreseen by Adam Smith. Every tendency to reduce the number of years of a leasehold correspondingly decreased the incentive to provide farm improvements at the expense of the tenant. The effects of this are interestingly described by Smith as follows: “Avarice and injustice are always shortsighted, and they did not forsee how much this regulation must obstruct improve- ments, and thereby hurt, in the long run, the real interests of the landlord.“ This last statement is typical of Smith’s “general sociolog'- ical way of looking at society,” to quote a phrase of Albion W. Small? The discussion of farm tenantry in the Wealth of Nations is the best illustration of Smith’s interest in distribu- tive justice. Professor Small was not mistaken in asserting" that “whatever the influence of Adam Smith’s work may have been, one cannot study his philosophy as a whole, even in the figment of it that has come down to us, without being certain that his basic propositions were clearly and positively the human rather than the capitalistic principles.“ His deep concern about human relations is illustrated in the following passage connected with the subject under discussion. l “Under all these discouragements, little im- provement could be expected from the occupiers of land. That order of people, with all the liberty and security which law can give, must always Improve under great disadvantages. The farmer, compared with the proprietor, is as a merchant who trades with borrowed money compared with one who trades with his own. The stock of both may improve, but that of the one, with only equal good conduct, must always improve more slowly than that of the other, on account of the large share of the profits which is consumed by the interest of the loan. The land cultivated by the farmer must, in the same manner, with only equal good conduct, be improved more slowly than those cultivated by the proprietor, on-account of the large share of the produce which is consumed in the rent, and which, had the farmer 10p. Cit. Book 3. Chapter 2, page 349. 2Adam Smith and Modern Sociology, Chapter I, page 1. 30p. Cit, Chapter I, page 2. Adam Smithfis Views 57 been proprietor, he might have employed in the fur- ther improvement of the land. The station of a farmer besides is, from the nature of things, inferior to that of a proprietor.“ It seems unfortunate that so little attention has been paid to Smith’s discussion of this problem. Professor Small seems to have been the only social scientist that has adequate- ly emphasized the sociological content of Smith’s WOFlLZ Per- haps his most enduring contribution to social science will be found to be his discussion of human relationship rather than the validity of his economic theories. In his discussion of the relation of landlord and tenant, he has Worked out with admir- able precision the importance of adjusting social relationships not only as a means of improving social conditions, but as the best arrangement in the interest of better economic enter- prise.’ 10p. Cit., Book 3, Chapter 2. page 350. 20p. Cit” Chapter 5, page 186. CHAPTER V. THE VIEWS OF THE EARLY CLASSICAL ECO- NOMISTS ON FARM TENANTRY. Economic thinking was destined to take a new turn about the beginning of the nineteenth century. The rapid develop- ment of the industrial revolution gradually changed the em- phasis of economics from production to distribution. The Phys- iocrats and Adam Smith were impressed with the importance of agricultural production, but, beginning with the publication of Le Traite d’ Economic gaolitiquc by J. B. Say in 1803, the em- phasis began to be laid on the economic aspects of manufac- turing and commerce. In discussing, for example, Des difiew entcs sortes d’ industrie, Say speaks of industrie agricolc, show- ing that he is thinking in terms of production as an industrial enterprise} He devotes the first book in his Traite to produc- tion (Dc la Production dc Richcsses), but he is thinking of pro- duction in a larger sense than that given to the term by the Physiocrats. Even in discussing the advantages of production, he does not emphasize farm production. The relationship of landlord (proprictare) to tenant (fermicr) is only referrerl to incidentally in connection with proceeds derived from agricul- tural production? Book II of the Trait/c is devoted to distri- bution, and Chapter Nine of this book presents Say’s theory of rent, which, of course, implies the economic relationship of land- lord to tenant. But it discusses the subject without reference to the human elements in the problem. He refers to the politi- cal rise of the tenant in England, which is clearly traceable to in- formation acquired from the Wealth of Nations. In contrast with the English system, he closes his chapter with an explana- tion of the mctayer system and refers to its feudal origin. This is as near as Say comes to the social aspects of farm tenantry. Turning again to England, the economists who succeeded Adam Smith did not attempt to evaluate the sociological con- cepts that Smith originated. As Small says, “To speak figuratively, then, the apostolic succes- sion in social philosophy from Adam Smith is through the sociologists rather than the economists. The soc- iologists have kept alive the vital spark of Smith’s moral philosophy. They have contended for a view lTraite d’ Economic Politique (2nd edition, 1814) Chapter 2, page 8. 20p. Cit., Volume 2, page 468. 58 The Views of the Early Classical Economists 59 of life in terms of persons rather than in terms of technology. That it, they have put persons in the cen- ter of their picture of life, and have assigned a subor- dinate place to the theory of those technical activities which deal with the material products of persons. The economists are the separatists and hierarchy, in ex- aggregating the importance of a technology ’till it has overbalanced, in social doctrine, the end to which it is normally tributary?“ This is particularly true of Malthus, Ricardo, and James Mill. They excluded social relationships from the field of polit- ical economy. The subject of “rent” was carefully treated as one of the aspects of distribution. But the early economists of the nineteenth century ignored the question of social justice be- tween the renter and his landlord. The classical economists were dominated by the idea thateconomic laws were nearly as immutable as physical laws. This caused them to approach the content of political economy from the standpoint of an abstract science. This point of approach caused them to feel that noth- ing could be done to ameliorate social conditions. There could be no escape from the consequences of economic law. Views of Malthus. Malthus approached nearest to the social phase of the ques- tion in his Essay on the Principle of Population, which first appeared in 1798 and rapidly passed through several revised editions. He discusses the influence of the agricultural system of the various countries and calls attention to the evil effects of a system Where lords own and control large tracts of terri- tory? In another connection he lays down a principle to guide in the adjustment of the mutual interests of landlord and tenant as a means of maintaining the population. “With a view to the individual interest, either of a landlord or farmer, no labour- er can ever be employed on the soil who does not produce more than the value of his wages; and if these wages be not on an average sufficient to maintain a wife, and rear two children to the age of marriage, it is evident that both the population and produce must come to a stand. Consequently, at the most ex- lAdam Smith and Modem Sociology, Chapter I, page 4. 2Essay on the Principle of Population as it Affects the Future Improvement of Society, Chapter 8, page 79. 60 Farm Tenantry in the United States treme practical limit of population, the state of the land must be such as to enable the last employed labourers to produce the maintenance of as many, probably, as four persons?“ In his Principles of Political Economy (1820) Malthus de- votes nearly one hundred pages to the rent of land? This dis- cussion shows clearly that he is thinking entirely from the land- lord’s point of view. He shows his concern for the landlord in discussing “The causes which may mislead the landlord in let- ting his lands, to the injury of both himself and the country.” His deep concern for the landlords’ interest is expressed in the following passage with reference to the competitive rental of land: “In the first place, he may be induced, by the im- mediate prospect of an exorbitant rent, offered by farm- ers bidding against each other, to let his land to a tenant without sufiicient capital to cultivate it in the best way, and make the necessary improvements upon it. This is undoubtedly "a most short-shighted policy, the bad effects of which have been strongly noticed by the most intelligent land-surveyors in the evidence brought before parliament; and have been particularly remarkable in Ireland, where the imprudence of the landlords in this respect, combined perhaps with some real difficulty in finding substantial tenants, has ag- gravated the discontents of the country, and thrown the most serious obstacles in the way of an improved system of cultivation. The consequence of this error is the certain loss of all that future source of rent to the landlord, and wealth to the country, which arises from the good farming of substantial tenants.“ Malthus also seems to feel that the landlord might be too generous to the tenant. He warns the landlord against the error of giving a whole part of the rents to the tenants when there is a temporary depression in the price of farm products. “There is no just reason to believe, that if, in the present state of this country, the landlords were to give the whole of their rents to their tenants, corn would be in any marked de- gree cheaper - - - - - - - - The effect of transferring all rents to tenants, would be turning them into landlords, and tempting 10p. Cit., Book 10, Chapter 3, page 92. It should be observed that he is thinking only of the influence of this situation on the problem of population. He did not have in mind the social relationship involved in the problem. 2Chapter 3, pages 136-217. 3Principles of Political Economy, (2nd edition), Chapter 3, page 190. The Views of the Early Classical Economists 61 them to cultivate their farms under the superintendence of care- less and uninterested bailiffs, instead of the vigilant eye of a master, who is deterred from carelessness by the fear of ruin, and stimulated to exertion by the hope of competence. The most numerous instances of successful industry, and Well-directed knowledge, have been found among those who have paid a fair rent for their lands; who have embarked the Whole of their cap- ital in their undertaking; and who feel it their duty to watch over it with unceasing care, and add to it. whenever it is possi- ble.”1 It would appear that Malthus was fearful that turning tenants into landlords would be harmful to the country. He seems to have totally ignored the discussion of this subject by Adam Smith. It is hardly possible that at the time Malthus was insisting on the landlords’ exacting full rents from their tenants that he was unaware that the distressing conditions existing among tenants were making it necessary for landlords to re- duce their rents in the interest of rural welfare? In speak- ing of these conditions at that time Prothero says: “Rural con- ditions were deplorable. Even as late as 1833, it was stated that, in spite of rent reduction, which in Sussex amounted to 53 per cent.; there was scarcely- a solvent tenant in the Wealds of Sussex and Kent, and that many farmers, having lost all they had, were seeking work upon the roads.” Malthus felt called upon to defend the landlord against the charge that was current at the time that his interests were in conflict with those of society. He thought that the interest of the landlord was not only not in conflict with the interests of the state, ‘but, on the other hand, that there was the strictest union between them. The only exception being in the case of im- portations. He thought that in this respect the landlord could not be separated from other producers? The Impersonal View of Ricardo. Ricardo was a contemporary of Malthus. Both were prin- cipally concerned with the economics of distribution. But the 10p. Cit., Chapter 3, page 191. 2See Protherds English Farming—Past and Present, Chapter 15, 0n “Agricultural De- pression and the Poor Law, 1813-37”. 30p. Cit., page 324. 40p. Cit., Chapter 3, page 206, Cp. Haney’s History of Economic Thought, Chapter 11, page 204. 62 Farm Tenantry in the United States contribution of Ricardo to economic theory is a more substantial product than that of Malthus. His theory of rent is his most important contribution to economic doctrine. Conditions in England at the time made the subject of rent a burning ques- tion of the day. Every writer on political economy during the first half of the nineteenth century felt called upon to discuss it at great length. None saw more clearly “That three fold hierarchy which consisted of a worker toiling for a daily wage in the employ of a capitalist farmer who draws his profits towered over by a landlord in receipt of rents” than did Ricardo. But none saw this situation more abstractly than he. He scarce- ly refers to the relationship of landlord and tenant in any con- nection. In his entire treatment of the theory of rent, no ref- erence is made to the human elements in the problem. Ricardo was concerned about stripping political economy of all surplus content. He did not agree with Smith or the Physi- ocrats with reference to the scope of economics. “One of his great services lay in the fact that more than any predecessor he separated political economy from other branches of knowl- edge, and from ethics and jurisprudence, in particular.“ Ethical Viewpoint of Sismondi. The successors to Ricardo carried the abstract method to such an extreme that no social content was left. We must look again to France to find a writer who appreciated the human ele- ments in the economic problems of his day. We find him in the person of Jean Charles Leonard Simonde de Sismondi, who was born in Geneva, Switzerland, three years before the publication of the Wealth of Nati0ns»(1776). He was the first constructive critic of the classical economists. He sharply takes issue with Ricardo for his abstract method and unsupported generalities. He thought better of Smith and Say because they were more concrete. He restored to the content of economics the ethical aspects that had disappeared under the abstract reasoning of the English economists of the early nineteenth century. Haney, in contrasting Sismondi with the classical economists, says: “In his outlook and purpose Sismondi differs from the Classical School. He was a reformer. Ethical considerations played a 1Haney’s History of Economic Thought, Chapter 12, page 234. The Views of the Early Classical Economists 63 large part in his thought; and to him economics was largely an art. He aimed to put economics upon a new basis; the econom- ists had taught how to increase national wealth ; he would teach how to increase national happiness, and to this end Would point out the advantages of government intervention to regulate the- progress of wealth.“ Sismondi was primarily interested in agriculture. He re- fers in several places to the beauty and attractiveness of his farm, and his first economic publication was the “Tableau de l’ Agriculture.” His chief contribution to economics was his Nouveaux Principles d’ Econoniie Politique ou de la Richesse dons ses rapper-ts aoec la Population, which was published in 1819. His last important work on Etudes sur la Economie Politique (1837-38) expressed his protest against the abnormal influences of the industrial movement on economic theory. Much of Sismondfs social reflections appear to be incidental to the general theme he is developing. For example, in discuss- ing the probable effects of repealing the English corn laws, he refers to the relative cost of production of corn in England and some of the other corn-producing countries. He takes occas- ion to contrast unfavorably the conditions of the English tenant with the cultivator in other countries. He says it would be difficult for England to compete with such a country as Poland ‘ or Russia, where the only price paid by the landlord proprietor for production is “a few hundred lashes judiciously bestowed upon the pheasants.” This is typical of Sismondi’s method. Social conditions were to be taken into consideration in arriving at con- clusions relating to economic theory? Sismondi recognized the growing conflict between public and private interests. He was the first economist clearly to recognize this tendency. He believed the state should adjust production to consumption demands. He advocated govern- mental action as a means of restoring or maintaining social jus- tice between classes and securing adequate facilities for distri- bution. He saw the harmful possibilities of large-scale pro- duction. As a means of maintaining equality of opportunity, he advocated small-scale manufacturing, and consistently with this llbid, Chapter 19, page 304. ZNouveaux; Principles, Volume 1, page 257. 3Ibid, Volume 2, page 268. 64 Farm Tenantry in the United States view, he advocated a system of agriculture based on peasant proprietorshipf With the exception of Adam Smith, he was the greatest advocate of a farm system that would safeguard the nation against indifferent landlordism. His whole discussion of peasant proprietorship was determined by-this point of view. While he had much to say on this subject, two illustrations will suffice to make this point clear. In his argument for peasant proprietorship, he contends that the system offers the maximum of contentment for the producers of the country. He says: “When we traverse nearly the whole of Switzerland and several provinces of France, Italy, and Germany, We need not inquire in looking at any piece of land, to see if it belongs to a peasant pro- prietor or to a farmer. The intelligent care, the enjoyments provided for the laborers, the adornment which the country has received from his hands, are clear indications of the former.” In discussing the economic relationship of landlord and tenant, he very clearly reveals the nature of his sympathies in his condemnation of the landlord who attempts to demand more produce (he has in mind here the metayer system) than equity justifies. “The landlord who attempts to depart from usage,” says he, “who exacted more than his neighbor, who took for the basis of the agreement anything but the equal division of the crops, would render himself so odious, he would be so sure of obtaining a metayer who was an honest man, that the con- tract of all the metayers may be considered as indentical, at least in each province, and never gives rise to any competition among peasants in search of employment, or any offer to culti- vate the soil on cheaper terms than one another.“ These examples are sufficient to illustrate the humanizing aspects of Sismondi’s political economy. It is unfortunate that. his influence on economic thought has not been greater than it has. It did exert a great influence on John Stewart Mill, refer- ence to which will be made in the succeeding chapter. TIbid, Volume 2, page 661. 2Ibid, Chapter 3, page 87. 3Etudes sur Economie politique, 6 me essais De la Condition de Cultivateurs en Toscane- CHAPTER VI. JOHN STUART MILL’S VIEWS ON FARM TENANTRY. John Stuart Mill Wrote his Principles of Political Economy during a transition period in economic thought. The first edi- tion of this great work appeared in 1848. Classical economics received its best interpretation at his hands. At the same time he contributed a substantial product that was destined to assist in undermining the doctrines of the English classical school. His effort to apply the economic doctrines of Malthus, Ricardo, and his father, James Mill, to the changing World situation of which hewas a part, caused him to fall into some inconsistencies that are quite apparent. g Mill was greatly influenced in his thinking by Comte’s con- ception of society. Comte had severely condemned the doc- trines of the classical economists. He regarded their treatment ofyalae, utility, and production as sterile and unprofitable. Mill had been taught by his father to respect the views of the Eng- lish economists on these subjects, and he Was confronted with the impossible task of reconciling the economic conception of Ricardian economics With the unified conception of social phe- nomenon as taught by Comte. The influence of Comte is evi- dent in the “Preface” to the first edition of the Principles of Political Economy. In commenting on the Wealth of Nations, he says: “The most characteristic quality of that Work, and the one in which it most differs from some others which have equalled or even surpassed it as mere expositions of the general principles of the subject, is that it invariably associates the principles with their applications. This of itself implies a much wider range of ideas and of topics than are included in Political Economy, considered as a branch of abstract speculation. For practical purposes, Political Economy is inseparably intertwined with many other branches of social philosophy. Except on matters of mere detail, there are perhaps no practical questions, even among those which approach nearest to the character of purely economical questions, which admit of being decided on economical premises alone.”1 The admirable statement of Professor Haney as to the place lPage 27 of Preface, Principles of Political Economy. - 65 66 Farm Tenantry in the United States filled by Mill’s Principles, gives a fitting introduction to the so- cial application to the subject of farm tenantry: “Ricardo had developed a certain side of Adam Smith’s political economy, carrying it to its logical con- clusion. Malthus added his theory of population; Sen- ior his abstinence theory; and several writers contrib- uted refinements at this or that point. There was still room, however, for one who should be broad enough to survey the Whole field and fuse these various ele- ments into a systematic body of doctrine. In fact, there was need for a restatement of the classical eco- nomics; a restatement which would take into consider- ation the criticisms of the old system, and current con- ditions; one that would at least begin to realize the in- sufficiency of the existing political economy in relation to the problems of modern society, and so prepare the Way for a new economics. This was the work of John Stuart l\lill.”1 i Mill makes plain the insufficiency of existing economics in his “Preliminary Remarks.” The interaction of economic in- fiuences and social forces is clearly indicated in the third para- graph as follows: “Every one has a notion, sufficiently correct for common purposes, of What is meant by wealth. The enquiries which relate to it are in no danger of being confounded with those relating to any other of the great human interests. All know that it is one thing to be rich, another thing to be enlightened, brave, or humane; that the questions how a nation is made wealthy, and how it is made free, or virtuous or eminent in literature, in the fine arts, in arms, or in policy, are totally distinct enquiries. Those things, indeed, are all indirectly connected, and react upon one another. A people has sometimes become free, because it had first grown wealthy; or wealthy, because it had first become free. The creed and laws of a people act pow- erfully upon their economical condition; and this again, by its influence on their mental development and social relations, reacts upon their creed and laws.” Mill then proceeds to illustrate this interaction by specific references. He traces the steps of industrial evolution through the successive steps and evaluates the effects of each. In dis- cussing the characteristics of agriculture, he faces the problem 1Hmey’s History of Economic Thought, Chapter 21, page 344. ZIbId, Ashley Edition, page 1. John Stewart Millls l7iews 67 of the agency of production. The position of the agricultural producer is presented by Mill as one of disadvantage and un- equal opportunity. After explaining how agricultural surplus is secured, he says: “The surplus, too, whether small or great, is usually torn from the producers, either by the government to which they are subject, or by the individuals, who by super- ior forces, or by availing themselves of religious or traditional feeling of subordination, have established themselves as lords of the soil.”1 The injustice of the government toward produc- ers is described in the succeeding paragraph in more detail: “The government, in those countries, though vary- ing in its qualities according to the accidents of per- sonal character, seldom leaves much to the cultivators beyond mere necessaries, and often strips them so bare even of these, that it finds itself obliged, after taking all they have, to lend part of it back to those from whom it has been taken, in order to provide them with seed, and enable them to support life until another harvest.” Mill, of course, was here thinking of the practice in oriental nations, but the illustrations used in succeeding paragraphs in- dicate that in other forms the same policies have been followed by the govenments of Europe. He undoubtedly knew that the Physiocrats had complained of the existence of similar condi- tions in France. ' If the producers should by chance escape the unjust sys- tem of taxation, he was confronted by the capitalist upon whom he was compelled to rely for financial support. The process is quite simple: “The money dealers lend to the unfortunate culti- vators, when ruined by bad seasons or fiscal exactions, the means of supporting life and continuing their cul- tivation, and are repaid with enormous interest at the next harvest; or, on a larger scale, they lend to the government, or to those to whom it has granted a por- tion of the revenue, and are indemnified by assignments on the revenue collectors, or by having certain dis- tricts put into their possession, that they may pay themselves from the revenues; to enable them to do llbid, page 12. 2Ibid, page 12. 68 Farm Tenantry "in the United States which, a great portion of the powers of government are usually made over simultaneously, to be exercised by them until either the districts are redeemed, or their receipts have liquidated the debt.”1 After this historical recital of conditions in oriental coun- tries, Mill turned to the conditions of agricultural production in ancient Europe, where he finds conditions generally better than a in oriental countries. He traces these conditions to the advan- tages of small town-communities where the rent was equally divided or assigned in graduated allotments. Under this sys- tem “the whole produce of the soil belonged, without deduction, to the family which cultivated it. So long as the progress of events permitted this disposition of property to last, the state of society was, for the majority of the free cultivators, prob- ably not an undesirable one; and under it, in some cases, the advance of mankind in intellectual culture was extraordinarily rapid and brilliant?” It is at this point that we begin to see the influence of Mal- thus on Mill. He realizes the advantages of the situation he describes, but he hastens to explain that it could not continue. The increase of population under these conditions created ab- normal demand for land, which made wars inevitable. Small communities found it necessary to join with larger communities as a means of defense. Inequalities arose simultaneously with the process of empire building. Rome illustrated what happen- ed in connection with land tenure. “The Roman empire ulti- mately became covered with the vast landed possessions of a comparatively few families, for whose luxuries, and still more, for whose ostentation the most costly presents were raised, while the cultivators of the soil were slaves or small tenants in a nearly servile condition.” Under the influence of this social process, European society became composed, in unequal numbers, of landed proprietors and actual tillers of the soil. Thus grew up the system of landlord and tenant that existed in England at the time of Mill. He realized, however, that important differ- ences existed in the different countries. “In some the land owners were a class in themselves, almost entirely separated llbid, page 14. 2Ibid, page 14. sIbid, page 16. John Stuart Mill’s Views 69 from the class engaged in industry; in others, the proprietor of the land is almost universally its cultivator, owning the plow and often himself holding it. When the proprietor himself does not cultivate, there is sometimes, between him and the labourer, an intermediate agency, that of the farmer who advances the subsistence of the labourers, supplies the instruments of pro- duction, and receives, after paying a rent to the landowner, all the produce: in other cases, the landlord, his paid agents, and the laborers, are the only sharersf" While all of this discussion by Mill in his “Preliminary Re- marks” is largely historical rather than economic, two tendencies appear. (1) In the first place, Mill clearly reveals his interest in the welfare of the producer. He indicates that he believes the cultivator of the land should receive profitable returns from the efforts expended. This will appear more obvious when We ex- amine his economics of this situation. (2) In the second place, there is implied in this historical setting Mill’s belief in the inter- relation of the economic and social problems effecting national welfare. His social philosophy is so closely interwoven in his economic exposition that it is often useless to attempt to ex- tricate his economic doctrine from his social views. This, too, will reappear in the examination of the particular aspects of farm tenantry that Mill discusses in Book II of his Principles. Private Property in Land. Book II of Mill’s Principles is devoted to distribution. He begins with a discussion of property. He announces that in ac- cepting the principle of private ownership we must assume that in the beginning it was not accompanied by inequalities and in- justices which obstruct its beneficial use. “Every full grown man or woman, we must sup- pose, would be secured in the unfettered use and dis- posal of his or her bodily and mental faculties; and the instruments of production, the land and tools, would be divided fairly among them, so that all might start, in respect to outward appliances, on equal terms. It is possible also to conceive that in this original appor- llbid, page 20. 7 0 Farm Tenantry in the United States tionment, compensation might be made for the injuries of nature, and the balance redressed by assigning to the less robust members of the community advantages in the distribution, sufficient to put them on a par with the rest. But the division, once made, would not again be interfered with; individuals would be left to their own exertions and to the ordinary chances, for making an advantageous use of what was assigned to them?“ The other alternative for this economic system of private property is communism, which is described by Mill. After re- viewing the communistic schemes rather sympathetically, Mill returns to it in Chapter two of Book II when he discusses the theory of private property. He defines the institution of private property and describes the principles of inheritance. This leads him to an important and fundamental question. On what grounds is the exclusive ownership of property defensible? He thinks the answer is to be found in the recognition of the essential principle that all persons shall possess exclusively what they produce by their labor and accumulate by their abstinence. But how can this be applied to land where productive power is derived from na- . ture rather than industry? Mill reminds us that “though the land is not the product of industry most of its valuable qualities arepz Labor is as necessary here as in "industry. Therefore, “the use of the land in agriculture must indeed, for the time be- ing, be of necessity exclusive; the same person who has ploughed and sown must be permitted to reap?“ This conclusion seems very simple and very obvious. But Mill’s general analytical powers and logical methods carry him deeper into the question. These reasons seem sufficient justification to Mill from an eco- nomic standpoint, to give validity to private property in land. But he hastens to declare that “They are only valid, in so far as the proprietor of the land is its improver. Whenever, in any country, the proprietor, generally speaking, ceases to be the improver, political economy has nothing to say in defense of landed property as there established. In no sound theory of private property was it ever contemplated that the proprietor of land should be merely a sinecurist quartered on it.””* This is llbid, Book 2, Chapter 1, page 202. 2Ibid, Book 2, Chapter 2, page 230 3Ibid, Book 2, Chapter 2, page 230. 4Ibid, Book 2, Chapter 2, page 231. J 01m Stuart M'ill’s Views 71 a very remarkable and significant statement. This view had not been previously expressed by any economic thinker. Clearly Mill here makes the principle of private property in land de- pendent on its proper use as a social asset. This doctrine has de- served Wider recognition in the land policies relating to tenure, both in England and the United States. It certainly deserves recognition and acceptance as a guiding principle in the farm tenantry situation that confronts us at the present time. That Mill had in mind a concrete situation is evident from the use he makes of this doctrine. He tells us that in Great Britain the landed proprietor is not infrequently an improver of the land. But he hastens to explain that it is not generally so. He charges that the landlord in most cases rents his land on such ‘conditions that it cannot be improved by the tenant. In the southern part of England, leases are not used, Which makes im- provement impossible except by capital supplied by the land- lord. As a result of this condition, the south of England is very backward in agricultural improvement compared With the north of England and with Scotland, Where a better system prevails. Some landlords are not financially able to provide improvements. But “were they ever so much inclined,” says Mill, “those alone can persistently do it, Who have seriously studied the principles of sci- entific agriculture, and great landlords have seldom seriously studied anything?” An intelligent leasing system is urged by Mill as a means of relieving this situation and supplying a justification for prop- erty in land. The landlords “might at least hold out inducements to the farmers to do What they will not or cannot do themselves; but even in granting leases, it is in England a general complaint (1848) that they tie up their tenants by covenants grounded on the practices of an obsolete and exploded agriculture; while most of them, by withholding leases altogether, and giving the farmer no guarantee of possession beyond a single harvest, keep the land on a footing little more favorable to improvement than in the time of our barbarous ancestors.” If this is not done, the conditions that justify economically the existence of private property in land cease to exist. Even the argument for the llbid, Book 2, Chapter 2, page 232. Qlbid, Book 2, Chapter 2, page 232. 72 Farm Tenantry "in the United States sacredness of property cannot be appropriately applied to such a situation with reference to land. “When the ‘sacredness of property’ is talked of, it should always be remembered, that any such sacred- ness does not belong in the same degree to landed prop- erty. N0 man made the land. It is the original in- heritance of the whole species. Its appropriation is wholly a question of» general expediency. When pri- vate property in land is not expedient, it is unjust. It is no hardship to anyone to be excluded from what others have produced: they were not bound to produce it for his use, and he loses nothing by not sharing in what otherwise would not have existed at all. But it is some hardship to be born into the world and to find all nature’s gifts previously engrossed, and no place left for the newcomer. To reconcile people to this, after they have once admitted into their minds the idea that any moral rights belong to them as human beings, it will always be necessary to convince them that the ex- clusive appropriation is good for mankind on the whole, themselves included. But this is what no sane hu- man being could be persuaded of, if the realization be- tween the landowner and the cultivator were the same everywhere as it has been in Ireland.“ It is obvious that Mill is very close to the theory of land nationalization here. In subsequent paragraphs of the same chapter, he appears even nearer to the doctrine of socialization of agricultural lands. This theory will not be pursued further a in this connection, but subsequent reference will be made to the views of Mill in discussing the economic remedies for the farm tenantry situation. Classes of Tenants. Mill classifies tenants as follows: (1) Metayers and (2) Cottiers. The interest that Mill feels in the problem of farm tenantry is indicated by his rather extended discussion of the economic situation, which causes him to explain at the close of his- chapter on this subject that it “has occupied a space almost disproportionate to the dimensions of this work.” Under a sys- tem of peasant proprietorship, the “produce of the land and labor llbid, Book 2, Chapter 2, page 233. J ohn Stuart Mill’s Views 73 belongs undoubtedly to the laborer.” But under a system of tenant farming the produce is divided between two classes—the laborer and the landlord. He explains that it is not a material circumstance which furnished the stock, or whether each fur- nishes a determinate proportion of it on an agreed basis. But the essential difference depends on “Whether the division of the produce between the two is regulated by custom or by compe- tition.” It is on this principle that Mill bases his classification of farm tenants. The metayer system was traceable to custom. The cottier system was the result of competition. With this explanation Mill proceeds to define and explain the metayer system. “The principle of the metayer system says he, “is thatthe laborer, or peasant, makes his engagement directly with the land-owner, and pays, not a fixed rent, either in money or kind, but a certain proportion of the produce, or rather of What remains of the produce after deducting What is con- sidered necessary to keep up the stock.“ In __ the case where the relative shares are a matter of custom, there are no laws for a political economist to investigate. But the po- litical economist is concerned, according to Mill’s view, with the effects of the system on the moral and physical condition of the tenant, and the effect of the system on his producing efficiency. Mill thinks the motive to exertion on the part of the metayer is not so great as that of the peasant proprietor, because the meta,- yer receives only a share of the produce that his labor provides, while the peasant proprietor receives all of it. But the metayer has a much stronger motive than the farm laborer who has no other interest than that of continued employment. Mill correctly conceived of the metayer system as a co-partnership between landlord and tenant. But he did not develop in his discussion the inequalities in this relationship. However, he refers to the controlling power of the proprietor to prevent the multiplication of people beyond the point of reasonable subsistence? it is re- grettable that Mill did not develop more concretely the theory that he advanced with reference to the relatively decreased ef- ficiency of the tenant farmer under the metayer system. The principle is incontrovertible that the strength of the economic llbid, Book 2, Chapter 8, page 303. 2Mill is profoundly impressed with the theory of population as advanced by Malthus, and its influence 0n economic doctrine was costantly appearing and re-appearing in his economic analyses. 74 Farm Tenantry in the United States motive is determined by the relative benefits derived from phys- ical effort. But Mill did not develop this theory further in his discussion of this subject. Mill considers at considerable length the conflicting views of English and French Writers on the relative merits of the metayer system in Europe. He discusses the objection to the system on the part of English authorities and quotes at some length from Arthur Youngl, who declares that the metayer sys- tem is “a most cruel burden to the proprietor, who is obliged to run much the hazard of farming in the most dangerous of all methods, that of trusting his property absolutely in the hands of people who are generally ignorant, many careless, and some undoubtedly Wicked.” Mill also quotes from Mc Culloch’s PTlTIr ciples of Political Economy? where the statement is made that “Whenever it (the metayer system) has been adopted, it has put a stop to all improvement, and has reduced the cultivator to abject poverty.” On the other side of the question, Mill quoted from Chatte- auvieux3 and Sismondi‘ with reference to the favorable aspects of the system. The metayer system of Italy is especially com- mended as having proved very satisfactory. Mill is very posi- tively inclined to share the views of the French authorities rather than those of his English contemporaries. He charges the English Writers With holding extremely narrow views on the subject. His own appraisal of the metayer system is Worthy of reproduction here: The metayer tenure is not one which We should be anxious to introduce Where the exigencies of so- ciety had not naturally given birth to it; but neither ought We to be eager to abolish it on a mere a priori view of its disadvantages. If the system in Tuscany works as well in practice as it is represented to do, with every appearence of minute knowledge, by so compe- tent an authority as Sismondi ; if the mode of living of the people, and the size of farms, have for ages main- tained and still maintain themselves such as they are said to be by him, it were to be regretted that a state of rural well-being so much beyond what is realized in lTravels, Volume 1, pages 404-405. 2Third Edition, page 471. 3Letters From Italy, translated by Rigby, page 16. 4New Principles of Political Economy, Book 3, Chapter 5. John Stuart Mill’s Views 75 most European countries, should be put to hazard by an attempt to introduce, under the guise of agricultural improvement, a system of money-rents and capitalist farmers. Even Where the metayers are poor, and the subdivision great, it is not to be assumed, as of course, that the change Would be for the better. The enlarge- ment of farms, and the introduction of what are called agricultural improvements, usually diminish the num- ber of laborers employed on the land; and unless the growth of capital in trade and manufactures affords an opening for the displaced population, or unless there are reclaimable Wastes on which they can be located, competition will so reduce Wages, that they will prob- ably be worse off as day-laborers than they were as metayersf Mill’s reference to the danger of substituting “a system of money-rents and capitalistic farmers” for metayers, Whose in- l terest Was only a share of the produce, deserves a Word of ex- planation. He greatly feared the transiency resulting from the money-rent system. The French economists had encouraged a system of peasant proprietorship as a substitute for the metayer system. As previously indicated, it was believed that the motive to increase production would be stimulated and gradually the farmers would become proprietors. But Mill, While conscious of these agencies, wisely observed that “the benefit would not be without alloy.” The tenant, in becoming a peasant proprietor at a quit-rent, would be subject to displacement “at the land- lord’s will and liable to have his rent raised by competition to any amount which any unfortunate being in search of subsistence can be found to offer or promise for it; he would lose all the features in his condition which preserve it from being deterior- ated; he would be cast down from his present position of a kind of half proprietor of the land, and would sink into a cottier tenant.” Mill’s fears Were not unfounded in this regard, but in seeing only the alternative between the French metayer system and a system that placed the tenure of the tenant Wholly in the hands of the landlord, Mill failed to see an intermediate system that later developed in England as a result of his own teaching. The lease system_ that he was discouraging, gave relative per- llbid, Book 2, Chapter 8, page 316. zlbid, Book 2, Chapter 8, page 317. 76 Farm ‘Tenantry in the United States manency to the tenancy and encouraged farm improvements, was destined larely to offset his objection to a system of money-rents. In chapters nine and ten Mill discusses cottier tenancy. He has constantly in mind in this discussion the land-tenure situa- tion in Ireland. Under the original plan the cottier was a sub- tenant, who rented a cottage and an acre or two of land from a peasant proprietor. But by common use the term has come to apply to all tenants whose rents are determined by competition rather than by custom. While Mill, with some reservations ap- proved of the metayer system, he was unsparing in his condem- nation of a “cottier” system. The condition of the farm laborer depends on the amount of rent he is required to pay. Under a system of competition, as we shall see in the chapter following, rent is regulated by the available supply of land and the demand for it. The demand is determined by the number of rural popu- lation, the relative fertility and location with reference to mar- kets and transportation facilities. The effects of this system, according to Mill, was “to bring the principle of population to act directly on the land.” Here again Mill is emphasizing the doctrines of Malthus with reference to population, but ignoring the other factors referred to in the preceding sentence. As land is fixed in quality and population has unlimited possibilities of increase, unless some natural or artificial checks are applied, the competition for land must tend to increase con- stantly. To Mill this presented an almost impossible situation. He says: “In such a condition, what can a tenant gain by any amount of industry or prudence, and what lose by any recklessness? If the landlord at any time exerted his full legal rights, the cottier would not be able even to live. If by extra exertion he doubled the produce of his bit of land, or if he prudently abstained from pro- ducing mouths to eat it up, his only gain would be to have more left to pay to his landlord ; while, if he had twenty children, they would still be fed first, and the landlord could only take what was left. Almost alone amongst mankind the cottier is in this condition, that he can scarcely be either better or worse off by any act of his own. If he were industrious or prudent, nobody but his landlord would gain; if he is lazy or intemper- ate, it is at his landlord’s expense. A situation more John Stuart Millis Views 77 devoid of motives t0 either labour or self-command, imagination itself cannot conceive. The inducements of free human beings are taken away, and those of a slave not substituted. He has nothing to hope, and nothing to fear, except being dispossessed of his holding, and against this he protects himself by the ultima ratio of a defensive civil war.”1 ‘ Constructive Proposals to Meet This Situation Mill set about the task of proposing a remedy for this sit- uation. Historically, at least, the proposal is of improtance, be- cause it is the first that was made in the interest of improving» the condition of the farm tenant and contributing to the solution of the rural land tenure problem. Between the date of publica- tion of the first edition of the Principles of Political Economy (1848) and the appearance of the third edition (1852), the Eng-- lish government had taken cognizance of the farm situation in. Ireland. The English Parliament attempted to relieve the dis- tress of the Irish farm tenants by conferring on them a royal claim to charitable support. Mill was prompt to point out that the solution of the problem and the improvement of the condi- tions of the farm tenant depended on a more intelligent land pol- icy rather than a resort to the practice of a system of govern- mental charity. He submitted several proposals as possible solutions. (1) His first proposal contemplated the abolition of cottier tenancy through an act of Parliament whereby the land of Ireland was to be made the property of the tenants, subject to, a fixed rent to be charged by the government. In other words, land nationalization was to be applied as a remedy for this sit- uation. This proposal for the complete socialization of the landi was very radical, and Mill was called upon to justify his position. He contended that the policy would be perfectly warrantable if v by so doing a great public good was accomplished. He thought. the landlords should be compensated by the government for the land from which they were expropriated. But he contended that they should have no choice with reference to surrendering it for the public good. He slightly modified his general proposition by contending that not all the land should be taken over by the government. He thought it would be a mistake to provide. a. Jlbid, Book 2, Chapter 9, page 323. 78 Farm Tenantry in the United States system of agriculture consisting entirely of peasant proprietors. He believed that there was a place for large farms, cultivated scientifically, with the application of sufficient capital to serve as demonstrators of the best methods of production. He realized that peasant farmers could not afford the delay and risk of costly experiments to secure improved crops and better methods of pro- duction. Therefore, there was a place for experimental farms, as we would say today, in the midst of the farms owned and cul- tivated by the proprietors where they would have the oppor- tunity to observe soil improvement, systems of crop rotation, the application of farm machinery to farm production as a means of increasing crop yield and adopting better methods. It is in- teresting to observe that in the United States this plan has been adopted in many states where agricultural experiment stations have been provided for this very purpose, the difference in pol- icy being that the state has fostered the farms for these purposes rather than leaving them to the benevolent intentions of cap- italist farmers. (2) Mill’s second proposal was for the utilization of waste land. He would bestow ownership on those who would reclaim waste land, and compel the owner to surrender the title. How- ever, he would require the payment of a fixed quit rent equal to a modest interest on its value as waste land. It is interesting to observe that this is not a very dissimilar proposal to that of the Secretary of the Interior, Mr. Lane, made just after the close of the war. He recommended to Congress that the waste land be reclaimed by the government and parcelled out to the soldiers "who had taken part in the recent war. (3) Another suggestion of Mill was to encourage individuals to co-operate in buying land in large tracts for the purpose of selling it to peasant proprietors in small farms. He felt that by employing private capital in this way a double purpose would be served. In the first place, a profitable return on the in- vestment would accrue to those interested in the enterprise; and secondly, the social and agricultural economy of Ireland would be improved by substituting small farm owners for cottter ten- ants. J ohn Stuart Mill’s Views 7 9 The Influence of Mill. Mill exerted a Widespread influence on the farm tenantry ' problem in England. Slowly but surely public opinion crystal- lized about the views he had expressed. It is true that land na- tionalization did not come about as a result of his teaching, but it gained a number of notable adherents who have contended for it until the present day. In a more practical Way results have been accomplished. The English radical party was attracted by the thrift of the French peasantry after considering Mill’s views of them. The various small Holdings Acts that have been passed in England have been traceable to the in- fluence exerted by the teaching of Mill.‘ If Mill had accom- plished no other reform than that of securing a statutory modi- fication of the common law relating to landlord and tenant, he would be entitled to a significant place in the esteem of the social reformer. ~ As Mill’s teachings have important bearings on the practi- cal situation in the United States, reference will be made in sub- sequent chapters to the views that have been outlined in this discussion of Mill’s contribution to the subject of farm tenantry. 1Gide and Rist, History of Economic Doctrines, page 372. CHAPTER v11. THE ECONOMICS OF FARM RENT. The subject of farm rent implies a system of agricultural tenantry. The topic of “rent” has been included in every im- portant Work on political economy, and in its place in economic theory has been definitely determined. In the economics of the dis- tribution of Wealth, rent, interest, and wages are the respective products of land, capital, and labor. The distribution of these sev- eral products has become a topic of increasing importance. The three classes who have shared the benefits are landowners, cap- italists, and laborers. The conflicting interests that commercial enterprise has developed among these classes have created the most acute problems of our civilization. The part of the national product which represents land goes to the land owner and is called economic rent or simply rent. The measure of this product presents a fundamental problem of economics. Economists have very generally agreed that economic rent is the just share that the land owner should receive by virtue of ownership. But it should be observed that from time to time there have been thoughtful men who have denied that economic rent should ever '?oe appropriated to individuals who claim ownership of the soil. In other words, the theory of the socialization of the land, or land nationalization, has been advocated from time to time by some of the most thoughtful economic thinkers of the World. .But as a general thing private ownership in land has been recog- nized, and the right of the land owner to the private appropria- tion of economic rent has been generally conceded. But when the lland owner receives from a tenant a larger share of the produce, %§l*< 2%’ 053 e0 Allen . . . . . . . . . . . . ..] 192] 60.9 ] 17.2 ]39.1] 42] 11.4]$1,613]$11,706 Cowley . . . . . . . . . . ..] 222 60.1 ] 21.4 ]38.7] 40 12.3 1,417] 12,317 Jewell . . . . . . . . . . . ..]140] 56.6 32.0 ]43.4 36 8.0 1,62s|12,044 Pottawatomie . . . . . 70] 64.3 17.9 35.7 36] 8.4 1,184] 12,307 Average . . . . . . . . . . .. 60.0 22.0 39.3 40] 11.0 1,477] 12,405 He accompanies this table with the following pertinent statement: “The surveys bring out two facts very clearly, viz: that tenancy is on the increase and that the average age of ten- ants is in the neighborhood of 39 or 4O years, thus showing the The Increase and Distribution of Farm Tenants 127 difficulty that renters are experiencing in becoming land owners.” O. S.- Rayner, the Associate Agronomist of the Experi- ment Station of the Colorado Agricultural College says: “I am sorry to say that we have no data available relative to land ten- antry in this state. For the past two years we have been devot- ing the summer months to farm management survey work and at present have records in six dry land and three irrigated coun- ties. Several times We have tried to run some correlations based on land tenantry but as yet we have not been able to show any results. This is largely due to the fact that the country is fairly new and most of the farms are operated either by straight owners or by owners who are also renting additional land. In the dry land section the low value of the land, coupled with the fact that most of the people are homesteaders, gives us a fairly uniform condition. They are practically what you would call farm owners.” These are some of the views of those interested in rural economic problems and indicate the tendency with reference to tenancy in the respective sections referred to in the correspon- dence on this subject. Conclusion. The Fourteenth Census will clearly show that farm tenantry has continued to increase, especially in the South Atlantic, North Central, and South Central Divisions. While census figures are not available, Press Summaries issued by the Bureau of the Cen- sus show that farm tenantry has increased in many counties in states as widely separated as Arizona, Florida, Idaho, Iowa, and Tennessee. Conditions created by the war have accelerated the farm tenantry movement. War conditions have increased the speculation in farm lands. The land values have rapidly increas- ed in almost every part of the country. The prevailing high prices of farm products would, under normal conditions, enable a relatively large number of tenants to acquire farm homes, but this influence has been offset by the rapid increase in the price of farm lands. Under these circumstances, therefore, it is reason- ably certain that the census figures for 1920 will show a decided increase in the number and distribution of farm tenants through- out the nation. CHAPTER XI. THE FARM TENANT’S LABOR INCOME. The income from farm operations is not uniform even under like systems of tenure or in the same sections Where there is more or less uniformity in crop production. Great variation ex- ists also from year to year under changing economic and cli- matic conditions. But important tendencies are revealed by a study of the distribution of agricultural income. No adequate study of farm tenantry can be made that leaves out of account the share of distribution that is awarded to the tenant farmer under the various systems of tenancy that are practiced. The tenant farm~er’s income is the index to his standard of living and it re- veals his possibilities of ultimately acquiring a farm of his own. The data that have been brought together in this chapter from the surveys that have been made should be interpreted in the light of their influence on the opportunities and possibilities that they offer to the tenant farmer. Definition of Terms. At the outset, it is well to have clearly in mind the meaning of the economic terms that are used in this discussion. It may be Well to distinguish between capital and working capital. Capital is a term applied to the value of all property, such as land, farm buildings, agricultural implements, live stock, feed, seed, and available cash for farm operation. Working capital includes all of these with the exception of the value of land and permanent improvements. Agricultural income is the difference between receipts de- rived from the sale of farm products and the expenses that enter into the cost of raising these products. It represents what was earned by the farmer through his own efforts and his capital investment in the farm enterprise. Labor income is the amount the tenant earns exclusive of the help of his capital and represents Wages for manual labor and the profits on his managerial skill. Capital is usually charged at the mortgage rate of five and one-half per cent. on the market price. “By the agricultural income,’ says Carver, “is meant that portion of the gross product of the farms which goes, as com- 128 9 The Farm Tenant? Labor Income 129 pensation or income, to those who are directly connected with them. In other words, it is the total farm value of all products after deducting the cost of all such factors of production as com- ' mercial fertilizers, tools, machinery, etc., which are not them- selves produced on farms. More specifically, this agricultural income includes the Wages of farm labor, the rent of farm land, the interest on the capital invested in the stock, tools, machinery, etc., employed on farms, and the profits of farming. It is ob- vious that the agricultural income includes more at one period than at another. At one time, for example, all the labor in- volved in the growing of crops was performed on the farms. Now a part of it is performed in the shops where farm machin- ery is made. “Though it is customary in the United States for the func- tion of laborer, landowner, capitalist, and manager to be com- bined in the same person, yet it is possible, even in such cases, to divide the farmer’s income into four parts just named. The farmer sometimes hires all his manual labor, frequently a part of it; and sometimes borrows all his capital, frequently a part of it. In view of the wide variations of practice in these partic- ulars, it is simpler and less complicated to divide the whole farm income into four parts,—wages, rent, interest, and profits—even when they all go to one and the same person.“ It is a very complicated problem to distribute the farm in- come on the basis of the elements that enter into production and between the landlord and the tenant. In Hoard’s Dairyman for March 31, 1916, under the heading “A Tenant Problem,” a problem of this kind is stated and a solution submitted that is both interesting from the standpoint of the solution that is of- fered and as a means of indicating the intricacies of the prob- lem. The problem and its answer are as follows: “A owns a farm of 160 acres with 130 under cul- tivation and the balance pasture. He keeps 4 to 5 horses to do the work. He also owns 13 mature cows and machinery enough to do the work. Has a silo and an up-to-date dairy barn that will accommodate 33 cows together with cow, bull and calf pens. He owns jointly with B one bull, 7 two-year-old heifers, two yearling lPrinciples of Rural Economics, page 289, 130 Farm Tenantry in the United States heifers, and nine heifer calves. _ A also furnishes grain for horses, but all other feed shall be owned jointly. “B is to make all hay, raise enough corn for silo, and produce other feed for stock; B to have use of A’s horses to do such work. A farms to grain or other crops any land not used by B, and uses the same horses. What would be an equitable division of profits? What about repair bills, depreciation of machinery, risk and depreciation of horses and cows not owned jointly? “The rental problem is too complicated to permit of an easy or explicit reply. According to the facts presented it would appear that A was entitled to three- fifths of the profit from the sale of dairy produce and to share in like measure the increase in stock. Under this arrangement A should also bear one-half or three fifths of the cost of feed purchased. It is quite possible that conditions are such that A may well afford to grant B a one-half share instead of two-thirds but this is largely a personal matter between landlord and tenant and is to be determined on its merits in each instance. “In his new book on farm contracts, W. C. Tish- enor presents a novel and interesting method suggested by Dr. H. B. Miller of Ohio. ‘The first step,’ Says Dr. Miller, ‘in determining the basis for an equitable di- vision is to agree upon the actual money value of what each puts into the enterprise. Five per cent. is con- sidered a fair return upon‘the land. The investment in cows, work horses, and farming utensils should be al- lowed 10%, and upon the growing young stock there should be allowed 5 %’. “In order to show the application of Dr. Miller’s sug- gestion to the above problem we will assume A’s farm to be Worth $15,000 and his investment in horses, cows, and other stock and equipment to be worth $3,500. We will assume that B’s interest in stock is worth $1,200. Allow 5% on A’s $15,000 and 10% on his $3,500 and we find that A should receive $1,100 per year. As in this instance B’s only investment is in non-productive young stock, he should receive 5 per cent. on his $1,200, or $60. However, in addition to money put into the farm operation, B is also furnishing all the labor to op- erate the farm. We Will assume that B’s labor is worth $360 per year, in addition to the use of the house, garden, milk, etc.; we will assume that his hired help for the year costs him $480 for wages and board. B should, therefore, receive $60 plus $360 plus $480, or a total of $900 per year. The Farm Tenantfls Labor Income 131 “According to the above basis of computation A should receive a theoretical income of $1,100 and B a theoretical income of $900 of a total theoretical in- come of $2,000. It is, therefore, quite easy to under- stand that on this basis A should receive 11-20 of the actual farm income and B should receive 9-30. When this method of computation is followed, all the cur- rent farm expenses are paid from the gross income in the same manner as in the usual system of renting on shares. “If the actual net receipts for the year were $2,400, A would receive 11-20, or $1,320; while B would re- ceive 9-20, or $1,080. If the net farm income Was only $1,800, A would then receive the same 11-20, but it would amount to only $990; and in like manner B would receive 9-20, or $810. “The same principle would apply Whatever amounts were actually invested by either party, and the actual investment can best be determined "by an inven- tory agreed upon by both parties at the beginning and end of each lease term.- Permanent improvements taxes, etc., should be paid by the owner, the same as under the usual methods of renting. “The proposal of Dr. Miller as outlined above comes more nearly to approximate fairness between the difierent classes of farming as Well as profiering a more systematic method of determining a division of the returns from the farm operation. For instance, under the old share system the tenant who raised hay and sold it made more for his lab-or than the tenant who raised large fields of potatoes, because the latter tenant was compelled by the necessities of the crop to expend a greater‘ amount of labor and for this he does not secure an adequate return. Under the system proposed by Dr. Miller the labor in both instances would be cap- italized and the tenant who raises intensive crops that are liable to increase the general farm income would receive a more equitable share in the increase due to the greater amount of labor he has expended.“ The labor income of tenant farmers under this system of tenure and in typical sections of the country will be summar- ized from available data taken from reliable sources. 1H0ard’s Dairymzm, Volume 51, No, 10, page 437, for March 31, 1916. 132 Farm Tenantry in the United States The Tenant’s Labor Income in the Cotton Belt. In the study of the tenant system of farming in the Yazoo- Mississippi Delta made by E. A. Boeger and E. A. Goldenweiser of the Federal Office of Farm Management, important data on farm labor income have been secured. The Yazoo-Mississippi Delta is a large area east of the Mississippi River and extending from just below Memphis on the north to Vicksburg on the south. It goes without saying, that cotton is the sovereign crop of this river valley land. It is typically a tenant farming area of the South. From eight hundred and seventy-eight records, figures have been compiled to show the percentage of tenants under the various systems, making from $100 to $1,000 in labor income for a year’s work. These percentages are expressed in the follow- ing table: Percentage Having a Labor Income of not Less Angylnt Than Each Specified Amount} Income All Share Share \ - Cash Tenants Croppers Renters Renters $0 98.0 98.9 97.1 l 95.6 $100 94.0 97.1 92.0 90.2 $200 82.0 84.3 77.3 80.8 $300 59.9 56.6 61.9 63.9 $400 36.1 24.6 43.5 a 50.1 $500 22.1 10.1 26.4 37.0 $600 15.0 5.1 19.2 | 28.2 $700 10.6 2.4 12.3 I 21.8 $800 6.7 1.0 7.4 15.1 $900 4.5 0.5 3.7 11.1 $1000 3 5 0.5 3.0 l 8.4 These figures become more intelligible when compared With the interest returns on the landlord’s capital, as shown in the following table: _ The Farm Tenrmtis Labor Income 133 Average Rate of Interest on Land1ord’s Invest- ment on Holdings of Tenants in Each Speci- fied Labor-Income Group} Class l of ‘g Tenants +2 f: ,___ l 3 3 ' B B s; m ' (g go l oo: ocn o0: om o i“ =2 2» @1222 aelse 2e a? 11 W, __,____,,.__c__ .___ 41B Q _,_ Dee was wee meow l wee. _2@_ ------- ~~* 222 22 22; 222 .22: 222 are moppers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Share Renters . . . . . . 11.8 7.1a 8.0 9.2 12.4 13.3‘ 14.8 16.6 Cash Renters . . . . . . . .| 6.6 8.0 5.7 6.8i 6.7 6.41 6.0 7.1 “The share-cropping system is the safest for the tenant. The share cropper is practically assured of av- erage Wages for his work, but he rarely makes a large income. “The share renter fails more frequently t0 make even a bare living, but has a better chance to make a good income than has the share cropper. “The cash renter runs still greater risk of failure but has the greatest opportunity of making a labor in- come of not less than $1000. “The average labor income for share croppers was $333; for share renters, $398; for cash renters, $478. “From the point of view of the landlord the sit- uation is reversed. He is assured of a return of be- tween six and seven per cent. on his investment when the land is operated by cash renters no matter what the yield or the tenant’s labor income may be. “When the land is worked by the share croppers or share renters the landlord’s rate of interest often falls below six per cent. but when the yield is good and the tenant makes a good return the rate of interest some- times rises to more than three times that amount. “It appears on the Whole that the landlord can make better money on the average, when he rents his land on some system of shares. The average rate of interest received by the landlord from share croppers was 13.6 per cent.; from share renters, 11.8 per cent.; and from cash renters, 6.6 per cent. “The holdings of share croppers are considerably smaller, on the average, than those of share renters or lBulletiri-No. 337, U. S- Department of Agriculture. 134 ’ Farm Tenantry in the United States of cash renters, and there are few share croppers hav- ing as much as twenty-five acres in cotton, While about one-third of the share renters and of the cash renters have at least that acreage. The labor income of a ten- ant increases directly with the increase in cotton acre- age, but the rate of interest on the landlord’s invest- ment appears to be but little affected by the size of the holdings. “The principal factor in determining the amount of the tenant’s labor income and the rate of the landlord’s profits in this region is the yield of cotton to the acre. The relationship between yield of cotton and labor in- come, however, is much closer on cash renters’ farms than on those of share croppers, while the effect of yield on the landlord’s profits is more important under the share-cropping or the rent system. “The tenant’s incentive for securing a good crop is consequently greater among those Who rent for cash but, on the other hand, the landlord is more directly in- terested in the magnitude of yield on the land of his share croppers.” An economic study of farming in Sumter County, Georgia, made by H. M. Dickson and H. W. Hawthorne of the Federal De- partment of Farm Management, brings out similar data with ref- erence to the labor income of farm tenants. Sumter County is strictly in the cotton section and does not differ essentially in this respect from the Yazoo-Mississippi delta. However, the conditions of soil and climate are somewhat different, but the influence of cotton production on labor income is the predomin- ating consideration. In this particular county, there were found to be five hundred and thirty-four farm operators. “There were found to be 299 farmers owning a part of the entire farm oper- ated; 268 of these farms were owned by white and 31 by colored farmers; the other 235 farms were operated by tenants, of which 49 were white and 186 colored”1 In this study it has been found that the size of the farm enterprise has an important bearing on the tenant labor in- come. The following table and the interpretation that follows the table explains the influence of this factor: lAn Economic Study of Farming in Sumter County, Georgia, page 10, Bulletin No. 492 U. S. Department of Agriculture. The Farm Teuaufs Labor Iuoorne 135 Area, capital, receipts, expenses," and income on farms of dif- ferent tenures. Sumter County, Ga. I I m q - »—1 jg 31) i q) q) ‘E g '13 c“ S g ~ E E "‘ E Edsfr-E’: éfi sisfiég _%-- 1 so fie; e5 no analog sLefi/Hfi White} . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . I f | Owners . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 160] 158 $13,773 $4,097i$2,555 $1,542|$ 853 Owners additional . . . . . .. 38; 168 10,521 4,594 2,796 1,798| 1,272 Owners part rented out . 70f 1394 26,883 6,400 3,963 2,437) 1,093 Tenants . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49: 85 890 1,572 980 592 547 Colored: _ i Owners . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .1 12]‘ 95 5,984 1,659 977 682 383 Owners additional . . . . . . . 11; 77 3,043 1,646 955 691 539 Owners part rented out . . . 8} 307 15,998 3,107 1,812 1,295 495 Tenants . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .l 186,‘ 59 481 902 566 336 312 “The 160 farms operated by white owners, having an average of 158 acres of tilled land and with an in- vestment of $13,773, returned an average farm income of $1,542. Deducting interest on investment the owners have left, on the average, $853 as labor in- come. - Deducting from the farm income the value of the farmer’s labor, these farms show a return of 8 per cent. on investment. “There were 38 farms operated by white owners renting additional land. On the average these men op- erated 168 acres of tilled land, but owing to 30 per cent. of the farm area being rented, the average investment of these men was lower than that of the 160 owners. The average investment on these farms was $10,521, with a farm income of $1,798 and a labor income of $1,272. “The 70 farms operated by white owners renting a part of their farming land out were the largest farms found in this study. These farms averaged 394 tilled acres, of which 41 per cent. was rented out. The invest- ment averaged $26,883, labor income $1,093, and in- terest on investment 7 per cent. “Forty-nine of the farms were operated by white tenants. These farms averaged 85 acres of tilled land and with an average of $890 capital they returned a farm income of $592 and a labor income of $547. Sev- eral white tenants were found in this area who owned small farms, but who, in order to do a larger business, had leased their own farms and were operating large rented farms. ‘ v “It will be noted from this table that in all classes 136 Farm Tenantry in the United States of tenure the farms operated by colored farmers are smaller than those operated by white farmers of the same tenure. “Thirty-one of the farms were owned by colored farmers. Of this number 12 were operated as owner farms, with an average size of 95 tilled acres; average investment was $5,948; farm income, $682; and labor income, $383. Eleven of the farms owned by colored farmers were operated with additional land rented. These farms averaged 77 tilled acres, of which 26 per cent. was rented additional.‘ They had an average cap- ital of $3,043, a farm income of $691, and a labor in- come of $539.” “The remaining 8 farms owned by colored farmers were operated as owners renting out part of their land. These farms averaged 307 acres of tilled land of which 45 per cent. was rented out. The average capital in- vested was $15,998, which returned them a farm income of $1,295 and alabor income of $495. “The 186 colored tenants, as previously stated, were operators responsible for the entire operation of the farm. They farmed on the average of 59 acres, and with $491 capital realized a farm income of $336 and a labor income og $312. It is doubtful whether on the average, these men make any higher profits than the share croppers, as under the share-cropper system the profits of the land owner are dependent upon the quality of the crops grown by the cropper. The most desirable feature of the tenant system, from the stand- point of the tenant, is that in the main he is emanci- pated from the directing authority of the landlord and tlhulskhas more liberty than the share cropper to do as e 1 es.”1 A farm management study of cotton farms of Ellis County, Texas, which is a typical cotton county in that state brought out some interesting results with reference to labor income. In this study it was found that every operator with less than $4,000 capital is a tenant, while every one with more than this invested in the farm enterprise is an owner. It is interesting to observe from this study that tenants with an average capital of only $1,200 made nearly as much as owners with $10,000, while tenants with $2,500 invested made greater incomes than owners with an investment four times as great. “These figures indicate clearly that an operator with small capital can make a much better in- come as a tenant than as an owner.“ lAn Economic Study of Farming in Sumpter County, Georgia, pages 17 and 18. Bulletin N0. 492, U. S. Department of Agriculture. 2Bulletin 659, page 1'7, U. S. Department of Agriculture. The Farm Tenant’s Labor Income 137 The following table summarizes the data with reference to this situation: Relation of capital invested by farm operator t0 income of the operators of owner and tenant farms (79 farms, Ellis County, Texas, 1914) .1 Owner Farms Tenant Farms 4 w l Operator’s 5.4 ,,, l - 833 as g 2&1” __ _g___vg_____gz_____ w_______g<fim :87 _E1_,»J»-¢__ itoiefifeeeei. Less than $10 $ 7.43 s 736 15 $10 and over 13.62 1,233 175 to 259 acres. . . . . 23 I Less ‘than $7 5.55 I 1,096 21 z $7 and over 9.91 1,379 260 to 499 acres. . . . . 16 5 Less than $6.50 4.31 1,813 | $6.50 and 0V6] 8.11 1,588 “In each group of farms of the same size those farms with the more work horses and tools per acre produced the higher labor income. Comparing the three groups of farms of different size, the labor income in- creases directly with the increase in the size of the farm. It is generally conceded that more work horses and tools per acre are required on small farms than on large farms as shown in table II, but it is not gen- 1Bulletin 159 of the Agricultural Experiment Station, Iowa State College on Farm Leases in Iowa, page 159. 140 Farm Tenantry in the United States erally recognized that the use of more work horses and tools per acre is profitable on large as Well as small farms. . “One reason for more work horses and tools per acre being profitable is the greater relative advance in recent years in rent than in the price of Work horses and tools. Therefore it is cheaper to use a large amount of horse and tool labor to each acre of land.”1 .An interesting observation that does not appear elsewhere in the literature of this subject, is the influence of man-power on the tenant’s labor income. This is shown in the following table: LMAN LABOR PER ACRE. Effect of Different Amounts of Man Labor on ‘Labor Income When Farms Are First Sorted According to Size of Farm} £1 2 _m Size of Farms "3 g Man 541:3!‘ per g Sig’ ‘g g g 2E i? t» _ ._-.-__ - _-_._______vs L FL A .__.__P:*_ 100 to 174 acres . . . . .‘ 12 Less than $4 $3.15 $ 7 2 15 $4 and more 4.97 1,188 175 to 259 acres. . . . 24 Less than $3.50 2.97 1,173 $3.75 and more 4.47 1,302 260 to 499 acres . . . . 16 Less than $3.50 3.91 1,345 $3.50 and more 3.92 1,731 “In each group of farms of the same size, those farms with the more man labor per acre produced the larger labor income. Value of man labor includes wages for hired labor and cost of board and the value of labor done by the operator and his family.” Finally, in this study a summary is made of the influence of the type of farming on the tenant’s labor income with the fol- lowing results: lLtoyaVs Farm Leases in Iowa, page 161. 2lbid, page 162. The Farm Tenants Labor Income 141 TYPE OF FARMING. Relation Between Type of Farming, Crop Yields and Labor Income. s s. Animal Units* 21w 56 § *5"? 3 s l” q-i w as o. o o o v =- ‘b’ ‘1’ per100acres ¢g ggpcc v38 28 53g d E >'E 5° 53 O 2 5% ° . 2a.. 53 529535832“ QEO§Q>3§ Q P‘ V1 Record fig 059g g0“ 3g g"? fig g; g» '3 Qwg Number an: ma: m8 mm .43 2m ggako 3 2+1! 3m 3 . . . . . . . $ $2.50 10 $ $ $ |$ $ 6 . . . . . . . 3.00 12 .17 1.75 1.50 2.50 .50 7 . . . . . . . 2.50 8 .20 1.25 1.50 2.60 .80 11 . . . . . . . 2.50 12 .18 1.10 1.25 2.50 12 . . . . . . . 2.50 12. .18 1.75 1.10 1.25 14 . . . . . . . 2.50 11 .20 1.75 1.10 1.50 2.50 .50 15 . . . . . . . 2.25 16 . . . . . . . 2.50 10 25 1.95 17 . . . . . . . 2.25 12 18 1.90 .85 1.35 .75 18 . . . . . . . 2.25 10 20 1.80 1.10 1.25 .90 19 . . . . . . . 2.50 10 20 1.80 1.10 1.35 .90 24 . . . . . . . 1.50 27 . . . . . . . 2.50 3.00 .20 2.00 1.50 1.50 2.75 .65 28 . . . . . . . 2.50 12 .20 1.50 1.35 2.60 2.50 .65 29 . . . . . . . 2.90 10 .22 2.00 1.50 2.50 30 . . . . . . . 2.50 12 1.75 1.00 1.25 2.25 31 . . . . . . . 2.50 10 20. 1.00 1.35 2.50 2.25 32 . . . . . . . 2.50 10 .20 2.00 .125 1.35 33 . . . . . . . 2.50 10 .20 1.35 2.50 ' Average . . . . ..] 2.44] 2.60] 10.7] .199] 1.98] 1.154] 1.347] 2.52 2.375] .70 Cash Price ....| 1.70] 1.90] 14 | .145] 1.00] .75 ] .95 ] 1.75] 1.40 ] .40 Excess . . . . . ..]43.5 ]36.8 ] 21 ]3'7. ]98. ]53.8 ]41.8 ]38.2 ] .75 ] Data from other counties in this section show that there is great disparagment between cash and credit prices. Influence of Bank Loans on Credit Prices. It should be observed that these extreme differences in cash and credit prices prevail in those sections where credit is obtained largely through merchants orlandlords instead of through banks. Mr. Peteet found that whenever bank credit instead of store credit prevailed there was a relatively smaller difference between cash and credit prices. The rapid multiplication of national and state banks with their aggres- sive competition with the credit store, has slowly brought about an increase in the volume of bank credit business with the 1Pe_teet’s Farming Credit in Texas, page 5. 2Ib1d, page 7. Methods of Financing Tenant Farm Operations 215 farmers. Store credit with its economic abuses is gradually dis- appearing. The country store in may section of the country is gradually disappearing because of bank competition. The ten- ant farmer has learned that it is generally more economical to borrow money at the bank and pay cash for supplies than to de- pend upon the credit merchant or the landlord to finance the farm operation. Interest Rate on Farm Loans. It is not to be inferred that interest rates on bank loans have been low. Mr. Peteet found that in the section of the State where his survey was made that: “Interest rates on bank loans for crop making purposes vary from 1O per cent. per annum to more than 60 per cent. Minimum rates are on large loans to farmers of undoubted solvency. Maximum rates are paid by small farmers on loans of small amounts with short maturity. “The general level of interest rates corresponds with the general level of credit prices to farmers, and is highest in districts of small farms in East Texas, and lowest in the North Central tier of coun- ties, where the store credit system has almost dis- appeared. - “There is a marked variation between the rates charged by small banks in country towns and large banks in more populous trading centers. “Much difficulty was encountered in ascertain- ing from farmers the rate of interest charged on crop loans. In many instances they did not know the rate. In others they confused the discount rate with the rate per annum. Thus, in a certain corn- munity where bankers frankly admitted that they added 10 per cent. of the amount borrowed to the face of the note regardless of maturity, many farm- ers would say they were paying ‘ten per cent.’ “It is a noteworthy fact that, as a general rule, in the strictly agricultural regions of the, State, the cost of bank loans for crop making purposes it not affected by the time for which the money is borrow- ed. In other words, a farmer who borrows $100 February 1, payable October 1, pays the same gross amount of interest as his neighbor who borrows a 216 Farm Tenantry "in the United States like amount March 1, or April 1. The current prac- tice in all but a few sections is to add from 10'per cent. to 13 per cent. to the face of all notes having a maturity of more than three months, and in some counties this percentage is added to notes of 30 to 60 days maturity. A minor variation of this custom is to deduct 10 per cent. or more of the face of the note; thus, a borrower who executes a note for $100. will receive $90 in cash.”1 It is naturally to be expected that the merchant will charge more for goods when sold on credit that when sold for cash. It is also to be expected that rates of interest will vary under every condition that effects the risk of credit. Personal char- acter, business ability, thrift, methods and character of farm- ing, size of the loan, and many other factors enter into the in- terest rate. But the uniformly high rate of interest on short time farm loans indicates that as a rule farm credit is too high. In a study of the factors affecting interest rates and other charges on short term farm loans made by C. W. Thompson, specialist in Rural Organization of the U. S. Department of Agriculture, in 1916, it was found that interest rates and other charges paid on short time loans by farmers varied widely in different section of the United States? Extra charges“ are shown to be especially high in the Southern states and in the Rocky Mountain states. ‘The extra charges are usually the result of evading the legal interest rate. The grain states of the West, including North Dakota, South Dakota, and Nebras- ka, and the Southern states of Oklahoma and Texas, show the highest interest rates on short term farm loans. A compara- tive study of interest rates and extra charges shows clearly that tenantry and the one-crop system are determining factors in this situation. However, in some states the influence of these is neutralized by other predominant economic condi- tions. 10p. cit" page 11. 2Bu1letin No. 409, U. S. Department of Agriculture. 3By “Extra Charges,” is meant the commission that is charged for negotia- ting the loan. This is not an important factor and is more generaly resorted to in short term loans for farm operations. Methods of Financing Tenant Farm Operations 217 Factors Affecting Interest Rates and Other Charges on Short-Term Farm Loans. In the study made by Mr. C. W. Thompson, it is shown that the interest rate and other charges made on short term farm loansare influenced by the following: (1) Distance from financial centers. (2) Integrity 0f the farm borrower. (3) Financial ability and business habits. (4) Methods and character of farming. (5) Size of the loan? Exactly the same conditions influence the interest rate that the tenant farmer is required to pay. The banker bases farm credit on the degree of risk. Many tenants do not pos- sess the habits of thrift and business discernment that make them a good financial risk. The banker and creditor feel com- pelled to resort to high averages of interest rates to make farm loans safe. The uncertainty of crop production due to weather conditions has also influenced interest rates in the agricultural sections of the country. The chattei mortgage is the product of these conditions. In many of our agricultural states chattel mortgages are made in January and February for the year or until the crop has been harvested and sold. The loan is usually made for a sufficient sum to supply the family with food and clothing and for the running expenses of the farm enterprise. In most cases the credit merchant or banker feels the necessity of keeping the amount as small as possible. These chattel mortgages are often surprisingly small. Mr. Charles B. Austin found that one mercantile firm in Texas during one year’ held 254 chattel mortgages. The sum total of these 254 mortgages was $18,292. This is an average of $72.02 per mortgage? _ » Two very detrimental factors grow out of this situation. (1) In the first place, the farmer is ‘compelled to pledgeper- sonal property for a loan. The debt, therefore, is incurred for running expenses, which means that the sum secured on loan is used for consumptive as well as productive purposes. This lBulletin No. 409, U. S. Department of Agriculture, pages 6 to 9 inclusive. 33W“ “Studies in Farm Tenantry in Texas”, Bulletin N0. 21 of the University of Texas, (1915), Chapter 3, page 49. 218 Farm Tenantry in the United States is where the farmer’s loan often differs from that of the com- mercial loan. The latter borrows for productive purposes alone. He, therefore, secures his loan at a lower rate, and the loan is based on a different character of collateral. (2) In the second place, the conditions under which the tenant farmer secures his loan compel the creditor to restrict the amount as much as possible in the interest of safety. The result is that the tenant’s standard of living is low. His family is often un- dernourished. Illness that often adds a burden of medical and doctor’s bills and other unusual expenditures is prevalent. The labor and farm income is often consumed in meeting obligations growing out of misfortune and unforseen circum- stances. These conditions and their effects are too well known to need elaboration. In the admirable study made by Mr. Austin, he quoted statements from a few tenants with reference to this situation. These statements are so typical of hundreds that are familiar to the author that they are quoted as the best expressions of the tenant’s viewpoint with reference to this credit system: “The bankers charge from 12 1-2 to 15 cents on loans, and some of them do not run over 8 months; but if you borrow you will pay interest for 12 months. Some will say, ‘Why don’t you make them pay for usury?’ But say, friend, first you can't get a county attorney to take hold of it, and if you could, and did make them pay, you would never borrow any more in this county from a banker.’ “It is almost impossible to build up a permanent _ school in a rented school district. Your school will overflow one or two years, then fall far below par one, two or three years in this community. After the landlord gets his rent and the merchant his sup- ply account, there is nothing left for the doctor, nothing to build schools nor churches. “Renters, as a rule, failed to pay out this year. Merchants have collected less than 50 per cent. of this account, and carried over about 20 per cent. last year. Our leading banker estimates the reduc- tion in cotton acreage at 25 per cent. for 1915. “So you see we have to pay usury now to the merchants. First, they won’t pay us enough for our stuff so that we can get out of debt, and they keep us buying on time with such an extortionate price Methods of Financing Tenant Farm Operations 219 that the tenant is in debt from one year to another; never out of debt for a bare existence. “Let me say that the ‘Cash Bonus’ is not what is the matter with the tenant farmer today, but it is the fact that he is the victim of high interest and unrea- sonable large profit, as Well as high rent. He is forced to do just What the landlord says do. “Since answering your questions as brieflly and plain as I can, I wish to add a few Words in regard to, and facts concerning, the tenant situation. First, We are in a deplorable condition. Three-fifths of us Will never pay our store accounts. I have talked to merchants, and they all tell me they will never collect more than 60 per cent. of what they Pave let out.”1 It should be observed that many changes have come in the credit situation of tenant farmers within the last few years. Students of rural economics, intelligent bankers, and business men have been studiously seeking a better method and a bet- ter system for financing farm operations. A system of diversified farming is fundamental in over- coming the bad financial system for the tenant farmer. When the farmer has something to sell in the open market Weekly, he is in position to secure ready. cash to carry on much of the farm enterprise. He at least has the advantage of not seeking the loan for consumptive purposes. The sale of eggs, butter, and vegetables gives to the tenant a constant income that not only offsets a part of his farm loan but gives him also, partial control of market prices. In other words, he has something upon which to live if the merchant attempts to charge an un- reasonable price for his food products. As previously indicated, the merchant and the banker have often prevented diversification by making a single crop the basis of credit. It has been a very difficult process to overcome this harmful and uneconomic system. To remedy this situation Mr. R. L. Bennett of Paris, Texas, worked out a rate sheet to be used as a basis for securing farm loans. He secured its adoption by many bankers in Texas. This rate sheet used by the bankers in passing on the credit risk of farmer, and in a modified form has been adopted by the Federal 1Ibid, 5g... s2. 220 Farm Tenantry in the United States Reserve Bank of Dallas andwidely used in Texas, may be des- cribed as follows: (1) The rate sheet contains a formal application for credit and states the amount. This is followed by a state- ment of the farmer’s business assets and liabilities. Under the heading “Property Owned by Undersigned” are included cash on hand and in banks, notes and accounts due, agricultural commodities including grain, cotton, and other farm products; live stock, machinery and tools; real estate and improvements. On the opposite under “Debts Due By Undersigned,” are included notes and accounts due, mortgages on live stock, and mortgages on liens on real estate. (2) On the reverse side of this sheet under “List of Real Estate and Improvements Owned With Incumbrances There- on” is a tabulated statement of location and acreage, improve- ments, valuation, mortgages and liens. Under the heading of “live stock” are listed the number and value of horses, mules, cattle, hogs, poultry, sheep, and goats. Under “Machin- ery and Tools” are contained the number and cost of wagons, cultivators, and other farm machinery. The lower half of the back of this rate sheet under “Statement of Farming Opera- tions or Cropping System” contains blanks for information about the farm, acres in the farm and in cutivation, name of the owner, and the amount of rent to be paid. Then follows a tab- ulation of the number of acres to be planted in the various kinds of farm crops with a statement of the probable number of farm animals that may be marketed during the year.‘ The principle that guides in this business negotiation is stated by Bennett as follows: “Safe farming for liquidating a loan, is had when not exceeding 50 per cent. of the cultivated land of the farm is planted in one crop, or, when sufficient acres of the farm, as shown by a crop rate sheet, are planted in food and feed crops, including the necessary poultry, milk, cows, and hogs, to sup- ply the family and stock on the farm with food and feed, and to maintain the soil, and the balance of the cultivated land planted in crops for market, or for feeding stock for market.” lBulletm No. B-28, pages 5 and 6, Rate Sheet Essential in Long and Short Time Farm. Loans, by R. L. Bennett, published by Extension Service of the A. and M. College of Texas. 2Ibid, page 4. Methods of Financing Tenant Fawn Operations 221 This represents one of the means of securing a better sys- tem of safe farming as well as a more intelligent basis of economic credit. Its influence has been felt in two direc- tions. The farmer has been encouraged to diversify his crops, on the one hand, and the credit agency has secured a safer risk on his loan, on the other. The relation of credit to income determines the net finan- cial benefits that accrue to the farmer. A large labor income will not produce results in the way of home ownership if this income is absorbed by high interest rates and other abnormal expenditures. No normal business enterprise could have pos- sibly prospered under the economic system that has been ap- plied to farming in the past. No business has been so profit- able that it could have withstood the interest rates and the credt charges that have been forced upon the small farmer. While improvement has been made in recent years, much needs yet to be done before farming will be placed upon a sound financial basis. Agencies are at Work on this import- ant problem. It is reasonably certain that improvement will continue until farming will be established upon as sound eco- nomic principles as that already applied to commercial enter- prise. PART III. An Analysis of the Social Aspects of Farm Tenantry in the United States. CHAPTER XVIII. SOCIAL FACTORS CONTRIBUTING T FARM TENANTRY. - ’ The social influences that retard the movement toward farm ownership must be accounted for in an analysis of the social and economic conditions created by this rural situation. The remarkable growth of tenantry in recent years is due to p conditions that need to be understood. Farm tenantry is rapidly producing a menacing situation, and by no process of rea- soning can it be regarded with complacency. A social diag- nosis is a prerequisite to a correct application of remedies. The factors that enter into the social analysis vary from the very definite and obvious to the remote and intangible. Some are so interrelated as to depend on each other as a contribu- ting cause of farm tenantry. Some are economic and some are social. In many cases, the social causes are traceable to economic conditions. The less tangible of these factors will be briefly dis- cussed in this chapter, and in chapters that follow the more spe- cific factors responsible for the present farm tenantry situation will be analyzed. But the general and less specific need to be dis- cussed as a preliminary approach to the larger social influences that have made farm tenantry a real problem in our rural ciziliza- tion. The Unequal Bargaining Influence of Landlord and Tenant. 1. The obsolete political doctrine of laissez fairs has prevailed in the open country long after it has yielded to an intelligent system of social control in the cities. The conser- vatism of our rural population has retarded the application of regulations of the relationship of landlord and tenant by society. It has been assumed that it is nobody’s business whether a man chooses to cultivate his own land or prefers to rent it to another. If the owner is satisfied, no other person has a right to raise an objection or to offer a criticism. Can- not the farmer use his land as he pleases? Is not the tenant a free agent, capable of continuing on the farm he cultivates, 225 226 Farm Tenantry in the United States or moving to another as he chooses? Why not everybody, then, leave these matters to the free choice of the farmer and his tenant? This is the old laissez faire doctrine applied to the contractual reationship between landord and tenant, and it has persisted even to this day. We are reminded that in the history of the labor movement at one period this argument was advanced in opposition to the organization of labor as :1. means of increasing the bargaining power of laborers with capitalists. But the tenant farmer in many sections of our country today is passing through the transition stages similar to that through which organized labor passed. With the growth of tenantry the unequal bargaining power between land- lords and tenants has become more obvious, and the economic probems created by this inequality have become more press- mg. We still await the application of remedial measures such as have come to every other country. The doctrine of laissez faire practiced in rural communities must ultimately force society to interfere in the interest of the tenant farmer. Pre- vious reference has been made to cottier tenancy in Ireland, where this’ political doctrine prevailed for a long time, and the landlord did as he pleased in his contractual relations with his tenants. He chose to be an absentee landlord; he chose to collect a commercial rent so high as to reduce the labor income of his tenant below a subsistence wage and to spend his surplus income from this source in luxurious living in England or continental Europe. The farm land of Ireland was fast becoming sterile, and the peasant tenants a class of impoverished farm laborers. The British government finally‘, after half a century of Wrestling with this situation, was com- pelled to apply remedial legislation to the problem. The English parliament compelled the landlords to sell their farm holdings, to the state at a price determined by parliament, and in turn the government sold the land to the tenants on sixt - eight and one-half years time at three and one-half per cent. interest. This was the substitute for the doctrine of laissez faire in the rural sections of Ireland. In many other countries a similar policy has had to be applied as a substitute for the Social Factors Contributing t0 Farm Tenantry 227 eighteenth century individualism, out of which this doctrine originated. We have accepted and applied the doctrine in this country that where the bargaining powers between two mutually interested groups of our population become unequal, it is the duty of the government to restore equality of con- tractual relations by legislation. It is inevitable that we must extend this doctrine to the relationship of landlord and tenant. The landlords have not yet realized that they are retard- ing the development of a better rural situation by their sys- tem of tenantry. Or, it might be more accurate to say, that the system of tenantry that landlords uaconsciously apply is responsible for the situation. But whatever be the correct statement of the case, home ownership is being retarded in this country by the unequal ability of the tenant to contract with his landlord on a basis of social justice to both parties. Just in proportion as this inequality exists and develops will the landless class increase at the expense of profitable agriculture and wholesome rural living. It is inevitable, therefore, that the landlord cannot be permitted to do as he pleases in his contractual relations with his tenant, unless he pleases to have his land cultivated in the interest of the public good and in harmony with the social doctrine of distributive justice. The Thriftless Tenant. 2. A second cause in this category is the absence of thrift on the part of many tenant farmers. Men differ wide- ly in natural aptitudes. Some possess initiative and energy; others are phlegmatic and lazy. There is a class of tenants, and their number is relatively large, that are indifferent to advancement social, moral, or economical. This class is‘ reconciled to live with meager comforts and in a squalid en- vironment. A tenant of this class is described by Mr. Charles S. Atkins, himself a tenant of quite a different type, in con- trasting the thrifty with the thriftless tenant as follows: “Now there are two classes of those tenants. One class grows very little, for the standard of their liv- 228 Farm Tenantry in the United States ing is very low. He cares very little for the standard maintained in his household. He gets along and gives his family very little schooling advantage. I know what I am talking about because I have a neighbor to- day who has five sons, the same as I have, and out of those five sons, not one passed the third grade in school. The oldest son, who is going out to do for himself today, cannot write his own name-—and is a young man of twenty-five years old..”1 This class exists in many rural communities. In some communities the social standards that prevail are determined by this element of the rural population. The thriftless ten- ant presents the most serious problem connected with our rural situation because remedial measures are difficult to apply to members of this class. ’ Some study has been given to this aspect of the farm ten- antry problem. In a study made in several rich counties of North Texas in 1916 by F. B. Clark, Professor of Economics in the Agricultural and Mechanical College of Texas, it is found that not one tenant failed to express a desire to own a home, but when asked what he thought of the tenant's chance of ultimately owning a home in his section, his answer clearly indicated that few expected to become homeowners. In estimating the percentage of tenants who would ultimately, acquire homes under conditions existing then and for that im- mediate" section, the estimate ranged from three per cent. to ten per cent. The concensus of opinion was that the percent- age of tenants who acquired homes would continue to decrease from year to year under existing conditions. In this particular investigation, there were some tenants who thought conditions were all right and contended that a thrifty tenant could ulti- mately acquire a farm. But by far the predominating senti- ment was that there are serious obstacles, not only in the way of thrifty tenants becoming land owners, but that these difii- culties are of such a nature as to discourage thrift among the tenants. A summary of these obstacles as given in the un- published report of Professor Clark is as follows: (1) “Many tenants were thoroughly discouraged about IThe proceedings of the National Conference on Marketing and Farm Credits, held at Chicago from November 29 to December 2, 1915, page 433. Social Factors Contributing to Farm Tenantry 229 home ownership because of the high price of land. The opin- ion was ‘almost unanimously expressed that if a man had to pay the prices charged for the land from the yield of the soil it could not be done. The estimate, both by landlord and tenant-and, in fact, some to whose benefit the high price land accrued—agreed that in most places the land values were twice too high. But their statements were qualified by tho assertion that if the prices of farm products remained where they were now (1916) the price of land is not too high} But everybody appreciated the fact that this was an abnormal year. Coupled with the high price of land is the fact that much land is held in large estates and is not available at any price. On these estates are found the very worst conditions. One farmer pointed across the road to an immense estate of a thousand acres or more and said: ‘The owner of that land, although in other respects a good man, is a curse to the com~ munity. The nature of his tenants is reacted upon by their living conditions and the result is we have no respectable c neighbors.’ (2) “The second observation that is very common was that the landlord made such great exactions upon his tenants as to discourage thrift and profitable agriculture. It was believed by the tenants in that section that there were some landlords who do not make unfair exactions, but it was tho opinion that these are in the very small minority. Some of the exactions that were complained of are as follows: “The refusal of the landlord to pay for necessary improve- ments under a share-renting system. This has two aspects. In the first place, no encouragement is held out to the tenant to make the home he occupies more comfortable; in the sec~ 0nd place, the tenant is practically required to terrace and ditch his land without any kind of recompense. The tenants complained also that they were required by the landlord to sell the cotton that they produced, at a time when the price was low, to the landlord, who reaped the benefit of a rise in prices. On the rich black land farms the tenant complained that he was denied a garden plot for the raising of vegetables for family use. In some instances the tenant was refused lFarm land in the section referred to ranges from about $50 per acre in the sandy sec- , tions to approximately $200 per acre on the black land areas. 230 Farm Tenantry in the United States permission to own any live stock of any kind. These exactions usually were made only in case of the so-called share-crop- pers, but even those working under the system of third and fourth basis, were sometimes not allowed garden plots and other concessions. Complaint was also made that strict sup- ervision of the tenant’s planting was a discouragement to initi- ative and thrift. The tenant was compelled to plant exactly what the landlord-required and work it according to his direc- tions. Although this is the natural result of the share sys- tem of farm tenantry, which really makes the tenant farmer a hired man depending on a share of the crop for his wage, nevertheless, it has a tendency to reduce the tenant to a state of servility.” The whole effect of this situation, according to Professor Clark’s observation, was to deaden the initiative of the tenant and completely discourage him in any aspirations for home ownership. _ 3. The third factor in the incidental cause of farm tenantry may be designated as unforseen misfortune. The “hard luck” story is often heard by the investigator in this field. There is no justification for disparaging the influence of ill health, for example, as a factor in this situation. A few definite studies have been made on the subject of rural health. “It is commonly supposed”, says Ogden, “that good health is the invariable accompaniment of country life; that children who are brought up in the country are always rosy-cheeked, chubby, and, except for occasional colds, free from disease; that adults, both men and women, are strong to labor, like the oxen of the Psalmist, and that grandfathers and grand- mothers are so common and so able-bodied that in practically every farmhouse the daily chores are assigned to these aged exponents of strong constitutions and healthy lives. If, hovr- ever, we are honest in our observations, or have lived on a farm in our younger days, or have our eyes open when visiting in the country, we will remember, one by one, certain facts which will persistently suggest that, after all, life on the farm may not be such a spring of health as we have been led to be- lieve. We will remember the frequency of funerals. especi- ally in the winter, and the few families in which all the child- ren have reached maturity. We will remember the worn-out bodies of men and women, bent and aged while yet in middle life.”1 lOgdexfs Rural Hygiene, page 1. Social Factors Contributing to Farm Tenantry 231 During the summer of 1915, the» New York State Department of Health made a survey of health condi- tions in five townships and two villages of Albany county. The area surveyed was classified as (1) the remote rural, and (2) the accessible rural. In the remote rural districts data were received from 5,187 families or 91.2 per cent. of the total pop- ulation. In the accessible districts 11,372 families were re- corded, or 93.6 per cent. of the population. The following tabulation shows the comparison of health conditions in the two districts: Health Conditions, New York State} l Remote l Accessible l Num. l Pct. l Num. l Pct. Persons admitted to be ill . . . . . . . . . . . . 582 11.2 l 660 5.8 Number in bed or in hospital . . . . . . . . . 32 5.5 48 7.0 Number under medical care . . . . . . . . . . 168 l 196 . Number ill with preventable disease or l curable with early treatment . . . . . . . 460 79.0 l 544 l 82.4 Number whose illness was preventable l l or curable who did not have medical l l treatment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 297 51.0 | 391 59.2 Number persons ill with preventable or l l curable illness who have been ill for l l years . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . l 329 49.8 Dr. Paul L. Vogt in commenting on this particular survey says: “The fact that almost twice as large a proportion of those living in the remote districts were ill as those living the more accessible sections, indicates in the words of the Report, that ‘the more remote the rural district, and the greater the difliculty of access, the greater is the need of disseminating knowledge of measures for preserving health’ ”Z The causes of the relative amount of illness in the remote districts are well known, and they have been carefully de- scribed by authors dealing with various aspects of the rural problem? While the data based upon actual studies are inade- quate, it may be assumed that, relatively speaking, the con- *Vogt's Introduction to Rural Sociology, page 156. 2V0gt’s Op. Cit., page 156. SSee Gillett’s Constructive Rural Sociology, Chapter 2; Vogt’s Op. Cit., Chapter 8; Og- den’s Rural Hygiene. 232 Farm Tenantry in the United States clusions reached as a result of the survey made in Albany County, New York, are typical of conditions in many parts of the country. It is certainly true in the South that illness has been more prevalent in the open country than in towns and cities located in the same sections. As farm tenantry is also more generally restricted to the remote rural sections, it is the natural consequence that the largest part of the illness falls upon the tenant class. The expense of doctors’ bills and medicine, "there- fore, has been an important factor in the tenantry prob- lem. This kind of misfortune has fallen with a heavy hand upon many struggling farm tenants whose aspirations for ownership of the land they cultivated were destroyed by un- expected and continuous illness, as a result of causes that they could not understand, that involved them in obligations that they could not meet; and slowly but surely the own- ership of a home became an impossibility. The tenant’s labor income is normally a subsistence wage, and any unforeseen expenditure drives him into debt. The significance of these conditions can be appreciated only by those who have come into intimate contact with rural com- munity life. But the evidence is abundant that in a large num- ber of cases farm ownership has been made possible through financial hardships resulting from illness. We have come to regard certain diseases as essentially rural. The most important of these are pellagra, malaria, typhoid, and hook worm. The causes of some of there dis- eases are not well known. Pellagra has usually been regard.- ed as a result of malnutrition; hook worm is probably trace- able to unsanitary conditions existing about the farmstead ; malaria has prevailed widely in the plantation sections of the river valleys which have not been sufficiently drained to safe- guard the farm home from the infestation of the mosquito. While the causes of malaria are now well known to scientists and the intelligent element of our population, many farmers are totally ignorant of these causes, and even where the facts are known, in many cases, houses are not screened and sanitary conveniences are not applied because of poverty. Pellagra and Social Factors Contributing to Farm Tenantry 233 hook worm have prevailed throughout many sections of the South. In fact, it is a matter of Widespread recognition that all of these diseases are most prevalent in those sections Where farm tenantry is the commonly accepted method of land cul- tivation. In some of the sections where these diseases are most prevalent, farm tenantry is abnormally high, in some cases, averaging as much as 97 per cent. of the farm popula- tion. It is easy to see the effects of these rural diseases upon the great plantation systems in the river valleys and among the negro farming sections of the South. The labor income is affected by this situation in three de- finite Ways: (1) In the first place, the cost of professional medical attention and drugs is a serious drain upon the labor income. (2, In the second place, the loss of time, due to ill- ness, from actual labor on the farm is often an important fac- tor in reducing production. This is especially noticeable Where the farm enterprise is carried on by _a large family, all, or most of Whom, engage in labor on the farm. (3) In the third place, is is a Well known fact that pellagra and hook worm, especially, tend to reduce vitality and thereby destroy the energy necessary for persistent effort. No adequate ap- praisal has been made, or perhaps it is not possibly to make an accurate estimate of the influences of the common diseases so prevalent in the rural sections of the South, of the loss in eco- nomic returns as a result of preventable diseases. But it needs only to be referred to, to impress those familiar with the situation with the great influence that illness has had .in creating a real tenantry problem. There are other causes, such as accidents and other kindsof misfortune, that have played a part in creating this problem, but they are perhaps negligible in comparison with illness. Ignorance as a Factor in Farm Tenantry. 4. The influence of ignorance is a contributing cause of farm tenantry. This fact is also well known to the student of rural problems. It has a more or less direct bearing upon all other influences that act and interact upon this situation. 234 Farm Tenantry in the United States The first impression that the investigator gets when he comes in contact with the problem of farm tenantry, is that the great masses of tenant farmers are woefully ignorant—ignorant of their legal rights; ignorant of their possibilities; ignorant of their social and political responsibilities. An editorial in the Progressive Farmer on “More Agricultural Knowledge Need- ed by Both Landlord and Tenants,” sets forth in a very interest- ing manner, the influence of the farm tenantry situation. After referring to the seriousness of the situation, the editorial pro- ceeds as follows: “It is probable that any material change in our present tenant system will come slowly, and until ten- ants become more intelligent a high type of tenant agri- culture seems impossible. The ignorant negro tenant, Whether he pays a cash rental per acre or is a share- cropper, will not do good farming, unless an intelligent landlord maintains a close and direct supervision of his operations. This, the average landlord is not able nor willing to do; hence, there is not much prospect of im- provement in our tenant farming. Any great improve- ment is impossible until the tenant becomes sufficiently intelligent to do better farming, or until the owner is able and willing to introduce and maintain a satis- factory system of farming and to give such supervision of it as may be necessary. “Our tenants are largely ignorant negroes, but there is no good to come from denying the undoubted fact that our landlords are about as deficient as land- lords as are the tenants. Most landlords are not will- ing to provide the buildings, fences, etc., necessary for good farming, and knowing the inability of the aver- age negro tenant to pay rent with any other crop than cotton, the landlord is naturally unwilling to encourage any other kind of farming.“ The writer of this editorial is not mistaken about the in- fluence of ignorance on the whole farm tenantry situation. While he is thinking primarily of conditions in the South, his editorial has a much wider application. Throughout the na- tion, ignorance is retarding the movement for farm ownership. All the agencies now engaged in the task of rural education— agricultural colleges, the U. S. Department of Agriculture, lProgressive Farmer, Volume 39, No. 32, page 1025, for September 9, 1916. Social Factors Contributing to Farm Tenantry 235 agricultural experiment stations, agricultural extension activ- ities, agricultural high schools fostered by the states, or by the states through Federal aid, and farmers’ organizations of an educational nature—have not yet suceeded in overcoming the widespread ignorance throughout the rural sections. There are many farmers in every section who are ignorant of the use of farm machinery, and the best construction and arrangement of farm buildings. They are often ignorant of labor saving devices about the farmstead, and they have little understanding of the importance of sanitary devices and their influence upon health. All of these considerations lie at the basis of better economic and living conditions. The passion for home ownership is largely determined by an intelligent comprehension of What is involved in good farming, comfor- table homes, and attractive environment. “The more one con- siders the whole question”, says President Henry Smith Pritchett, “the more fully one is persuaded that the problem of teaching the boy on the farm, training him into a successful agent for a new scientific business of farming and making him a factor in the conservation of resources, is inextricably con- nected with the larger problem of the betterment of social and economic conditions of rural life.”1 A Ignorance is not a measurable quality. Its influence on production cannot be determined directly by statistical meth- ods, but its social significance is well understood and its extent is fairly Well determined in this country. Its significance as a contributing cause to the problems of rural life must be con- sidered in any program of social betterment that may be de- vised for rural conditions. Individualism as a Factor in Farm Tenantry. 5. Failure to provide and to promote agencies of coop- eration has contributed to farm tenantry as well as to other problems of rural life. There is really no system of farm tenantry in the United States that encourages the organiza- tion of farm tenants for co-operative enterprises. In fact, lFourth Annual Report of the Carnegie Foundation for the Advancement of Teach- ing, page 106. 236 Farm Tenantry in the United States under many systems of farm tenantry in practice in this couir- try, there is discouragement of any kind of co-operative effort. Some of the systems that are practiced make organization for co-operative purposes impossible. It is doubtful if the landlord, as a rule, encourages such a movement among tenants. The tenant himself is responsible in a large measure for the individualism that he practices. The shifting of tenants from one community to another makes organization difficult. The uncertainty of his tenure causes the tenant to feel that it is useless to spend his energies in organizing for specific purposes. The short-term lease and the uncertanty of contin- uance on the same farm for more than a year has caused the tenant to assume an indifferent attitude toward all co-opera- tive efforts to organize with his neighbor for mutual economic and social purposes. He simply feels that even to attempt it would be wasteful and unprofitable. But whatever the cause, the failure of the tenant to or- ganize has decreased his ability to purchase a farm and con- tributed to his indifference to the benefits of home ownership. Clarence Poel has well summarized the benefits of rural co- operation. Rural organization offers opportunities for co- operative buying, production, joint ownership of agricutural manufacturing enterprises, marketing, and finance. Dr. Poe discusses the social and economic importance of these as a means of increasing the farmer’s labor income and contribut- ing to his contentment. The influence of rural co-operation in Ireland, in England, and in Denmark is well known to the student of rural problems. The specialist in rural organization tells us that home ownership is an essential factor in rural organization. Home ownership does make co-operation easier, for the reasons that have been referred to . But what about the reverse of this situation? Can co-operation be secured as a stimulus to home ownership? There is obviously a reciprocal relationship b0- tween these two aspects of the situation. The permanence of tenure is the essential factor contributing to rural organiza- tion. If this could be secured, home ownership would come largely through the influences of rural organization. Isola- tion and individualism are the usual reasons assigned for the farmers’ failure to organize for co-operative purposes.’ But 1-1-1-010 Farmers Co-operate and Double Profits, pages 7 to 17. 2See Butterfield's Chapters in Rural ProgresmChapter 1. Social Factors Contributing to Farm Tenantry 237 the problem involves other elements. It might be possible to overcome partially these influences and still fail to secure co- operative efforts under our present system of tenant farming. It is not contended in this discussion that all farmers, in- cluding tenant farmers, are handicapped by the factors discussed above. It is well known that there are many tenant farmers, as well as others, who possess adequate intelligence to carry on the enterprises of the farm with skill and success. But no one would contend that there are not large numbers of farm- ers, largely the tenant class, to whom this description will apply. The significance of these five factors upon farm tenantry lies at the basis of the specific causes that will be discussed in the next four chapters. These subsequent discussions would hardly be intelligible without the recognition of the influences that have been described in the present chapter. CHAPTER XIX. THE INFLUENCE OF IMMIGRATION ON FARM TENANTRY. The status of the immigrant races is an important factor in the study of farm tenantry. At a time in our history When probably important modifications is contemplated in government- al policies with reference to immigration, it is well to consider the influences of immigration upon the important problem of ag- ricultural production, especially with reference to the land tenure aspect of it. The value of the immigrant to the country as a producing agent depends upon three considerations. (1) The distribution of immigrants throughout the agricultural sections; (2) the degree of skill and scientific knowledge possessed by them; and, (3) their status with reference to the ownership of land. The inter-relation of these questions makes it necessary to dis- cuss each of them with reference to the others. The question of the distrbution of immigrants was neg- lected for a long time, but attention is being given to the problem which has resulted from the segregation of foreigners in the crowded quarters of the large cities and the failure of the social workers to make much headway in assimulating the alien popu- lation under these conditions. The Commissioner of Immigration in his report for 1908, in discussing the labor situation, called attention to the condi- tion in the cities as “the congested places in the industrial body which checked the free circulation of labor.” In a later report, however, he expressed the opinion that the aliens were becoming better distributed than in earlier periods. But as the conditions were still very unsatisfactory, the Immigration Act of 1907 included a section providing for the establishment of a division for information. In the report of the Commiss- ioner General on Immigration in 1908, he interprets this pro- vision as follows: “It is first to bring about a distribution of immigrants arriving in this country, thus preventing, as far as possible, the congestion in our larger Atlantic seaport cities that have attracted the immigration of recent years; and sec-- 0nd, to supply information to all of our workers, whether na- 238 The Influence 0f Int-migration on Farm Tenantry 239 tive, foreign born, or alien, so that they may be constantly ad- vised in respect “to every part of this country as to What kind of labor may be in demand, the conditions surrounding it, the rate of wages, and the cost of living in the respective local- ities.”1 While according to this construction of the law. natives as well as foreigners are included, yet the work of the division has been largely directed toward sending unemployed aliens into the farm districts. The results accomplished have been of doubtful value. Several defects in the plan are obvious. In the first place, the distribution of the slum population of cities through- out the rural sections will not accomplish its purpose as an agency of production unless some preliminary opportunity is given to teach these immigrants something about American methods of agriculture. This is especially true of our foreign population coming from Southern Europe, Who are not pre- pared by previous training or possessed of temperamental qual- ities that will enable them to pursue agriculture with profit. In the second place, to transplant a slum population from the city tenaments to a rural district would merely cause the establish- ment of rural colonies of foreigners, and nothing would be gained in the Way of political or social advantages for the country as a whole. The skill and knowledge of the agricultural elements of our foreign population depend entirely on the vocations fol- lowed before they came to this country. The problem of wise distribution, therefore, of our alien population depends upon adequate information concerning the conditions and vo- cations of these people previous to their immigration to America. The older immigrant race groups came largely from Northern Europe. They included the Germans, Norwegians, Swedes, and Danes, all of whom came from the rural sections of their respective countries and immediately established ag- ricultural colonies in this country. In most cases they were more skilled in agricultural knowledge and experience than the na- tive Americans around them. They acquired large land hold- ings and became very successful and prosperous farmers. lReport of 1908, page 223. 240 Farm Tenantry in the United States This has not been true of the recent immigrants who have come in large numbers from southeastern- and southern Europe. They are unskilled and untrained in agricultural pursuits, and they have not as yet demonstrated their ability as producers, althou-gh they have formed many agricultural colonies and are gradually acquiring modern agricultural infor- mation. The Immigration Commission investigated recently nearly every important settlement of immigrant groups that have settled East of the Mississippi River. Studies were made also of immigrant agricultural groups in Texas, Arkansas, and Southern Missouri. The investigation included Poles, Slovaks, Bohemians, northern and southern Italians, Portugese, and a few other less significant groups, such as German, Swiss, and the Japa- nese. For purposes of this investigation immigrant groups were divided into two classes. First, those who were more or less permanently identified with the land as farmers, and sec- ond; seasonal farm laborers, who drifted from the cities to this or that section to assist in harvesting some particular crop. It is interesting to observe that while nearly two-thirds of the Italians from southern Italy and approximatelyone- fourth from northern Italy were farmers in their native land, a very limited number of them are following agriculture in this country. As the Italians have constituted a large per cent. of immigration since 1900, it is obvious that agricultural development has not been stimulated to any large degree by recent immigration. However, there are large farming coni- munities of Italians in Alabama, Louisiana, Mississippi, North Carolina, Tennessee, Arkansas, and Texas. The largest agri- cultural colony in the South, numbering approximately two thousand persons, is at Bryan, Texas. At Sunnyside, Arkansas, there is also an unusually large Italian farm community. As a rule, the Italian is thrifty and saves his money. He begins as a farm laborer, but as rapidly as possible climbs the agricul- tural ladder, soon becoming a tenant farmer and later on acquiring ownership of the land he cultivates. We are told by Jinks and Lauck that “at Sunnyside, the immigrants gener- ally rent farms, while at Knobview and Tontitown, Arkansas, it is their ambition to be independent land owners. As 1n The Influence of Immigration on Farm Tenantry 241 other parts of the country, the Italians in the South have small farms, requiring little capital and little outlay for machinery.“ The Poles have not contributed a substantial element to agriculture. The Immigration Commission, in their investiga- tion, found settlements of them in the undeveloped farm reg- ions of the West, assisting the owners in the settlements of large tracts, and on the abandoned farms in certain sections of the East, notably in the Connecticut valley. “Up the Connecti- cut river valley of New England”, says Archibald McClure, “there recently have appeared thousands of Polish farmers, reclaiming the land left by the old Puritan stock, who have sought easier fields of agricultural conquest farther West. Good farmers-as they are, these Polish peasants seem able to make a living in the Long Island truck farms; or in the warm climate of Texas, where, with the Bohemians, they have set- tled down in large numbers; or out in the newly claimed‘ lands of Washington, where they have many prosperous-looking ten- acre tracts.” Their love for the ownership of property has rapidly transformed them from seasonal laborers into farm owners. They have readily adapted themselves to specialized types of agriculture in different sections of the country. For example, they have been very successful in potato culture in Porage County, Wisconsin, and in cotton farming in Texas. They have also been successful in raising onions and tobacco in the East. Their success as farmers cannot be determined by the extent to which they have become home owners. In the Connecticut valley, they are mostly tenants because the high price of land has made it impossible for them to purchase their own homes. There are still many Polish tenants in cer- tain section of Texas, where land values are relatively high and where the producing crop, usually cotton, has not been suffi- ciently remunerative in the past to enable them to buy land. But in Illinois and Indiana, where land is high but the crops produced have yielded a relatively high price, they have rapid- ly been transformed from renters to owners. Like the Bohemians, the Slovaks have entered upon farm- ing as a vocation in various parts of the country, including Vir- ginia, Texas, and Arkansas. The Slovaks come from Hungary lThe Immigration Problem, page 86. ZLeadership of the New America, page 69. 242 Flarm Tenantry in the United States and, like many of their people, they were peasant farmers at home. According to the 1910 census, there were about 285,000 of these people in the United States. The Slovaks, unlike the Bohemians, are largely illiterate and are less skilled in farm- ing than the Bohemians. However, as they are naturally a farming people, they are adapting themselves to farm condi- tions in this country. At Slovaktown, near Stuttgart, in Ar- kansas, there is a colony of fifty or sixty farm families. The colony is about fifteen years old, but it has grown very little in recent years. The comparatively small number of Slovak farmers creates no economic rural problem, and they have ex- erted no influence on the tenantry problem in the sections where they have located. Bohemian immigration has contributed a rather substan- tial el-ement to the farming population of the United States. There are between 500,000 and 700,000 of these people in the United States, and about one-third of them are engaged in agricultural pursuits. They have settled in Nebraska, Iowa, Wisconsin, and Texas. A colony of Bohemians settled in Fay- ette County, Texas, previously to the Civil War. McLennan County, Texas, has a colony of more than four hundred fam- ilies. Almost one-half of the farming population of Kewau- nee County, Wisconsin, was Boehmian in 1890, while in cer- tain sections of Nebraska the Bohemians shared about equally with the Scandinavians in directing all the farm operations. Most of the Bohemian farmers in Texas are located in the cot- ton growing sections of the state, but they were quick to diver- sify their crop production sufficiently to meet their own food and feed requirements. In every section they rapidly be- came farm owners. They have met most difficulty in con- necticut, where, having bought old homesteads, and- lack ing scientific knowledge, they have not been able to made the most out of the worn out soil. But the Bohemian farmer may be ignored as a factor in the farm tenantry problem in the United States, for he rapidly climbs the agricultural lad- der to farm ownership, and his farm soon becomes a model for his neighbors. _ The three-most prominent elements in recent immigra- tion are the Italians, Poles, and Jews, but the latter have not The Influence of Immigration on Farm Tenantry 243 l contributed materially to agricultural pursuits. The report of the Jewish Agricultural and Industrial Aid Society of New York, is authority for the statement that in 1909 there were approximately 3,040 Hebrew farmers in thirty-six states. Three-fourths of this number were located in New York, New Jersey, and various parts of New England. Jewish farmers are not numerically important in any other section of the Unit- ed States, except in North Dakota. Great efforts are being made through social organiza- tions to assist the Jewish immigrants who come to this coun- try. The Baron de Hirsch Fund, which was incorporated in 1891, is designed to encourage Jewish agriculture. Archibald McClure is authority for the statement that “More than two million dollars has been loaned to 3,151 farmers by the Jewish Agricultural and Industrial Aid Society in its work of promot- ing agricultural colonies in the United States.“ Many of the farm colonies established through social effort have failed, the exceptions being the colonies in New Jersey. It seems now to be permanently established and reasonably successful. Jenks and Lauck commenting on the Hebrew as a farmer make this observation: “The Hebrew is not adapted by training or tra- dition to be a pioneer farmer and in general his attempts at agriculture are unsatisfactory. The crops, tillage, the qual- ity and quantity of produce are not as satisfactory as in most colonies of other races. The farm income is not large. The largest gross income noted was in the tobacco farms of the colony at Ellington, Connecticut, which has been established only a few years. The largest net incomes are probably de- rived from the Vineland, New Jersey, farms. The difficulty in making Hebrew farm colonies succeed has been recognized by the Jewish Agricultural and Industrial Aid Society, which has now established an experimental farm on Long Island for future rural colonists. To succeed, Jewish farmers must have some capital and improved land. They must settle in groups large enough to maintain a synagogue. Those most apt to suc- ceed have been either farmers abroad or experienced in this country before becoming permanent farmers. Country life, however, has benefited the individual. Hebrew farmers live better than Poles or Italians of the same length of residence lLeadev-ship of the New America, page 169. 244 Farm Tenantry in the United States here. They show, also, a greater desire for comforts. They become citizens sooner than most races from Southeastern Europe, and take a more intelligent interest in politics and civic questions. In many districts they have demanded bet- ter schools. Assimilation is retarded by religious traditions and rural segregation, but the Hebrew landowners are quick- ly Americanized, and soon appreciate representative govern- ment, democratic institutions, and an educated electorate. There was no colony investigated by the Immigration Commis- sion whose members voted less as a unit than those where rural Hebrews formed a large part of the electorate?" It is obvious from this discussion that the Jewish farmer has not become a social problem in rural communities. It is likely that his importance will increase, due to the agencies that are promoting Jewish agriculture, but perhaps the phil- anthropic efforts that will accompany these social efforts will prevent the Hebrew farmer from ever becoming a rural economic ’ problem. The largest farm element in our foreign population has come from Germany. According to the 1910 census, there were 221,800 German farmers in this country. “No other for- eign element,” according to Ross, “is so generally distributed over the United States as the Germans.” Their skill, industry, and thrift have made them also uniformly successful, not only in agriculture but in the other pursuits which they have fol- lowed. They have brought with them their traditional love for home ownership and willingness to settle down and de- velop the land they occupy. No where in the United States has farm tenantry become a problem where Germans cul- tivate the soil. Professor Ross has admirably characterized the German farmer in the following statement: “Thanks partly to good farming and frugal living, and partly to the un-American practice of working their women in the fields, the German farmers made money, bought choice acres from under their neighbor’s feet, and so kept other nationalities on the move. This is the reason why a German settles on fat soil and why in time the best land in the region is likely to come into German hands. Unlike the restless American, 11l‘he Immigration Problem, page 91. 2The Old World in the New, page 47. The Influence of Immigration on Farm Tenantry 245 with his ears ever pricked to hail of distant opportunity, tne phlegmatic German identifies himself with his farm, and feels a pride in keeping it in the family generation after gen- eration. Taking fewer chances in the lottery of life than his enterprising Scotch-Irish or limber-minded Yankee neigh- bor, he has drawn from it fewer big prizes, but also fewer blanks.“ ' An entirely different type of immigrant is that represent- ed by the Chinese and the Japanese. Numerous problems have grown out of the immigration of these oriental people to the United States. It is well to note two points of general interest with reference to Chinese immigration. (1) In the first place, the number of Chinese in the country and the number that are being admitted are gradually on the decline. Between 1890 and 1910, the number of Chinese in the United States decreased from over one hundred thousand to seventy-one thousand five hundred and thirty-one. Four thousand Chi- nese immigrants was the maximum number admitted to this country in any one year of the nineteenth century. (2) In the second place, the Chinese immingrants are largely localized --the large majority being in California and other Pacific Coast states. The Chinese have been very successful in certain types of farming. Truck farming has been developed to a high degree by them in Southern California, but the number of Chinese farmers is gradually decreasing in this country and does not present a- problem for serious consideration. The Japanese population in the United States, which is large- ly confined to the Pacific Coast states, is slightly less than 100,000? The most conspiciuous fact about the Japanese in America is the unusually large percentage engaged in agriculture. “The most noteworthy feature,” says McClure, “about the presence of the Japanese as workers in this country, is the great proportion of their numbers engaged in farm work. Aside from the few thousands employed in the mines of Wy- oming and California, as track workers on all the great rail- roads of the far West, and in the lumber camps and mills of 1The Old World in the New, pages 52 and 53. 2See Millis’, H. A. The Japanese Problem in the United States, page 1; McClure, Archi- bald, The Leadership of the New America, page 230. 246 Farm Tenantry in the United States Washington and Oregon, those who are not in the city centres as business men, domestic servants or students are largely farmers. Of 71,299 adult males, the Japanese American for ‘1913 estimated the number of farmers and farm laborers at» 31,496—-more than twice as many as were engaged in any other line of work, and nearly one-half of the total. This gives to the Japanese a distinct characteristic, unique among most of the immigrant people of our land. They are out in the country on the farms where it is felt that it would be well if our European immigrants could also be.”1 The explantion of this fact is to be found, perhaps, in the home conditions from which most of the Japanese come. The vast majority of our Japanese immigration belong to the farming or laboring class in their native country. They come prepared to use their energy and apply their skill under new conditions. No other foreign element in our population has brought to the farms of this country so much knowledge of scientific farming. They are familiar with methods of irri- gation and possess a limited knowledge of the rotation of crops, which they readily learn to apply to farm conditions in this country. This has given the Japanese farmer an un- usual advantage over our native population in some respects. Professor H. A._Millis explains the strong tendency of the Japanese to engage in agriculture in this country as follows: “In Japan the farmer has been ranked higher than his fel- low man engaged in trade or industry. Because of the meager- ness of natural resources and the necessity of the most care- ful husbandry, the agricultural arts, in so far as labor and scientific application are concerned, have been highly de- veloped. So, here in-the adopted country, agriculture has carried with it station in life and has given opportunity for the application of the best-developed arts possessed by the race.” _The Japanese have become a rather important factor in agriculture 1n Idaho. Utah, and Colorado. in connection with the sugar beet industry. In those states, farm tenantry in con- nection with the Japanese has become a problem. In Colorado, the Japanese are almost all tenant farmers with one year leases according to Millisfi lLeadership of the New _America, page 232. ZT/te Japanese Problem m the United States, page 80. 3Ibzd, page 85. The Influence of Immigration on Farm Tenantry 247 “Most of the tenants,” says he, “now provide most of the equipment needed. Nearly all are growing crops requiring intensive cultivation and a moderate amount of irrigation. While farmers grow the same crops to a very considerable extent, though the Japanese have come to be known as the chief growers of cabbage and tomatoes for the canneries. Their land is well tilled and they are regarded as good farm- ers. Here and there several adjacent farms are tenanted by Japanese; in other cases their farms are widely scattered. In some cases the tenant has only a part of the farm, as, for example, those that are devoted to the production of beets. He then ordinarily occupies a house built for the hired help or a tenant. This is frequently, if not usually, a fairly substantial cottage . _ _ _ _ _ _ In numerous cases, however, the Japanese tenant leases an entire farm, and, if so, he ordinarily occupies the regular farm house . _ _ _ _ _ _ The Japanese families have replaced white families to a certain extent.”1 This condition of tenant farming is probably typical of the other states in that immediate section where beet sugar and vegetable farm- ing are predominant. Tenant farming among the Japanese is an important factor in the agricultural situation in Washington. In 1910, according to the census figures, 316 farms of 9.412 acres were leased by the Japanese? Professor Millis is responsible for the statement that in 1913 the number of farms leased was about 560, the acreage having increased to 16,000 or 17,0OO.3 It seems that Japanese own no land in the state of Washing- ton. This is explained by the fact that there is a clause in the state constitution which prevents aliens from acquiring land ownership unless they have certified to their intention to be- come citizens of the United States. The Japanese constitute a very substantial element of the farmers in California. A bulletin issued in 1914 by the cen- sus bureau‘ is authority for the statement that of a total of 2,502 farms, comprising 147,259 acres in the state of California, the Japanese controlled in 1910, 1,816 of these farms, embrac- ing 99,254 acres. In other words, approximately 73 per cent. 1The Japanese Problem in the United States, page 85. 2Census Bulletin 127, page 44. 3The Japanese Problem in the United States, page 89. 4Bulletin 127. 248 Farm Tenantry in the United States of the farmers and 63 per cent. of the farm lands are controll- ed and operated by Japanese either as owners or tenants. In- Lenswe agriculture is the type of farming mostly practiced by Japanese in California. Their agricultural activities are largely devoted to the growing of vegetables, including potatoes and sugar beets, and such fruits as berries and grapes. Most of the farms held by Japanese are small—many of them containing less than five acres. The average size of the 1,816 Japanese farms reported by the census was only 54.7 acres} The branches of agri- culture followed by the Japanese in California involve tedious processes and much individual hand work. The tendency of the white man to avoid this kind of agricultural production has given the Japanese almost a monopoly in the culture of most of these crops. The Japanese have been important factors in the land tenure problem in California. The land tends to pass into the pos- session of those best ‘qualified by temperament and previous experience to meet the labor need of that type of production. It has been easy for the Japanese to pass from farm laborers to share tenancy where the land owners supplied teams and equipment. Cash tenancy, however, has gone along parallel t0 share tenancy in certain Japanese communities in Cali- fornia. “Most of the tenant farming,” says Millis, “by Jap- anese in the localities specializing in the growing of grapes and deciduous fruits has grown out of the fact that the Jap- anese work under a ‘boss’ and occupy a dominant place in the labor supply required for taking care of crops. As some leased their land and secured an advantage in the labor mar- ket, there was the more reason for others to do so.” As the Japanese ire-directed the agricultural production of California into intensive farming and developed a new type of crop production, the unit area of production increased and the tenant was able to pay high rents. Under this process, the owner found it more profitable to lease his land than to farm it himself. This situation is clearly explained by Pro- fessor Millis as follows: “That they could afford» to pay rela- tively high rents is explained, in part, where a new type of farming was introduced by the Japanese, by the fact that their 1M‘llis’ Th J P bl ' h ' zlblid’ pagee lfipanses r0 em m t e Umted States, page 137._ The Influence of Immigration on Farm Tenantry 249 crops would bear a higher rent than those which had been grown. When land worth a few dollars per acre for growing hay is turned to the production of strawberries, it may be worth $20.00, $25.00 or even $30.00 per acre. If turned to the production of beans or potatoes, or other vegetables, it is worth more to the tenant that when used for the production of general crops. But the relatively high rents paid are not to be explained entirely in this way. Five years ago the writer was ‘present when a young American sought to lease a ranch from an agent at Stockton. It was wanted for growing potatoes. He first offered to pay $10.00 and finally $12.00 per acre, one half down, the remainder when the crop was harvested, but his offer was declined because a Japanese had already offered $15.00, a Chinese $16.00 for it for growing the same crop. _ _ _ _ _ _ _ Instances came to my attention along the Lower Sacramento where Japanese had replaced Italians as tenants by giving a larger share of their crop. Similar instances were found in some other places. With time, the difference in rents would-be tenants are willing to pay have diminished, but it has not yet disappeared. It obtains to some extent about Fresno, for example, in the leasing of producing vineyards. Of course other considerations than the share of the crop by the Jewish Agricultural and Industrial Aid Society, which enter into a share lease but in genera-l it may be said that there in 1914 the general rule was for the Japanese tenant to ‘take forty and give sixty’ per cent., while other tenants and landowners ‘shared alike.’ That the Japanese have been will- ing to pay relatively high rents for agricultural land has, how- ever, never been in dispute, so that further detail need not be added. Some regard it as meritorious, others as objectionable. Other things being equal, it is well to have land devoted to those crops which will bear the highest rent. The points we are interested in here, however, is that the strongest competitor for land is the one who will pay the highest rent.”1 Three questions arise with reference to the Japanese as a tenant farmer in California. (1) What influences has he had upon land and production? (2) What has been the irr- fluences upon the landlord? (3) Has the system worked out to the interest of the Japanese farmers themselves? There lMillis’ The Japanses Problem in the United States, page 141. 250 ‘ Farm Tenantry in the United States is no doubt that the Japanese farmer has proved to be a great asset in agricultural production in California. His methods of intensive cultivation and his influence on diversifed farm- ing has greatly increased the agricultural and horticultural production. The complaint that the Japanese rob the land of fertility has some justification, but the nature of the agricul- tural production compels some attention to soil improvement, and for that reason the Japanese tenant has not “skinned” the land as some would have us believe. The general opinion is that the Japanese haveshown more interest than is usualiv found among tenants in the care of the farmstead and the conservation of soil properties. As under all other conditions of tenant farming, absentee landlordism has grown out of the Japanese tenant situation in California. The high rents that the Japanese have been willing to pay have enhanced land values, and the owners in many instances have moved to the near-by towns and cities. But it is rather interesting to observe that the number of tenants in California in 1910 was 20.6 per cent., while in 1900 it was 23.1 per cent. This is in contrast with the conditions in the United States as a whole, the percentage of tenants having increased from 35.3 in 1900 to 37 per cent. in 1910. It ought to be said, perhaps, that absentee. landlordism has not been so serious a problem in California as in some other sec- tions of the country. In many cases the land owners continue to live with their families on the farms, all, or a part, of which they have leased to Japanese. The most serious social effect is to be observed on the other side of the question. In com- munities where Japanese farmers have settled, relatively few white persons are settling. This has greatly retarded the development of a small land-holding class, and, of course, tends to perpetuate tenancy. Little consideration has been given to the influences of rent prices on the Japanese themselves for obvious reasons. There is no doubt that landlords in some cases have exacted too much rent from the Japanese. This is the inevitable consequence of land competition and profitable agriculture. This much may be said, however, in justification of the system from the Jap- anese standpoint, they are as a rule, living under better con- The Influence of Immigration on Farm Tenantry 251 ditions and enjoying more comforts than they experienced in j their native country. They have been able to farm without Timuch capital and probably in no other vocation could they “have succeeded as unskilled laborers so well as they have as tenant farmers. In other words, it would appear that the Jap- ganese tenant farm situation in California is not to be con- demned on the grounds that it has created in itself a serious social situation. There is no indication that Japanese tenants ’ill advance to land ownership in California in any large umbers, but in their present situation they will probably ‘prosper in a more substantial way than any other tenant farm felement in the country. Geographic Distribution of Farm Tenants. v A better perspective is given to the influence of immigra- i ion upon farm tenantry by indicating their distribution fhroughout the United States. The follwing tablel _taken om the Census Abstract shows this situation: i Nativity of Farm Operators: 1910. 3| This table reveals several interesting facts. (1) It will "observed that only 10.5 per cent. of the farm operators of l nation are foreign born. (2) The largest percentage of _ ract Thirteenth Census, Table 1, page 206. Per cent. of all Per cent. of Farm Oper- Per cent. of Farm Owners ators Farm Tenants‘ F’: if 5i q E "a? E "s? E a‘; .3 a g .3 w g .3 =<= g l o Qrnvdgzom 0m ‘gnu; églwm £23m é“ Z8 as “$33 as “g-EB s8 w; » Ln o h o o ‘ted States . . . . . . . . .. 75.0] 10.5 14.5 80.1 13.8 6.1 66.2 5.0 28.8 ‘w England . . . . . . . . .. 85.3 14.5 0.2 85.6 14.2 0.2 82.6 17.1 0.3 dle Atlantic . . . . . . .. 89.5 10.1 0.4 89.1 10.5 0.4 91.1 8.4 0.5 p,‘ t North Central . . . . . 82.7 16.7 0.5 79.9 19.7 0.5 90.3 9.1 0.6 ~= North Central . 74.8 24.3 0.9 70.4 28.6 1.0 84.4 14.9 0.7 nth Atlantic . . . . . . . .. 67.4 0.6 32.0 81.8 1.0 17.2 50.2 0.2 49.6 v: South Central . . . . . 68.3 0.5 31.2 87.7 0.8 11.5 49.5 0.2 50.4 g South Central . . . . . 73.4 4.4 22.2 81.0 5.9 13.1 66.6 3.1 30.4 tain . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78.5 17.1 4.4 78.0 17.2 4.8 81.7 16.7 1.7 "fic . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69.8 27.7 2.5 69.9 28.7 1.4 67.9 24.1 8.0 252 Farm Tenantry m the United States the foreign born are found in the Pacific division, where the Chi-' nese and Japanese compose the large element of the foreign popu- lation, and in the West North Central, and the East North Cen- tral divisions. (3) In the South Atlantic and East South Cen-. tral divisions the foreign-born element is negligible. According to the census of 19102, Minnesota and North Dakotahave the largest percentage of foreign farm operators, which amounts to more than one-half of the farming element . ,_ in the state. The United States census for 1910 presents an interesting i table with reference to the status of foreign-born farmers as l, to the land tenure. This table is as follows: Farm Tenure by Nativity Per cent of Per cent of Negro and Native White Foreign-Born other Non- Farm White Farm white Farm Operators Operators Operators (l! :3 l0 g 1 m g £3 *5 an fi *5 b0 i3 +5 b0 Division g g g g g g E g g Q) Q) CD o a 2 o e1 2 o a 2 United States . . . . . . . . ..‘| 66.3) 32.7 1.0? 81.4} 17.6: 1.0 26.2. 73.6! 0. New England . . . . . . . .. 89.6 7.7 2.7 87.2 9.3 3.5 79.2 15.2 5. Middle Atlantic . . . . . . ..| 75.4 22.7 1.9] 79.0 18.6 2.4 72.1 24.2 3. East North Central . . . . . 69.5 29.5 1.0‘ 84.6 14.7 0.7 68.4 30.3 1. gVest Norith Central 64.3 34.8 0.9 80.7 18.9 0.4 74.7 24.5 0. outh At antic . . . . . . . .. 64.8 34.2 1.0 84.9 11.7 3.4 28.7 71.1 0. East South Central . . . . . 62.9 36.7 0.4 81.1 17.8 1.2 18.1 81.9 0. “Vgest South Central . 51.6 47.8 0.6 62.7 36.8 0.5 27.6 72.3 0 ountain . . . . . . . . . . . .. 87.1 11.2 1.7 88.3 10.4 1.3 95.6 4.1 0 Pacific . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 80.1| 16.8 3.1! 83.1 15.0_ 1.9 43.8 54.5 1 It is interesting to observe the comparison between the native white farm operators and the foreign-born white opera- tors with reference to land tenure. It will be observed from the above table that while 66.3 per cent. of the native white Per cent of . i: Lubahwwoocoqmw a 1.1.0" w F -. '. farm operators in the United States are classified as owners, . 81.4 per cent. of the foreign-born white farmers own their own fargis. In every geographic division of the United States, with the exception of New England, the percentage of tenant- operated farms is greater for the native white than for the ZThirteenth Census, page 296. l merican Statistical Association, The Influence 0f Immigration on Farm Teuantry 253 foreign white population. Professor Gillette, commenting on this fact, says: “It Would seem that the nation need have no fear that immigrants who settle on farms will fall into tenantry. It should rather fear that native farmers be eliminated by for- eigners, though that fear may be ungroundedf" Before ac- cepting this conclusion, however, it may be desirable to study the question from the standpoint of the aggregate foreign pop- ulation engaged in agriculture. In a very careful statistical ‘i study made by Professor Gillette and Mr. George R. Davis and incorporated in an article entitled “Measures of Rural Mi- gration and Other Factors of Urban Increase ‘in the United States,” the following statistics are given: Number of Persons Engaged in Agriculture Males Females Both Sexes \ "a =1; "6 l p 45 , L‘ +§ I p 43 | cu 5 :3 w 5 w F: 5 m l ,_ e 8 a g 3 § a = B 8 a g {Q E H O-r-n ~ a H Q2 a g O-v-I <9 5 q; |—< 4a 5 q; Z ‘c; 5 Q) p-a t; Cmlntry F?‘ Z $1173 n. Z 0- w a. Z F“? c. United States 191010,582,039 35.2 1,806,584] 22.4 12,388,623 32.5 1900 9,272,315 39.0 977,336 18.4 10,249,651 35.3 1890 7,787,539 41.4 594,385 17.3 8,466,363 37.2 |1880 7,068,658 47.9 594,385 22.5 7,663,043 44.1 Volume 14, 1914-15. 254 Farm Tenantry in the United States Percentage of Total Rural and Urban Population of the United States, Classified by Nativity. Rural Urban tivit n e ra hi Na Ygiviffinfig p c 1910 1900 1890 1910 1900 1890 1 Native Parentage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . New England . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69 8 73.0 77.* 33.9 37.8 43.6 Middle Atlantic . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 0 70.6 71.3 34.4 35.8 35.8 East North Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66.4 64.9 64.3 41.7 38.8 36.8 West North Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 58.5 57.5 59.3 51.2 47.8 45.6 South Atlantic . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62.2 60.8 59.9 54.2 50.0 45.9 West South Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 7 64.4 61.4 58.4 47.4 41.7 Mountain . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57.8 52.9 50.4 51.9 47.2 47.6 Pacific . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54.8 54.8 54.6 46.9 40.6 36.8 Total, United States . . . . . . . . . . . . . .| 54.1 63.2 63.3] 41.9] 40.2 39.7 Foreign or Mixed Parentage New England . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 17.0 14.9 11.5 34.2 31.6 26.6 Middle Atlantic . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17.6 16.6 15.5 33 6 34.8 33.3 East North Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 22.4 23.0 21.3 33.0 35.8 33.2 West North Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27.4 26.7 22.6 28.2 30.4 27.5 South Atlantic . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.4 1.4 1.4 10.1 12.2 13.0 East South Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.0 1.2 1.4 9 5 13.2 14.8 West South Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.4 5.5 4.3 12.1 16.9 18.9 Mountain . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21.2 24.1 21.2 27.3 30.2 25.0 Pacific . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 22.4. 23.4 196 27.2 31.4 28.2 Total, United States . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .l 13 3 13.6 12 4 29.01 30 9 28 7 Foreign Born New England . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12.6 11.5 10.4 30.7 29.3 28.6 Middle Atlantic . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13.9 11.2 11.7 29.5 26.8 28.7 East North Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10.2 11.1 13.2 22.8 22.9 27.5 West North Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12.6 13.9 15.8 16.3 17.0 21.8 South Atlantic . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.1 0.8 0.8 6.2 6.5 8.3 East South Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 0.4 0.5 0.7 3.7 5.0 7.6 West South Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.1 3.1 3.2 7.0 8.8 12.3 Mountain . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15.7 15.9 18.6 18.3 19.9 24.0 Pacific . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18.4 16.5 18.7 22.2 23.1 28.0 Total, United States . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .| 7 51 7 5| s.7| 22 6| 22.2] 24.8 Colored : l New England . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 0.6’ 0.6 0.5 1.2 1.3 1.2 Middle Atlantic . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 1.5 1.6 1.5 2.5 2.6 2.2 East North Central’ . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.0 1.0 1.2 2.5 2.5 2.5 West North Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.5 1.9 2.3 4.3 4.8 5.1 South Atlantic . . . . . . . : . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35.3 37.0 37.9 29.5 31.3 32.8 East South Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 31.4 44.0 32.9 32.4 34.2 33.5 West South Central . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23.8 27.0 31.1 22.5 2619 27.1 Mountain . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.3 7.1 9.8 2.5 2.7 3.4 Pacific . . . ,_ . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.4 5.3 7.1 3.7 4.9 7.0 Total, United States . . . . . . . . . . . . . .] 15.1\ 15.7| 15.6\ 6.5! 6.7| 6.8 The Influence 0f Immigration 0n Farm Tenlantry 255 Changes in the Rural and Urban Population in 1910 and‘1900 Compared With 1890. (1890—1910). _ Foreign _ l Natlve or mixed Forelgn Parentage Parentage Born Colored Total l ' l Census Year and T: E "<3 ii T: E T6 a E T6 E Grand Division S 5-4 E" s-t g 5-4 § L H § s4 F11 i3 O5 i3 Di i3 Dd 1 i3 D5 i3 1 1910 7 New England . . . . . 86.7 119.0 142.4 19 . 11.6.1 164.6 11 .1 156.3 96.3 153.2 Middle Atlantic . . . . 97.8 179.9 118.2 18 . 123.7 192.0 10 . 220.4 104.1 187.1 1- West North Central. 115.5 188.5 142.3 17 . 94.0 125.4 7 . 143.0 117.2 167.8 l South Atlantic . . . . . 132.6 211.2 128.8 13 . 166.9 134.0 11 . 160.6 127.7 178.9 a East South Central . 126.0 238.0 85.0 124.4 74.2 92.7 116.0 185.8 121.8 192.6 i West South Central 197.3 382.8 211.3 174.1 164.2 155.4 129.5 228.0 169.6 173.4 6 7 8 4 8 6 9 0 _ . East North Central . 106.4 218.8 108.1 187.7 79.4 156.4 88.7 186.9 108.0 188.7 1 6 6 6 9 7 9 0 Mountain . . . . . . . . . 225.4 290.8 197.0 290.9 165.2 202.7 106.1 195.0 196.4 166.4 1 Pacific - - - - - - - - - - - 16.111 311119 llq-QEE 1.519.154 19311.57} 115i? 297-1 .Total, United States|124.3 197.8|181.s|189.5 106.4|1_Z1_.Ql1}§2{1QL5E12EYI18L6 1900 I New England . . . . . 92.7 109.0 127.5 148.8 108.6 128.4 120.8 138.8 98.5 125.5 i Middle Atlantic . . . . 99.0 137.7 107.4 143.6 96.1 127.9 108.1 163.1 100.1 137.4 gEast North Central . 105.5 149.1 112.8 152.7-~ 87.7 117.9 93.5 145.4 104.6 141.6 ’West North Central 108.2 133.8 132.4 141.0 98.7 99.5 91.1 120.0 111.7 127.6 South Atlantic . . . . 116.8 140.8 120.9 120.9 106.1 102.1]112.6|123.1|115.2 129.2 }East South Central 114.8 149.5 105.2 123.5 83.0 91.8 114.4 141.0 114.3 138.4 iwest South Central 142.8 167.9 171.7 131.4 132.3 105.8 118.0 145.8 136.0 147.7 Mountain . . . . . . . . . 138.7 151.1 150.2 183.5 113.1 126.2 94.9 121.7 132.0 152.2 "Pacific . . . . . . . . . . . 119.7 154.6|142.6 155611052 1153i 87.3 98.7 119.1 140.0 iTotal, United States. 1112.2|187.2|I22T9|146.0\ “97.8l121.1|112.8|1s4.4.112.4|185.5 Taken from American Statistical Association——Quarterly Publication. The Agricultural Element in the Population. a. A summary of the above tables shows the following: Y(1) The total number of persons engaged in agriculture has l greatly increased in the four decades since 1880, but the per- . licentage with reference to all occupations has shown a decided idecline. This is due, of course, to the fact that the number of occupations in industrial activities have multiplied greatly . hile the number choosing agriculture has increased but ittle. (2) The percentage of foreign-born farmers has in- ‘reased very slowly in the country as a whole since 1890, and A e total percentage of increase is not sufficiently great to se- "iously affect the land tenure problem. (3) The increase in I e different geographic divisions has been far from uniform. ' several of the divisions there has been actually a decline v the percentage of the rural population. 256 Farm Tenantry in the United States Conclusion. It would appear, therefore, that Professor Gillette is cor- rect in his conclusion that immigration has not intensified the problem of land tenure. There is no element in our foreign , population, with the possible exception of the Japanese, that presents any serious problem of tenantry whatever. On the whole, they seem to pass through the stages of farm laborer_ and tenantry to land ownership with reasonable rapidity, and this is almost as true of one foreign element as another, with the exception of the Chinese and Japanese, as has been shown. In different sections of the country, there is here and there a community of farmers that have met difficulties in acquiring land, but this seems to be due in all cases to the geographic and economic conditions rather than to any real racial attribute. The rural immigrant problem is due rather to the disinclina- tion of recent immigrants to settle in the open country than to their attitude toward land tenure. This is very clearly indicated in the study by Professor Gillette and Mr. Davies. This fact is rather surprising when we recall that most of these immigrants came from rural regions and were either farm. laborers or small farm owners. This will create a problem that will demand consideration in the future. But lit will be greatly simplified by the fact that the prob- lem of land tenure is not likely to accompany the re-direction of the vocational activities of the immigrant who settles in our country. a CHAPTER XX. THE NEGRO FARM TENANT. The farm tenantry situation cannot be understood With- out a knowledge of the facts connected with negro farm tenantry , in the South. The present chapter will attempt to present the available statistics and other important facts with reference to ' the extent and the influence of the negro tenant on the general ' problem of farm tenantry. The Negro on Southern Farms. Approximately 77.5 per cent. of the population of the South About 40 per cent. of all persons engaged in agricul- In Mississippi, South is rural. tural pursuits in the South are negroes. Carolina, and Louisiana, the number of negroes engaged in farm- ing is about 60 to 70 per cent. of all farmers in those states. Alabama and Georgia come next with from 53 to 56 per cent. of negro farmers in the total} The importance of the negro farmer in the South can best be appreciated by a comparison of the statistics of the number of negroes on farms in 1900 and 1910? Number of Negroes on Farms. T l i l Per cent. State 1910 1900 Increase Increase Alabama . . . . . . . . . . . . . .| 353,906 279,480 I 74,426 26.6 Arkansas . . . . . . . . . . . . . . I 177,491 117,571 59,920 51.0 Florida . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70,697 43,245 27,452 63.5 Georgia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 411,086 I 277,970 133,116 47.9 Louisiana . . . . . . . . . . . . . .| 211,873 I 189,969 21,868 11.5 Maryland . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33,551 27,193 6,358 23,4 Mississippi . . . . . . . . . . . . . 472,594 337,940 134,654 39.8 North Carolina . . . . . . . . . 226,525 160,194 66,331 41.4 Oklahoma . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34,259 30,402 3,857 12.7 South Carolina . . . . . . . . . 351,927 267,326 84,601 31.6 Tennessee . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109,848 90,337 19,511 21.6 Texas . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 217,930 145,555 72,375 49.7 Virginia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 127,730 103,521 24,209 23.4 West Virginia . . . . . . . . . . 2,450 2,116 334 15.8 While Florida, Arkansas, Texas, Georgia, North Carolina, and Mississippi show the largest increase in the number of ne- 1Bulletin No. 33 (1916), Bureau of Education, Department of Interior, on Negro Educa- tion, Volume 1, Chapter 7, page 98 2Ibid. 257 258 Farm Tenantry in the United States gro farmers during -the ten-year period, there was a substanti increase in all the Southern states. The statistics show that =-» number of negro farmers during that period increased =§_ rapidly than the number of white farmers in all the states ex '- cept Louisiana, Virginia, and Alabama. i. A study of the occupation tables of the U. S. Census als shows that the negro is preeminently a farmer. There art 5,192,535 negroes engaged in vocational pursuits and 2,893,380 or 55 per cent. of this number, are engaged in cultivating th soil. Between 1900 and 1910 the number of negro farmers in the United Statesincreased 705,226, or 25.9 per cent. The number of farms operated by each agricultural group in 1910 and 1900 is as followszl Number 0f Negro Farmers. Increase Per cent. 1900 1910 . 1900-1910 Increase Total . . . . . . . . . . . . . 893,370 746,715 146,655 16.4 Owners . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 218,972 187,797 31,175 14.2 Tenants . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 672,964 557,174 115,790 17.2 Managers . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1,434 1,744 310 17.8 This table clearly indicates that the negro has been and is’ an important factor in agricultural production in the South. It. is a matter of significance that he has been climbing the “agri- cultural ladder” with unusual rapidity since the close of the _ Civil War. But the percentage of increase in tenantry has con- tinued to be somewhat greater than the percentage of increase in ownership. A comparison of the acreage owned and rented by negroes in ' each of the Southern states is as follows :2 lBulletin-No. 33, Chapter 7, page 100, U. S. Bureau of Education. 2Ibid, Chapter 7, page 103. The N egro Farm Tenant 259 M Farm Acreage State Total I Owned Rented Total . . . . . . . . . . I 42,259,247 15,691,478 26,567,769 Alabama . . . . . . . . . . . I 5,073,953 1,466,719 3,607,234 Arkansas . . . . . . . . . .I 2,647,230 1,204,114 1,443,116 Delaware . . . . . . . . . .I 54,578 13,615 40,963 Florida . . . . . . . . . . . . I 758,731 458,443 300,288 Georgia . . . . . . . . . . . I 7,064,500 1,349,503 5,714,997 Kentucky . . . . . . . . . 436,459 255,363 181,096 Louisiana . . . . . . . . . . 2,103,345 834,695 1,268,650 Maryland . . . . . . . . . . ' 345,156 122,039 223,117 Mississippi . . . . . . . I 6,420,549 - 1,227,194 4,193,355 North Carolina . . . . . 3,166,812 1,197,396 1,969,496 Oklahoma . . . . . . . . . I 2,270,416 1,599,655 670,761 South Carolina . . . . .I 3,898,022 1,098,044 2,799,978 Tennessee . . . . . . . . .| 1,588,396 I 590,676 997,720 Texas . . . . . . . . . . . . I 4,188,979 1,866,742 2,322,237 Virginia . . . . . . . . . . . 2,208,235 1,381,223 827,012 West Virginia . . . . . .i 33,886 25,957 I 7,929 These figures indicate that the negro farmer is largely a renter. to every acre owned. In a number of the Southern states, two acres are rented Checking this comparison with the value of farm property owned and rented by the negro in the South, we find the follow- ingzl _ Value of Farm Property State Total I Owned I Rented Total . . . . . . . . . . . .I $1,104,496,687 $346,829,258 $757,667,329 I , Alabama . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96,856,685 22,506,427 74,350,258 ; Arkansas . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86,871,173 27,139,889 59,731,284 Delaware . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2,184,474 686,322 1,498,152 KFIorida . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14,622,184 8,779,585 5,842,599 TGeorgia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 156,988,269 25,679,922 131,308,347 p. Kentucky . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17,519,312 8,908,927 8,610,385 ‘Loulsiana . . . . . . . . . . . . 55,834,314 16,494,075 36,340,239 I Maryland . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10,953,278 4,879,716 6,073,562 .,_' rMississippi . . . . . . . . . . . 186,458,876 44,417,423 142,041,453 l North Carolina . . . . . . .. 80,804,831 27,44 ,410 53,356,421 " 58,674,493 40,59 ,030 18,084,463 117,281,487 27,340,950 89,940,537 53,181,362 16,411,350 36,770,012 figTexas . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111,736,262 39,873,225 71,863,037 fill/irginia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53,266,983 34,774,150 18,492,833 1,262,704 898,957 363,747 ggiwest Virginia . . . . . . . . . T. a. =2: .)\ '5‘ 3 Si» g These figures show that there is a great excess in the value farm property rented by negro farmers over the value of farm igiiiproperty owned by them. 'j,!Bulletin No. 33, Chapter 7, page 103, U. S. Bureau of Education. 260 Fa/rm Tenantry in the Unzted States Comparison of White and Negro Farmers. The real significance of this situation is best seen by a com?‘ parison of the principal statistics of agriculture for negro an 1 for White farmers. The accompanying table presents this co parison in 1910 and in 1900 for the United States as a Wh0l€I2 _ Farms 1910 and 1900 Plercentage - ncrease* 1910 1900-1910 w J <1’ w 6 1 m‘; E3 i. 3% Ti» ‘i. u: as q) w: m a m m hOn mop mo? @031 Number of Farms . . . . . . . . . 893,370 5,440,619 19.6 9.5 Acreage, total . . . . . . . . . . .. 42,279,510 832,166,202 10.6 4.4 Per Farm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47.3 153.0 152', Improved acreage, total . . . . 27,845,190 449,418,265 19.2 15.215; Per Farm . . . . . . . . . . . .. 31.2 86.2 f Tenure: Owners and part owners . 218,972 3,707,501 16.6 7.6‘ Tenants . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 672,964 1,676,558 20.8 14.4" Managers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1,434 56,560 --17.8 -1.2 Value: j Total . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . $1,141,792,526 $39,712,214,845 128.4 99.6 Land . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 756,158,264 27,615,515,334 133.2 117.3 Buildings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166,559,439 6,148,876,853 131.6 76.7 j Implements and machinery. 34,178,052 1,277,407,744 81.2 68.4 " Live Stack . . . . . . . . . . . . . 184,896,771 4,720,414,914 117.7 58.6 ' Value per farm . . . . . . . . . . . 1,280.75 7,299.21 91.3 82.3 Value per acre . . . . . . . . . . . . 27.01 47.72 106.9 *A minus sign §—) denotes decrease. 2Bulletin 129, Bureau of Census, in the Uniter States". Department of Commerce, pages 36 to 39, on “Negroes 91.1 _; mmnl- ' A tenants is less than one-half c“ United States. 'the percentage of negro farm tenants . of these divisions. -? comparisons are made for typical states in each of the three geo- ' graphical divisions. y cent. of all farms are operated by tenants, 80.3 per cent. of all . farms were operated by negroes, While only 34.3 per cent. were The Negro Farm Tenant 261 This table shows that the number of farms operated by A negroes in the United States is relatively small When compared i with the number operated by Whites. But the number of negro he total number of tenants in the A comparison of the percentages of White and negro ten- A ants in the South with the percentage of all farms operated by tenants, reveals the fact that negro farm tenancy is peculiarly a a Southern problem? Comparison of the Percentages of White and Negro Tenancy in the South With Percentage of All Farms Operated by Tenants? ?ercentage of all Percentage of all Percentage of all Farms operated by farms operated by farms operated by tenants. whitetenants negro tenants United States . . . . . . 37.0 30.8 73.6 A South Atlantic . . . . . 45.9 52.4 69.3 x East South Central. . 50.7 36.6 81.9 ' West South Central.. 52.8 47.2 72.3 Georgia . . . . . . . . . . . 65.6 50.0 87.1 A Alabama . . . . . . . . . . 60.2 42.6 84.5 Mississippi . . . . . . . . 66.1 38.2 84.7 Louisiana . . . . . . . . .. 55.3 34.3 80.3 i Texas . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52.6 49.2 69.5 In all four of the geographic divisions of the South, is relatively high in comparison with the percentage of White farm tenants in these divisions. The percentages are high also in comparison with the percentages of all farms operated by tenants in each A similar situation is seen to exist when the In Louisiana, for example, where 55.3 per operated by White farm tenants. llThirteenth Census, Volume 5, Tables 17 and 28. 262 Farm Tenantry in the United States A further comparison develops another aspect of this situa- tion. The average acreage of farms operated by white and negro tenants shows the relative sizes of farms operated by each group: Comparison of Average Acreage per Farm Operated by White and Negro Tenants? Average Acreage per i Average Acreage per _ _ _ Farm Operated by White; Farm Operated by ‘Ne-- Dlvlsmn ‘Tenants rrro tenants U it d St t . . . . . . . 118.9 40.0 Sdldth Atlgniisltl . . . 75.4 l 46.9 East South Central. . 52.6 I 33.7 West South Central. . 113.7 l 37.8 The census tables do not present the data for the several Southern states on this point, but it is a well known fact that the average acreage per farm that is cultivated by negroes is smaller than the average acreage cultivated by the white farm tenant. Correspondingly, the average value per farm operated by the negro tenant Will be relatively smaller than the average value of farms operated by white tenants? It is very apparent that the farm unit cultivated by the negro farm tenant has not been financially profitable. Conditions That Determine Negro Tenant Farming In the South. While the statistical data give us a basis of comparison and present the extent of negro farm tenantry, they do not reveal the nature of the problem that is created and the effects it has produced. The actual conditions can best be understood by a brief review of the agrarian problem out of which farm tenantry in the South has developed. Conditions in the South at the close of the Civil War pro- duced a radical change in the labor situation. The adjustment of available labor to the soil Was an acute problem. Economic conditions made it necessary to devise neyv methods of financing farm operations. The methods were largely the result ofuthe lThirteenth Census, Volume 5, Table 27. ‘See detailed comparison of these facts in an article by Henry Garnett on Farm Ten- ure in the United States” in Volume 30, (1909), page 171 of the American Acad- emy Annals. The Negro Farm Tenant 263 limited amount of available money that could be used for cap- ital investment. Three systems were evolved immediately fol- lowing the close of the Civil War, viz: (1) The standing-wage system; (2) the wage-earning system; (3) share-cropping. All three systems existed at the same time, and in many cases all three systems were practiced on the same plantation. The standing-wage system got its name because “hands” contracted to work for a period of months, usually during the cropping sea- son, and the wages paid were in a lump sum at the end of the period. Rations were issued weekly or monthly, or board was pro- vided. There were two objects of this system; (1) In the first place, by this planthe landlord was able to hold labor to the soil until the crop was planted, cultivated, and harvested. (2) In the second place, the farm owners could pay the wages to his farm hands after the sale of his crop when he had available money. This system has gradually disappeared. The share-cropping and the wage-earning systems have per- sisted until the present time. “No system,” says Thomas J. Ed- wards, “seems to have a more permanent effect than what is " known today as the share-cropping system. For many years after the Civil War, work on shares had a very different meaning from that which it bears today. Crops were cultivated for one- fifth, one-fourth, two-fifths, and one-third. In most cases, when the cropper worked for any fractional part below one-third, he received apart ration. Dividing crops into smaller fractional parts than one-half, was at that time considered very reason- able by those who had served years in bondage without pay and whose demands for education and better methods of living had no likeness in comparison to what they are today. It has been less than a decade since the wants of each individual farmer and his family have so increased and the competition between landlords in holding labor upon their plantations has grown so p, keen that the fractional part gradually increased, until now t5 working on shares means generally all over the Southland, that at harvesting time that crop will be halved between landlord and cropper.”1 - l, lThe Tenant System and Some Changes Since Emancipation, American Academy An- nals, Volume 49, (1913), page 39. 264 Farm Tenantry in thelUnited States Share-croppers. and renters existed in the early years fol‘ lowing the Civil War, but renting was less common than sharp cropping because renting required some capital and few of the landless class possessed it. The emancipated negroes in larg‘ numbers were compelled to farm on the share-cropping plan b cause they had not been able to acquire the ownership of a mule, the necessary feed, a wagon, and other farm implements that th landlord required as a condition to renting his land. Croppers were anxious to become renters because they desired a“ larger; control over their farm operations. Landlords were generally} _, not opposed to this change, because their financial responsibility’ ‘ was reduced and they were freed from the close supervision that; __ the cropper required. This was one point that the landless manly? p _ and the landlord had in common. The ability of the negro farmer gradually to change his status to that of ownership is traceablef. l to this situation. “Three different methods,” says Ray Stannard, Baker, “are pursuedby the landlord in getting his land culti- vated. First, the better class of tenants rent the land for f; cash, a ‘standing rent’ of some $3 an acre, though in many places"; in Mississippi it ranges as high as $6 and $8 an acre. Second, a share-cropping rental, in which the landlord and the tenant .»,. divide the cotton and corn produced. Third, the ordinary wage it system; that is, the landlord hires workers at so much a month and puts in his own crop. All three of these methods are usually employed on the larger plantation!" Condition of the Negro Tenant. _ Baker describes the condition of the negro farm tenant as a he found him on a Southern farm as follows: “Most of the tenants, especially the Negroes, are very poor, and wholly dependent upon the landlord. Many Negro families possess practically nothing of their own, save their ragged clothing, and a few dol- lars’ worth of household furniture, cooking utensils and a gun. The landlord must, therefore, supply them not only with enough to live on while they are making their crop, but with the entire farming outfit. Let us » say that a Negro comes in November to rent a one- mule farm from the landlord for the coming year. “What have you got?” asks the landlord. “N othin’, boss,” he is quite likely to say. “The ‘boss’ furnishes him with a cabin to live in lRay Stannard Baker’s “Following the Color Line”, Chapter 4, page 74. The Negro Farm Tenant 265 —which goes with the land rented—a mule, a plough, possibly a one-horse waggon and a few tools. He is often given a few dollars in cash near Christmas time which (ordinarily) he immediately spends—wastes. He is then allowed to draw upon the plantation supply store for a regular amount of corn to feed his mule, and meat, bread, and tobacco, and some clothing for his family. The cost of the entire outfit and supplies for a year is in the neighborhood of $300, upon which the tenant pays interest at form 1O to 30 per cent. from the time of signing the contract in November, although most of the supplies are not taken out until the next summer. Besides this interest the planter also makes a profit on all groceries and other necessities furnished by his supply store. Having made his contract the Negro goes to work with his whole family and keeps at it until the next fall when the cotton is all picked and ginned. Then he comes in for his ‘settlement’—a great time of year. The settlements were going forward while I was in the black belt. The Negro is credited with the amount of cotton he brings in and he is charged with all the supplies he has had, and interest, together with the rent of his thirty acres of land. If the season has been good and he has been industrious, he will often have a nice profit in cash, but sometimes he not only does not come out even, but closes his year actually deeper in debt to the landlord.“ In another connection, Baker discusses the housing and liv- ing conditions of the negro farmer. He says: “Life for the tenants is often not a pleasant thing to contemplate. I spent much time driving about the great plantations and went into many of the cabins. Usually they were very poor, of logs or shacks, some- times only one room, sometimes a room and a sort of lean-to. At one side there was a fireplace, often two beds opposite, with a few broken chairs or boxes, and a table. Sometimes the cabin was set up on posts and had a floor, sometimes it was on the ground and had no floor at all. The people are usually densely ignor- ant and superstitious; the preachers they follow are often the worst sort of characters, dishonest, and im- moral; the schools, if there are any, are practically worthless. The whole family works from sunrise to sunset in the fields. Even children of six and seven years old will drop seed or carry water.” 10p. Cit, Chapter 4, pages 74 and 75. 2Ibid, Chapter 5, page 100. 266 Farm Tenantry in the United States There may be those who are inclined to contend that these f: are exaggerated statements of the conditions of the negro farm tenant in the South. It should be frankly admitted that these p; descriptions represent rather the Worse aspects of the situation. Nevertheless, it is a matter of common knowledge that the con- 5 ditions described in these quotations do exist in many sections of the rural South. Baker takes occasion to contrast tenantry conditions in the South and in the North. He analyzes this situation as fol- lows: “Tenantry in the South is a very different thing from what it is in the North. In the North, a man who rents a farm is nearly as free to do as he pleases as if he were the owner. But in the South, the present tenant system is much nearer the condition that prevailed in slavery times than it is to the present Northern ten- ant system. This grows naturally out of slavery; the white man had learned to operate big plantations with ignorant help; and the Negro on his part had no train- ing for any other system. The white man was the na- tural master and the Negro the natural dependent and a mere Emancipation Proclamation did not at once change the spirit of the relationship. “Today a white overseer rides on every large plan- tation and he or the owner himself looks after and dis- ciplines the tenants. The tenant is in debt to him (in some cases reaching a veritable condition of debt slavery of peonage) and he must see that the crop is made. Hence he watches the work of every Negro (and indeed that of the white tenants as well) sees that the land is properly fertilized, and that the dikes (to prevent washing) are kept up, that the cotton is properly chopped (thinned) and regularly cultivated. Some of the greater land-owners employ assistant over- seers_or “riders”, who are constantly traveling from farm to farm.“ It should be observed that the difference herein described is largely traceable to the influence of the negro tenant farmer and the organization of farm operations on the plantation basis. 10p. Cit., Chapter 4, page 76. The Negro Farm TeInant 267 Difficulties 0f the Landlord. It has not been possible for the landlord in the South profit- ably to conduct his farm operations with negro farm tenants ' without resorting to different methods from those practiced where the farm tenant was more intelligent, more industrious, and more dependable. Close supervision by the landlord has been made necessary by the irresponsibility of many of the negro tenants. Baker very interestingly describes some of the land- Ylord’s difficulties with his negro tenants as follows: “Saturday afternoon (or ’evnin’), as they say in the South, the negro goes to town or visits his friends. Often he spends all day Sunday driving about the country and his mule comes back so worn out that it cannot be used on Monday. There are often furious re- ligious revivals which break into the work, to say nothing of ‘frolics’ and fish suppers at which the Ne- groes often remain all night long. Many of them are careless with their tools, wasteful of supplies, irre- sponsible in their promises. One planter told me how he had built neat fences around the homes of his Negroes, and fixed up their houses to encourage thrift and give them more comfort, only to have the fences and even parts of the houses used for firewood. “Toward fall, if the season had been bad, and the crop of cotton short, so short that a Negro knows that he will not be able to ‘pay out’ and have anything left for himself, he will sometimes desert the plantation entirely, leaving the cotton unpicked and a large debt to the landlord. If he attempts that, however, he must get entirely away, else the planter will chase him down and bring him back to his work. Illiterate, without discipline or training, with little ambition and much indolence a large proportion of Negro tenants are looked after and driven like children or slaves. I say ‘a large proportion’—but there are thousands of in- dustrious Negro landowners and tenants who are rapidly getting ahead)“ This description does not exaggerate the difficulties that _ he landlord has experienced with many negro tenants. They re often found to be irresponsible and unreliable. Thriftless- _ ollowgg the Color Li-ne, Chapter 4, page 76. 268 Farm Tenantry in the United States ness and inefficiency are common characteristics. The planters of the South have found it necessary to deal with the negro farm laborer and tenant in a very exacting manner. The plan- tation system in the South has been feudal in its nature. Just as there were good and bad barons, so there have been good and bad landlords with every gradation between these extremes in the South since the Civil War. The ignorance of the negro and his financial dependence have made it a temptation for an unjust landlord to take advantage of him. Baker uses strong words ' in describing the result: “When the Negro tenant takes up land or hires out to the landlord, he ordinarily signs a contract, or if he cannot sign (about half the Negro tenants of the black belt are wholly illiterate) he makes his mark. He often has no way of knowing, certainly, what is in the con- tract, though the arrangement is usually clearly un- derstood, and he must depend on the landlord to keep both the rent and the supply-store accounts. In other words, he is wholly at the planter’s mercy—a tempta- tion as dangerous for the landlord as the possibilities which it presents are for the tenant. It is so easy to make large profits by charging immense interest percentages or outrageous prices for supplies to tenants who are too ignorant or weak to protect themselves, that the stories of the oppressive landlord in the South are scarcely surprising. It is easy, when the tenant brings in his cotton in the fall not only to underweigh it, but to credit it at the lowest prices of the week; and this dealing of the strong with the Weak is not Southern, it is human. Such a system has encouraged dishonesty, and Wastefulness; it has made many land- lords cruel and greedy, it has increased the helpless- ness, hopelessness and shiftlessness of the Negro. In many cases it has meant downright degeneration, not only to the Negro, but to the white man. These are strong words, but no one can travel in the black belt 10p. Cit., Chapter 4, page 77. The Negro Farm Tenant 269 , without seeing enough to convince him of the terrible consequences growing out of these relationships.“ V, It must be admitted that there is much truth in this severe indictment. But those familiar with actual conditions in the i South can recall many examples where the landlord has dealt generously with his» negro tenants and safeguarded their inter- ests as he has his own. Transition From Tenantry to Farm Ownership. All things considered, the negro farmer has made the trans- ition from tenantry to farm ownership rather rapidly. In the South in 1900 there were 2,620,391 farms of which 1,870,721, or 71.1 per cent. were occupied by whites and 740,670, or 28.3 per cent. by negroes. The total number of farms in the South in- creased to 3,097,547 by 1910, and of this number 2,207,406, or 71.3 per cent., were cultivated by white farmers, and 890,141, or 28.7 per cent., by negro farmers. Of the total acreage, 88 per cent. was operated by white farmers, while only 12 per cent. was cultivated by negroes. White farmers cultivated 87.6 per cent. of the value of farm property, while negroes occupied 12.4 per cent? The progress that the negro tenant has made to owner- ship is best seen perhaps by tracing the increase in a typical Southern state. At the close of the Civil War, negroes in Georgia owned only about 10,000 acres of land valued at $22,500. By 1876 they had increased the amount to 457,635 acres, the taxable value of which was $1,234,104. During the next ten years, from 1876 to 1886, they had increased their holdings to 802,939 acres, the assessed valuation being $2,508,198. By 1896 negroes owned 1,043,846 acres of land valued at $4,234,848? While the increase has not been so great since 1896, the negro has continued to buy land. “Using all the statistics at hand,” says Booger T. Washington, “it is safe to say that negro farmers own in the Southern states not less than 30,000 square miles of land. This is an amount of teritory nearly equal to 10p. Cit., Chapter 5, page 94. ZThirteenth Census, Vol, 5, Table 19. Cp. Garnettfs “Farm Tenure in the United States,” American Annuals, Vol. 33 (1909) p. 655. 3Booker T. Washington's “The Story of the Negro,” Vol. 2, Ch. 2, p. 41. 270 Farm Tenantry in the United States five New England states, Vermont, New Hampshire, ‘Massa-l It is difficult chusetts, Connecticut and Rhode Island al-aéefj, -' 43% for one who has not lived in the South and who has not closely l studied the life of the negro on the Southern iarms and plan- tations to clearly understand the actual progress that the figure I have referred to stand for.”1 ' It may be asked, why the transition from tenantry to ownership decreased in the last two decades? Mr. Thomas Nelson Page attempts to answer this question as follows: “A comparison of the rural colored population will show that possibly over ninety per cent. of the prop- erty now owned by the Negroes has been accumulated by those who were either trained in slavery or grew up immediately after the war, so that they received the beneficial effects of the habits of industry in which their race was at that time trained.” This is probably not an adequate answer. The negro farm tenant is experiencing the same handicaps that have retarded farm ownership for the white tenant farmer. But it is a well known fact that the negro farm tenant has not possessed the intelligence, the energy, and thrift necessary t0 enable him to overcome other difficulties in the way of acquiring a farm home. Negro Migration to the Northern States. A new and unexpected situation has complicated the negro farm problem in the South. For a number of years there has been an increasing migration of negroes from Southern farms and cities to the commercial centers of the North. In 1816-17, this exodus reached such proportions as to attract wide-spread attention and cause serious alarm to the agricultural interests of the South. The number of negroes who migrated in that year cannot be determined accurately. However, the available data indicate that the number ran into the thousands. The Commissioner of Commerce and Labor in Georgia estimated the number from his state at 50,000. The Commissioner of Agri- culture in Georgia gives 90,000 as a conservative number. The 10p._cit_., v01. 2, Ch. 2, p. 4v. 2The Negroes, The Southerner's Problem, Ch. 3, p. 76. The Negro Farm Tenant 271 negro insurance companies in Mississippi, Which keep in close touch with the movement among colored people, estimated that at least 100,000 negroes left that state. In Texas, Louisiana, Arkansas, and Oklahoma, the number of negroes migrating was much smaller than from other Southern states. It is difficult to determine what proportion of the negroes who migrated came from farms. But from the causes that ' have been assigned for the exodus by all those who have studied the question, it is clearly evident that the rural sections have . suffered most from this migration. “It seems quite clear,” says W. T. B. Williams, “that the exodus had its main start and re- ceived its largest numbers in those sections which suffered most from the boll Weevil, and the floods, and in those Where the gen- eral treatment of the negro has been at its Worst.”1 T. J. Woofter, Jr., in describing the migration from Georgia, compares it to the exodus to the Western states in 1866, 1867, and 1868. He says: “Discontent With the Whole plantation system which still ‘prevails on some southern farms Wae intensified by 10W wages in 1914 and 1915, and the appearance of the boll W6€V1l.”2 Tipton Ray Snavely, in reporting the causes for Alabama and North Carolina, finds the underlying cause to be “the transition from the old system of cotton planting to stock raising and the diversification of crops.” It is apparent from this investigation made under the direction of the U. S. Bureau of Labor that the uncertainty of crop production and the discontent With farm conditions have caused thousands of negro tenants to migrate to the Northern states Where Wages Were higher. The effect of this shift is certain to produce important economic results.. The ultimateeffects cannot be accurately forecast. But already a shortage of farm labor has resulted. Farm Wages have in- creased; tenant competition for land has become less intense; landlords have already been compelled to resort to power-driven machinery as a means of offsetting the loss of man-power on the farm. The negro farm tenant has been a problem in the past be- cause of his influence on standards of efficiency and his inabil- ity to apply scientific methods to production. His standards lNegro Migration in 1916-1917, _page 73, Bulletin of the U. S. Bureau of Labor (1919). » 2Ibid, page 76 3Ibid, page 60. ‘cured for him on the farm. - 272 Farm Tenantry in the United States of living have also lowered the standards for his white neighbo p Ineificiency has not been peculiar to him. But it now app; that his change of vocation from agriculture to industrial p l suits means inevitably the creation of a new problem of agric E tural adjustment. The nature, difficulty, and extent of this pro lem can only be determined by world demands "for farm product’ and the resourcefulness of our agricultural leaders. Southern negro farmer must certainly be considered in the Y» justment of this problem. His opportunity for farm ownershl must be increased and a better standard ofp living must be ‘#:£®ls?@.'$=‘t§<“,“?"" " ‘ gradually find solution in normal ways. position forget the fact that custom and habits of mind often determine the standard of living. 5 towns. CHAPTER XXI. THE HOUSING OF FARM TENANTS. The economic problems growing out of the farm tenantry situation have been so pressing that the purely social aspects have received relatively little attention. The hous- ing of farm tenants is one of those purely social situations that has not been included in the numerous farm manage- rnent surveys that have been made. Rural housing as a soc- ial problem has been generally regarded as dependent upon the economic situation. It has been assumed that when meth- ods were devised for increasing the agricultural income above the subsistence standard that the housing situation would Those who take this An adequate income of course is fundamental, but in addition to securing a better economic situation something else needs to be done in the Way of social reform and aesthetic appreciation to secure better living conditions on the farm. For this reason, it is impera- tively necessary that we know the actual situation with refer- ence to the conditions under which the farm tenant and his family live and that a social program be devised to improve living conditions on the farm. To most of us, the housing problem immediately suggests over-crowded sections or slum districts in our great cities. Few people are aware that over-crowding is also a problem of the country and that slum districts actually exist in commun- =ities remote from railways and highly organized city com- munities. Vogt explains the reason for this as follows: “American rural experience with the tenantry problem is so - new that few concrete lessons of the effects of tenantry on housing conditions can be found?" Be that as it may, the housing situation in the country presents the same general characteristics that are found in the city. Comparatively, ‘rural housing exhibits the same differences and the same rel- ‘ative comforts that are found to exist in the residences of the There are many dwellings on the farms that are well llntroduction to Rural Sociology, chaDf/el‘ 25, 5886 34- 274 Farm Tenantry in the United States built and possess the same conveniences, such as lights, heat- ing, and running water, that are t0 be found in city homes. l But at the other extreme there are to be found in almost every rural community single houses or small groups of houses which exhibit many of the characteristics of the city slums. Fortunately, the rural slum has one advantage over its city counterpart-there is plenty of sunshine and fresh air. But aside from these, the other characteristics exist, viz., unendur- able filth, primitive sanitary facilities, over-crowding, and, in some cases, indecent promiscuityf" Every student of rural problems is familiar with the fact that rural communities dif- fer greatly in standards of living, morals, health and sanita- tion, and general intelligence. It is not unusual to ‘find com- munities only a few miles apart that differ as widely in these characteristics as city communities separated only by one or two city blocks. The expert observer c.an usually determine the relative standards of two rural communities by merely observing the houses in which the people live. Contrast Between Housing Conditions of Owner and Tenant. The contrast between the housing condition of farm owners and farm tenants is very marked in every section of the country. Vogt, in his Introduction to Rural Sociology,‘ gives the data contained in a survey of housing conditions in Ohio made by a student of the University of Ohio. These data were collected from two hundred rural homes, located in twenty-one different counties of the state. Comparisons and contrasts were made of the heating, lighting and ventilating systems, location and source of water supply and laundry facilities. As we should expect to find, in every case less adequate systems and fewer conveniences were found in ten- ant houses than in owners’ homes in the same locality. Vogt summarizes his conclusion from these data as follows: “Hous- ing conditions are bad for country people generally but they are very much worse for the tenant than for the owner. When one realizes the difficulties in the way of securing adequate lSee Rural Housing, by Elmer S. Forbes, American Academy Annuals, Vol. 51 (1914) page 110. ' ZChapter 5, page 86-89. ; 3 slaw}; é ’l’ y a The Housing of Farm Tenants 275 housing for the tenant class he cannot see a very bright pros- pect for a healthful and attractive home environment for the future farming population if present tendencies toward in- crease of tenantry continue?“ It should be observed that in the study made in Ohio the housing conditions of both owner and tenants are much better than those to be found in other sections of the country, especially in the Southern states. Some light is thrown on the housing of tenant farmers as a result of an investigation made by the Industrial Commission on Ag- riculture and Labor? Mr. Joseph P. Ager, Master of the State Grange of Maryland, a prominent farmer anddairy- man of his state, in answer to the request that he “describe the tenant house” gave the following answer: A. “Usually small, perhaps three rooms; about the general size of that. Q. Of what are they constructed? A. Usu- ally frame, lath, and plaster; quite a comfortable house, but small. Q. What appurtenances go with the houses? A. Generally a garden spot, perhaps a quarter of an acre of ground. That is more than most of them will cultivate.“ In his testimony before the Industrial Commission, Honor- able J. W. Stockwell, Secretary of the Massachusetts State Board ‘of Agriculture, described the farm tenant house as generally good.“ The evidence with reference to the South was In rather marked contrast to conditions described in Massachusetts and other Northern and Eastern states. For example, Mr. Harry -Hammond, Civil War veteran, a former Professor of Natural Sciences in the University of Georgia and for many years a cotton planter, gave the following testimony: “What is the character of the tenant houses? A. The negro prefers to live by himself. He wants an isolated house. They have a front room 18 to 20, with 2 shed rooms 10 to 15, for bed- rooms. That is the usual form of tenant houses. Q. 10p. Cit., Chapter 5, page 90. zReport of Industrial Commission, Vol. 10, page 104. ‘ = Slbid, page 885. 276 Farm Tenantry in the United States There is no question that the houses have not suffi- cient rooms in them, very frequently, to separate the different members of the family, but I think every- body is improving in that respect very much. The houses are certainly more comfortable than they have been since slavery times. Immediately after the war any sort of house was put up. In fact, a hand would come to you and would be v"lling to build his house if you would let him have u. certain piece of land. He would build on the land and live in his house. A miserable cabin it Would be, but recently he has done better than that. The building has been undertaken by employers themselves, and they build substantial houses. Of course, they are not places of style; it is not necessary that they should be. Q. Are they frame houses or log houses? A. Frame houses; log houses have gone out en- tirely. In coming through South Carolina to Wash- ington the other day I did not see but one log house from the car window all the way through; the log cabin is disappearing. ' Q. Are they built with floors and with cellars? A. Yes; the dirt floor has disappeared entirely. That has not been in common use during my life- time. Generally speaking, all the houses have been floored for the last 60 years or more. Q. Do they have cellars also? A. No; they have instead any number of outhouses, little outhouses that they put up themselves—barns and things of that sort. Q. Are the houses provided with glass Win- dows? A. They are getting to be; they Were not formerly, in the neighborhood of which I spoke. All of the people did not have glass windows there. All the houses had board shutters and no glass in my early days. It is only in recent time, I may say during fifties and sixties, that they commenced to put in glass.“ These general conditions reported in the older Southern. states Were found to exist in Texas in a survey made by Dr. F. B. Clark, Professor of Economics in the Agricultural and Mechanical College of Texas in 1916. Professor Clark made 10p. Cit. page 821. The Housing of Farm Tenants 277 a tour of several of the most prosperous black land counties of North Texas. His observation on this point was as fol- lows: “The tenant houses are everywhere in bad re- pair. Almost no thought of sanitation, much less beauty, has entered the minds of these people. The landlord will usually say that it is useless to fix good quarters for the tenants for they will not take care of them; and the tenant will say that it is use- less to ask for good quarters for the landlord will not listen. There is mutual distrust and neither gets what he thinks that he deserves. But the fact re- mains that the tenants as a class have not been given a chance. If one has not been provided with things worth taking care of you can hardly blame him for not taking care of the things with which he has been provided.“ In the section visited by Professor Clark there are few negro tenants. The agricultural income from farm opera- tions in this section of Texas is rather adequate. Professor Clark was of the opinion, after a careful analysis of the situa- tion, that living conditions were as much a result of a lack of aesthetic appreciation as of economic causes. He refers to the fact that there are “some owners who possess abundance of Wealth and yet they live in poor houses with few conveniences. And again there are numerous tenants who possess nice incomes Without knowing how to enjoy them. We must remember, how- ever, that one may too hastily condemn an owner for not bettering his living conditions, for if the truth were known he might be found not to be an owner at all but laboring under a heavy mortgage likely to be foreclosed at any time. Yet we do find owners free from mortgages living in squalor. But the cause of this in most cases is not social but individual. The man may be a drunkard, he may simply lack pride, or the family may never have overcome the habits of the rural laborer or tenant. It is generally recognized, in spite of certain handi- caps, that it is only through some form of ownership that we can ever hope to produce a healthy and attractive rural life. The tenant innately opposed to bettering the conditions of‘ another lUnpublished Study on “The Texas Farm Tena/nt.” 278 Farm Tenantry in the United States man's place. This is characteristically true of the tenan I general, and unquestionably a direct result of the system _ tenantry as it exists in Texas?" Rental 0f Tenant Houses. In the Northern states it is often the custom to chargei: rental for the tenant houses, but this policy does not previ to an appreciable extent in the South. In some instances, t‘ days work each month is required as a rental for the occupied by the tenant. On the plantations of the South, i is the custom to supply the house free of rent and from on ‘ ' half to two acres of land go with the house for garden E chicken yard? The fact is, the character of the house -l__ a plied is rarely of sufficient value to justify the charge of rent.) If an element of rent enters at all into the assignment of a house, it is probably contemplated that the rent is included in the amount of produce to be received by thelandlord, or‘ the amount of cash rent is regarded as of sufficient amount to>1f include the rent of the farm house. ' Tenant’s Care 0f the House. Much has been said about the tenant’s neglect of the Y, house he occupies. This is often assigned as the reason why the landowner cannot afford to supply the tenant with-a bet- i, ter house. There is no doubt that many tenants and their families do not take reasonable care of the house they occupy. I But there is some evidence to support the opposite view. For l‘ example, J. H. Hale, a practical farmer of Ft. Valley, Geor- gia, testified before the Industrial Commission that his ten- ants did take fairly good care of his tenant houses. He fur- ther commented as follows: “Tenant houses have mostly been unpainted. Two years ago I told them (tenants) that if they would keep them painted we would furnish the material if they would do the work; and it was very much to their de- light, and they are now keeping them painted, and we are furnishing material and the other expenses, and they rather lUnpublished Study on “The Texas Farm Tenant” (1916). 2See testimony of J. H. Hale before Industrial Commission, Report, Vol. 5, page, 379. The Housing 0f Farm Tenants 279 1 t ke a pride in painting them.” It has been observed that the landlord provides houses of reasonable comfort _ hat as a rule the tenant takes some pride in keeping the house good condition. But houses that are unattractive, and do ti» offer reasonable comfort are usually neglected by the ten- nt. But this is to be expected. We find human nature ex- ‘ ing itself here exactly as we find it in many other things. Over-Crowding in Rural Houses. It is hard for us to believe that real over-crowding exists 3;: the rural districts. But this is very obvious to any one who - l}: studied closely the rural housing situation. The houses cupied by tenants are usually very small. In many cases consist of two rooms with a back shed room that is used lth for a kitchen and dining room. The negro tenant farm ouse often does not possess even glass windows. Light and_ Ventilation is received through an opening that is protected 4 om rain by a small door on hinges. It is not exceptional for om five to ten people to be housed in a building of this kind. Farvey B. Bashore gives the experience of a nurse from one ~ the state dispensaries in Pennsylvania who “came across a Jrtain farm house where five people were accustomed to ving in one not very large bed room which had only one R» window and even that was nailed shut; one of these five d in insipient tuberculosis.“ The same author calls atten- n to a “mountain home-—a typical one—a bed room, which v _ the loft with a floor surface of fifteen feet square, which is bitually used by eight people; three sleep in one bed, two t another, two more in still another, and the mother, who is a bercular, sleeps on the cot in the corner. One would hard- believe it possible that such over-crowding exists, yet there _ many cases like this among these mountain people.” These .ditions are less common in Pennsylvania, however, than cticed. I These conditions produce the usual results of ill health . Cit" page 384. ‘y are in the Southern states where tenantry is so largely 280 Farm Tenantry in the United States and immorality that we hear so much about in the ov_ crowded sections of our great cities. The negro farm ten‘ is peculiarly the victim of this situation. Immorality amo_ negroes is widespread, and it has been difficult for this r‘ to make normal progress under the conditions in which th live. i 5' Professor Ogden has wisely called attention in his b0.‘ on Rural Hygiene to the importance of the location of ru ' houses and their proper construction with reference to healt fulness. Most of the agricultural colleges of the county haY worked out house plans for tenant houses. These plans a designed with reference to economy of construction and co r i fort; health and modern conveniences are carefully consid‘ ed. But, unfortunately, few land owners have made use the available information relating to a better rural housin situation. k lOuercv-owded and Defective Housing in the Rural Districts, page 35. Zlbzd, page 36 lRm-al Hygiene, Chapter l, pagel. The Housing of Farm Tenants 281 Rural Housing- in England. It may be profitable by Way of comparison to direct at- ' tention to what is being done with reference~to rural housing in another country. Rural housing of tenants has received serious consideration in the countries of Europe. England, for aexample, where approximately 30,000 people are said to own g the land cultivated by more than 30,000,000 has been con- . fronted with a rural housing problem. This is to be expected 7 in a country of large estates cultivated by tenants under the a general direction of absentee landlords. Laws Were passed f as early as 1487 ,1 directing the landlords to improve the liv- ing conditions of tenants. Before the end of the fifteenth i century, laws Were passed making it the duty of justices to administer the rural housing laws? A more comprehensive rural housing act was passed in 1589,?’ which provided (1) l that no one was to build a cottage or convert a building into a cottage for workers on land Without allotting to it four acres 1 of land and (2) that two families were not to occupy one cot- , tage. This act continued in force until 1775, When it was suc- ceeded by other acts that more completely met the needs of a new situation. ~ "WW ,1“ . >\ A. The literature relating to English rural life presents here 3; and there a picture of the housing conditions of farm tenants. Vogt quotes from Mr. H. Rider Haggard’s “Rural England,” in which a description is given of a number of farm tenant houses: “No. 1. Thatched, built of cracked and ancient stud Work, contained one bedroom, one sitting room, and a lean-to scullery. The bedroom in the roof which Was stopped with rags to keep out the rain, was approached by a step-ladder, the WO- 1Fee 4 Henry VII, Chapter 19. n: ‘:1 Q u a 8‘ 3 P‘ ‘i b" m ‘.1 <+ m >1 ~l ,1 3Montague Fordham’s.A Short History of English Rural Life, Chapter 8, page 109. 282 Farm Tentmtry in the United States man who led me there crawling on her hands and knees into the apartment Where she slept with a daughter of a neighbor - - - - - This girl’s previous bedroom had been shared with her father, a wid- ower, in the next cottage. I should add that she was grown up. “No. 2. A row of cottages of small size. Until Miss Cochrane induced a neighboring landowner to grant a strip of land at the back, upon which the necessary outbuildings and conveniences now stand, these buildings were confined between the main road and a large open ditch upon the edge of which their back walls were built. Into this ditch ran all the sewage and other refuse. They were known as the ' ‘Eltisley death-trap’, and their back windows could not be opened because of the stench. “No. 3. A small two-roomed cottage. Seven children were reared in the bedroom, and at one time four children slept there for a period of three months while the parents lay sick in bed. It was impossible to wash the floor, as the water ran be- tween the boards into the sitting room below. “No. 4. (then empty). Two rooms and no out- house or pantry - - - - - - At the floor line at (the upstairs room) was 17 ft. by 9 ft., but as the roof sloped the space above was not so large. The win- dow was 24 in. by 18 in. In this room eight children were reared with their parents. In the sister cot- tage adjoining, also two-roomed, lived seven child- ren and their parents, making for the four rooms a total of nineteen, whose water supply was a filthy hole in the garden.“ E. N. Bennett says the conditions of farm cottages in England are “uncomfortable and unsanitary.” He tells us “Old cottages decay until they are abandoned, no more are 1Vol. 2, page 65. The Housing of Farm Tenants 283 built to take their places and so in many parishes there is a positive dearth of dwelling houses.” This author explains the exodus from the country to the city on this ground. “The Whole social system,” says he, “of rural England seems to form, indeed, unconsciously as it were and unintentionally, one vast conspiracy for expelling the people from the country.“ Rural Housing Reforms in England.’ The Rural Housing and Sanitation Association was form- ed in England in 1900 for the purpose of improving rural housing conditions. This organization made little headway for a time, but in 1909 it had gained sufficient influence in parlia- ment to secure legislation based upon its program of reform. This statute is known as “The Housing and Town Planning Act” and by its provisions Rural Councils are given authority to apply for public loans with which to build rural cottages. While these Rural Councils were rather slow to act at first, the number of cottages built under this plan has been increas- ing rapidly isrecent years? There is a very interesting ar- ticle by Hugh Aronson on Rural Housing in the Contemporary] Review for May, 1912.3 This article presents an interesting illustration of the administration of the Burn’s Housing and Town Planning Act by giving the details of an investigation made by a Rural Council of the needs for new cottages. This investigation also reveals the conditions in Hertfordshire. Another writer has declared that “in Hertfordshire a state- g ment that at least one-third of the rural cottages are unfit for Z human habitation has never been disputed; probably it is be- t cause it is below the mark; and yet, the powers that be are moving so slowly toward improvement that the knowledge l of their existence seldom extends beyond their own commit- . tees.“ One is prepared to accept this statement after read.- j ing the following account of these conditions: ‘ lProblcms of Villag/e Life, page 73. i 2€ee Constance Cochranes article on “Rural Housing and State Grants,” in Conntemporary . Review’. Vol. 101 (191?) page 29.11. -°-Contemp'\rary Review for May 1912, Vol. 101, page 709-13. i 4Fred Ballard on Rural Housing in Contemporary Review, Vol. 99 (1911), page 445. 284 Farm Tenantry in the United States “The first Witness called was an aged gentle- man resident in the village; he said the cottages are ‘as bad as bad can be _ - - - - - I would not put my pigs into ‘some of them’.~ He was asked if any of them were overcrowded; he replied, ‘some of them - - - - - - it leads t0 everything immoral; it appears t0 me that unless something is done it will destroy the manhood of England. Some dozen men and Women were then examined, all of whom asserted that cottages were badly needed. The following is an extract from some of the evidence. “One Witness said he had lived in the village seventy-five years, and being asked if any cottages had been pulled down, replied: ‘About thirty and over’. He Was then asked if he could remember any cottages being built, to which he replied: ‘Yes, about eight’. Another was asked: ‘Do they ("the inhabitants) think there ought to be more houses at Chipperfield?’ ‘They do, only they are afraid to speak’. Another was asked how many appli- cants there were for a cottage he had vacated. ‘About a dozen’, he replied. An agent was examined as to how many years the present occupier of a certain cottage had to wait for it. ‘About two and a-half years’, was the answer. A man who had been tak- ing charge of his employer’s farm, said that he had paid rent for his unoccupied cottage for fourteen months so as to retain it, and when asked if any- one occupied it Whilst he was at the farm, said: ‘We did not give them the chance’. So this man, earn- ing about sixteen shillings a week, actually paid five pounds rather than run the risk of not getting a cot- tage when he left the farm. A woman, on being asked if she had to walk four miles every day to and from her work, said, ‘Yes.’ ‘What did you have to do when it rained’? was another question. ‘I have to dish the water out of the window all day long and put clean curtains up’; she was further asked: ‘Do you remember two gentlemen coming around?’ She answered, Yes’. ‘Did they come to look at your cottage?’ ‘They came to look at it, but I could not let them go over it because the landlord had just been round and said I should have to go out if I did, and there was nowhere else to go to’. Over- crowding was admitted, and it was not denied that the rents of the tumble-down cottages had increas- ed from 20 per cent. to 30 per cent. in recent years!" lContemporary Review, Vol. 101, page 710. The Housing of Farm Tenants 285 Conditions of rural housing in England have been de- scribed at some length for the purpose of showing what has happened under an absentee landlord system. It is also easy to see from the references to these conditions how difficult it is to secure the effective administration of reform measures l even after they have been enacted into law. A similar situa- i2 tion is likely to exist in any country where housing is provided for a land-occupying population by an absentee-land-owner- ship class. It is important to consider our present situation {in the United States in the light of these conditions to see to a lwhat extent we have gone and what can be done to prevent i just such conditions as have been described. Standards in Rural Housing. The time has come when we should follow the example of England and other European countries and consider ser- iously the problem of rural housing for our tenant farmers. While most of our people, especially in the South, are more or less familiar with the needs for housing reform, few have felt the responsibility of assuming leadership in a campaign _ for the accomplishment of this purpose. Now and then, a voice is raised “urging appropriate legislation that will correct ‘q the evils of our inadequate and unsanitary housing situation. I f But it has not been heard by those responsible for making and , executing our laws. i There is a tendency on the part of tenant farmers them- selves to take the initiative in the matter of housing re- jform. The Renters Union that was ‘organized in September 1909 in McClain County, Oklahoma, set up the following standards for rural housing: - “(a) We demand that the landlords of this state shall provide their tenants with a house in which to live which shall consist of not less than two rooms and a lean-to. The said two rooms shall not be less than 14 feet square, with a ceiling not less than 8 1-2 feet high. The said room shall be plastered and have a lumber floor. ' . “The lean-to shall not be less than 8 by 2O feet and built substantially to exclude the elements. 286 Farm Tenantry in the United States It shall be partitioned, one-half into a kitchen and one-half into a porch, which said porch shall be screened in. There shall be at least four windows to said building and two of the lean-to, which said windows shall consist of two sashes t0 each window and so constructed that the sashes can be raised and lowered. The doors to said building and all of the windows to said building shall be screened with wire and in a manner to exclude the flies and mosquitoes. There shall also be built to said build- ing a front porch at least 16 by 6 feet, which may be roofed with boards and batten. “(b) We further demand that a stable be pro- vided for three horses, and also a shed of reasonable size in which to store implements. We also demand ficllilicken coop not less than 10 by 12 feet and 6 feet 1g . “(c) We also demand that the well on the premises shall be curbed and so fixed as to prevent the surface water from getting into it.”1 There is much in the rural housing acts of England and other countries that would help us to formulate our rural - house policies. But it should be frankly admitted that many l. departures from European practice would be necessary in for- mulating an adequate policy for our own country. There is a vast difference in rural conditions in this county and in a coun- i?’ try like England. Anderson has pointed out one of these dif- ferences in the following language: “There is now a strik- f ing difference between America and Europe in rural life. In 1“ Europe the country people are more generally gathered in vil- Y lages; in America more of them are scattered over the whole face of the country, dwelling on their farms.” This in itself makes our rural housing problem different from that in Eng- a land, and perhaps this ‘fact also makes the formulation of a l housing program more difficult. But this is not the only dif- ference. The character of agricultural production, the differ- ence in systems of cultivation, the methods of renting land, and the shift of the agricultural population are all factors that need to be considered in the formulation of an adequate rural housing policy for tenant farmers. lRepor-t of Industrial Relations, Vol. 10, page 9067. 2The Country Town, Chapter 15, page 244. The Housing of Farm Tenants 287 But the conditions demand that something be done. We cannot ignore the 10W standards of living and the social prob- lems created in many sections Without serious consequences to four national Welfare. It is imperative that a rural housing program be formulated and adequate legislation be secured to ‘raise the standard of living of these who live on rented farms. CHAPTER X-XII. THE INTELLECTUAL INTERESTS OF FARM TENANTS. Every observer of rural community life is familiar with the differences in the intellectual interests of a community where home ownership is the prevailing type of tenure in con- trast to the intellectual interests that are found to prevail in a community where tenantry is the prevailing type of tenure. As a general thing, the intellectual interests of the farm owners is broader and more intense than that of his tenant neighbor. That there are prominent exceptions to this generalization only helps to give assurance of the correctness of this statement. The relative intellectual interests of the two groups are usually re- flected in the character of the homes occupied by each, and the general conditions that prevail about them. The rural sociologist has found a fairly accurate way to measure the relative intellectual interests of different groups of people. The nature of the social activities that are practiced, the number and kind of books and magazines that are read, the musical instruments that are found in the homes, and the po- litical societies and religious organizations with which the mem- bers of the group are affiliated, are characteristic means of deter- mining the breadth and nature of the intellectual interests of the group. While the rural life studies that have been made that in- clude data of this kind are relatively small, nevertheless a suf- ficient number of surveys have been made in typical sections of the country to render definitely the establishment of the gen- eralization contained in the introductory paragraph of this Chapter. . In one of the Ohio Rural Life Surveysl made under the gen- eral direction of the Department of Church and Coutry Life of theBoard of Home Missions of the Presbyterian Church, U. S. A., a comparison was made of the number and kind of periodicals taken with the following results: 1“S0uthucste1"n Ohio,” from Ohio Rural Life Survey, published by Board of Home Missions of the Presbyterian Church in the U. S. A., page 89. The Intellectual Interests of Farm Tenants 2899 s‘ Number of Periodicals reported, Owners’ and Tenants’ Families, Southwestern Ohio. \ Owners Tenants N b T k" ' M“- um er a mg __ Number l Per cent. Number l Per cent. Total . . . . . . . . . . . . 271 100.0 l 193 l 100.0 1 paper only . . . . . . . . 43 15.9 l 50 25.9 2 papers . . . . . . . . . . . 59 21.8 57 l 29.5 3-5 papers . . . . . . . . . 119 43.9 71 l 36.8 6 or more . . . . . . . . . ., 50 18.4 15 I 7.8 _: Of the owners, 43.9 per cent. take from 3 to 5 papers, while but 36 per cent. of the tenants take this number. Sixty-two per 1 cent. of the owners take 3 or more papers, while but 43 per cent. of the tenants take this number. Of the tenants 24.9 per cent. take but one paper as against 15.9 per cent. of the owners} l The nature of the intellectual interests is more accurately re- vealed in this survey in the tabulation of the kinds of papers taken. ~ Kinds of Papers Taken, Owners and Tenants, Southwestern Ohio Owners ‘(273 considered) Tenants (203 considered) "Kind of Papers l’ Taken. Number l Per cent. Number l Per cent. Agriculture . . . . . . . . 158 57.9 87 u 42.8 ‘Religious . . . . . . . . . . 36 13.2 1O 4.9 =-.News . . . . . . .- . . . . . . 259 94.9 ‘182 | 89.7 omen’s Magazines . 74 27.1 44 21.7 Cheap Advertising . . 39 14.3 24 11.8 ‘Standard Magazines . 37 13.6 9 4.4 l The owners report 94.9 per cent. taking newspapers, while a he tenants report 89.7. Neither group is conspicuous for the _ lnumber of religious papers taken or for the number of standard agazines. The owners group report 57.9 per cent. taking ag- cultural periodicals, while the tenant group report but 42.8 Cr cent. Women’s magazines are reported as 27 .1 per cent. for e owners and 21.7 per cent. for the tenants? i, In an unpublished farm management survey made by S. A. cMillan, Professor of Farm Management in the Agricultural l.‘ Mechanical College of Texas, the relative interest of farm ers and tenants was indicated as follows: “Fifty owners and thirty-nine renters in Brazos County, exas, reported as follows: Vogt's “Introduction to Rural Sociolgy," Chapter 5, page 91. bid, Chapter 5, page 92. 290 Farm Tenantry in the United States Number of owners who held or had held some local public office 11 or 22 per cent. Number of renters who held or had held some local pub- lic oifice, 4 or 10 per cent. Number of owners who are members of lodges or se- cret societies, 18 or 36 per cent. Number of renters who are members of lodges or se- cret societies, 11 or 28 per cent. Number of owners who take one or more newspapers, 34 or 68 per cent. Number of renters who take one or more newspapers, 21 or 54 per cent. Average number of‘ books found in the homes of owners, 14. Average number of books found in the homes of renters, 8. Some musical instrument was found in one out of every two homes of the owners. l Only one musical instrument out of every nine homes was found in the case of tenants. Some Educational Advantages. Some interesting data bearing on this topic are revealed in the study made by O. R. Johnson and W. E. Foard of the Uni- versity of Missouri. This study shows that for the state of Missouri about one-third of the children of the owners finished the rural school, while only one-fourth of the children of part owners, and one-eighth of the children of tenants, ever accom- plished this task. The results shown by this study are as follows: Land Tenure and Education of Children. l l . l l 1 w w .3 J5’ . $4 , l as 4-2 1 é l, a s s A 5 Ah A A9. M? l P‘ Per cent. of children completing district school . . . . . . . 32.7 25.6 12.7 Per cent. of above completing high school . . . . . . . . . . . . 22.7 13.0 17.9 Per cent.- attending college . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9.4 3.6 3.0 Per cent. of children not at home . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33.9 26.8 15.8 Per cent. of above on farms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63.0 53.6 56.6 The Intellectual Interests of Farm Tenants 291 g_ One child in everylthree‘ from the families of landowners here shown to have completed a rural school education, While ' l4 one in eight of the tenants’ has this advantage. Turning w the class of children that have high school education, this shows “that of those who complete the fural school, one- Ith of both owners’ and tenants’ children complete the high hool. This would mean that out of every one hundred owners’ ildren, thirty-three would have finished the rural school, and of this thirty-three would have finished the high school. For e part owners, twenty-five would have finished the rural school ju three would have finished the high school, for the tenants’ g irteen would have finished the rural school and two would have ; ished the high school. Of those children in the various classes ishing high school, nine per cent. of. the owners’ children, three '_ d six-tenths per cent. of the part owners’, and three per cent. the tenants’ children attend college.” In a general way, this lows that the tenant’s children are not having the educational [vantages that are given to children of men who own land. is seems to be an important and fundamental criticism of the girability of tenant classes in the make-up of our rural society. g Another point in this connection, which is of interest, is the ' t that out of one-third of owners’ children who are not at g ggme, sixty-three per cent. are on farms; of one-fourth the part ‘rs’ children who are not at home, one-half are on farms; of A In one-sixth of the tenants’ children that are not at home, one- are on farms. In other words, more owners’ children have _ ’_ rted out for themselves than have those of part owners and l: nts, but a greater proportion of owners’ children have chosen culture as a profession and have probably been started by u help from their fathers.‘ g These authors summarize the data for this situation as fol- s: 'ersity of Missouri Agricultural Experiment Station Bulletin ~No. 121 on Land Tenure, e 81. ‘ ' 292 Farm Tenantry in the United States Education 0 f Operators. a 2 3 a p 2 fi s s s 6 O f-‘uO E4 Rural School . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . v 84.4 80.5 88.7 High School . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.2 9.1 6.2 College . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10.4 10.5 5.1 _ The education of farm operators is shown in the table above.‘ This shows a much smaller percentage of tenants receiving high- er education and a somewhat larger percentage of them getting i, no further than rural schools} The effect of farm tenantry on educational facilities is Well 1i brought out in “A Study of Rural Schools In Travis County, Texas,” by E. E. Davis, Department of Extension, Division of School Interests. In this study it is found “that 63.1 per cent. of T all the families in the section of Travis County that was surveyed were tenants, and in some communities the rate of farm tenancy to the total population exceeded 8O per cent. In the area included ' in this survey, 35.2 per cent. of the 511 white families do not own i their homes, 78.4 per cent. of the 390 negro families were found I; to be farm tenants, and less than 2 per cent. of approximately 230 l- Mexican families were reported as owning their homes free of j debt.” “A high percentage of farm tenants,” says Davis, “is not I j, conducive to good schools. It is not natural to expect the aver- f; age farm tenant t0 have the community interests that he would 1 if he were permanently located on land of his own. But a no less serious menace to the prosperity of the public schools in some- of the tenant districts in sight of the dome of the Capitol at Austin, is the absentee landlord who is opposed to local school taxes. Diligent inquiry was made, and in this area of 200 square miles and more than 13,000 population, only one absentee land- lord was reported as actively encouraging his tenants to vote for a school tax? lBulletin» No. 121, page 82, University of Missouri. 2Bulletin No. 67, page 7, (1916), University of Texas. The Intellectual Interests of Farm Tenants 293 A trustee who was reported as a representative citizen of more than average intelligence is reported by Mr. Davis to have said in answer t0 an inquiry concerning the poor conditions of the school: “You want to know what makes our school one of the sor- riest in Travis County. I can tell you that in about fifteen words. This community is owned and controlled by about three men who do not live here. They keep their tenants in fear of them. Two years ago when we were circulating a petition for a tax election Mr. A. came out and said to his tenants: ‘You vote a tax on me and I will see that you pay for it. I will raise the rent on the last one of you.’ Mr. B. came out and said to his tenants, ‘Gentlemen, you may vote a tax on me if you choose, but you can prepare to move next year if you do.’ Their bluffs carried. That was the last of the proposed school tax. You have found our school in a deplorable condition, and I see no hope of any improvement.“ In another study in Texas made by E. V. White on Farm Tenancy and the Public Schools, it is shown “that the schools and the factors that contribute for good schools are retarded in sec- tions where a high percentage of tenancy obtains is evident from the tables given below.” Table I shows a few vitally important school statistics for the school year 1912-13 for counties of the State where the percentage of farm tenancy is comparatively low. Table II shows the same items for the same school year for coun- ties where tenancy is high. In selecting the counties, an en- deavor was made to select those that were typical of the sec- tions which they represent. The counties were also distributed over the entire State. In other words, a consideration of all the counties would present approximately the same results as are presented in the few counties selected. lBulletin 67, University of Texas, page 9. 294 Fawn Tenantry in the United States TABLE I. Counties Having a Low Percentage of Farm Tenants. 5 é é <5 8 gs vb ' E l E 2i é“ ii “a ' m“ Name of ‘:3 535M131. ~55 :63“) County iriifi <33 $33.5 ci§f3§ c32§ c3335 Hansford . . . . . . . . . . .1 16 $ 32.00 122 100 89 63 Galveston . . . . . . . . . . 18 48.50 164 100 83 45 Garza . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 *582.00 132 86 T132 70 Gillespie . . . . . . . . . . . 22 25.70 137 21 62 49 Jasper . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 16.80 135 95 $104 59 Harris . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26 57.00 149 96 86 52 Lubbock . . . . . . . . . . . 30 43.40 210 100 82 33 Hale . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 34.95 160 100 96 59 Marion . . . . . . . . . . . . 39 10.65 130 33 - 91 54 Brown . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42 18.80 110 69 89 61 Mills . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44 9.65 102 67 97 65 Average for entire group . . . . . . . . . . . 32.55 135 75 89 52 *Evident1y due to a large county fund. {Evidently due to rapid settling of the country. TABLE II. Counties Having a High Percentage of Farm Tenants. S é ' é é = L é é .8 3’ 5 5 "a u: Q Egg "a _ 35 “a E s is s 3 “a “'5 . P‘ . > w - >~ ' Q F5 Q C3 Q fl O U U <9 Name Of $.42 2,. gimp 55E 13533 3&2: County fife‘; J53 <1“6.E n.5,! 0432 ans-firs Wharton . . . . . . . . . . .~ 60 $11.52 137 85 75 48 Fort Bend . . . . . . . . . . 61 8.82 144 76 75 48 Denton . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 17.90 111 78 83 47 Wilbarger . . . . . . . . . . 61 32.80 114 100 96 48 Dallas . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 19.28 126 15 86 50 Haskell . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 25.10 113 100 89 53 Bell’ . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 17.25 111 61 84 52 Hill . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 12.95 100 90 85 56 Frio . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62 20.00 144 87 45 31 Grayson . . . . . . . . . . . 63 20.93 130 75 89 41 Red River . . . . . . . . . . 63 8.85 109 59 73 48 Milam . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64 11.05 115 51 82 47 McLennan . . . . . . . . . . 64 9.45 107 35 80 55 Lamar . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66 9.32 107 51 86 52 Falls . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66 10.73 115 54 73 56 Hunt . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68 13.67 104 92 86 56 Ellis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69 13.71 114 65 76 44 Robertson . . . . . . . . . . 70 7.83 122 35 94 49 Average for entire Group . . . . . . . . . . . 13.76 117 64 81 47 The Intellectual Interests of Farm Tenants 295 Possibly some factors other than tenancy enter into the re- sults indicated. It remains true, however,'that the counties hav- ing a low percentage of farm tenancy have certain uniform con- ditions which vary from certain uniform conditions in counties having a high percentage of tenancyfl Education and Land Ownership. Poor school facilities, as revealed by such a study as that just referred to, not only restrict the intellectual interests of a farm population, but have a direct influence on the possibilities of acquiring a farm home. This is very carefully brought out in a study made by Eugene Merritt and K. L. Hatch in Wis- consin in 1916, based on data secured from 315 farmers. The following results were obtained: The numbers given are the averages for the crop. The study was made by the questionnaire method, and the questions and answers are indicated as follows :2 “Does the quality of his education affect the time necessary for the farmer to acquire free title to his land? For this study the farmers were arranged in two classes as follows: Class 1.—Those who had a high school education or better. Class 2.—-Those who had a common school education only. Each of these classes were again sub-divided into three groups: 1.—Those who had always worked on farms when not in school until they began farming on their own account. 2.—Those who never worked on farms until they began "farming on their own account. 3.—Those who had worked both on farms and at other oc- = - cupations before beginning on their own account. It was found that a much larger proportion of the high school class had never worked on farms or had worked at both farming for themselves than of the common school class. By what processes had these farmers acquired free title to i‘ their land? 1.--The largest number of both classes had started with i mortgages on their farms. a 1See Bulletin No. 21 of the University of Texas on Studies in Farm Tenantry, in Texas, Chapter 9, pages 41 and 42. ZResearch Bulletin No. 40 of the University of Wisconsin on Some Economic Facts Which BResearch Bulletin No. 40 of the University of 42 and 43. 296 Farm Tenantry in the United States 2.—The second largest number of both classes had begun as tenants and then acquired ownership through mortgage. 3.—-(a) Among the high school class the third group in im- portance were those who had been tenants but whose farms had never been mortgaged. (b) Among the common school class the third group in importance had neither been tenants nor had their farms ever been mortgaged. At what age had these men begun farming on their own account? 1.—-Those who had never followed any other occupation than farming began farming at an earlier age than either of the other two groups. 2.—Those who had a high school education began farming over one year later than those who had only a common school education. 3. It took the man with a common school education who had engaged only in farming 10 years to obtain possession of a clear title. 4.—It took the man with a high school education slightly over seven years to obtain a clear title to his farm. This ad- vantage over the common school group may have been due, how- ever, to superior opportunity or financial advantage. 5. Those who had never farmed began farming on their own account between 8 and 9 years later than those who had always farmed with the result that they owned their farms free from 5 to 8 years later in life than those who devoted them- selves entirely to farming. 6.—Those with a common school education began farming at approximately 26 years of age. 7 .—Those with a high school education began farming at the age of 27. ' 8.—-Those with a common school education owned their farms free at 36 years. 9.—-Those with a high school education owned their farms free at between 34 and 35 years of age. a By comparison of the above observations it is noted that the men with a high school education began farming on their own account one year later but owned their farms free from debt The Intellectual Interests 0f Farm Tenants 297 over one year earlier in life. These data apparently indicate that a high school education is a good investment for the farmer and that it pays the boy who intends ultimately t0 be a farmer t0 stick by the farm rather than to engage in other occupations.” Conclusion. These studies are sufficient to indicate that a high per- centage of farm tenantry has a definite relationship to poor rural schools. The reasons are quite obvious. The relative tran- ciency of farm tenants results in little interest being manifested in improving school facilities. The indifference of absentee land- lords is a natural consequence of an interest only in the financial returns from the land they lease for cultivation. The limited intellectual interest of the farm tenant is also largely explained by inadequate rural school facilities. There is very little _to stimulate intellectual interests in communities where these conditions prevail. Where there are poor schools, there are usually few lodges, social and literary clubs, churches, and other institutions that foster and develop the intellectual in- terests of the people. It is not surprising, therefore, that all the studies that have been made, reveal the fact that in those commu- nities where farm tenantry is high, the number and extent of the intellectual interests are 10W. The relative increase in the in- tellectual interests to be found in any rural community is, rough- ly speaking, in proportion to the number of home owners to the farm tenants. CHAPTER XXIII. THE RELIGIOUS INTERESTS OF FARM TENANTS. It has been said that “of all men the farmer is naturally the most religious.“ “Yet”, says this writer, “there are_from 5O to 60 per cent. 0f the country people on the prairies and in the uplands the nation over, who have no church connection, and send for the preacher only for the solemnization of marriages and the burial of the dead.” Wherever rural church surveys have been made, it has been found that rural churches are on the decline. This does not mean that every rural church is declining, but there is to be found in every section where surveys have been made many churches that have lost or are losing their vital hold upon the people. This general tendency is as characteristic of the rural landowner as it is of the tenant farmer and the farm laborer. It is a significant fact, however, that there is a vast difference in the degree or religious interests manifested by these several rural groups. The test of the religious interests of any man or group of men can only be measured by the active support of the church of his choice and the interest that it fosters. It is well to em- phasize in this connection that no indictment is being made of the religious intentions of any man belonging to either of the groups that compose our rural population. The writer is familiar with a number of men who are farm tenants, who manifest more interest in the religious welfare of their respec- tive communities than many of their land owning neighbors. But all the information that is available from surveys and care- ful observation clearly indicate that the farm tenant group is manifesting less interest in the church and its enterprises than farm owners who are similarly situated with reference to churches and Sunday schools. Farm Tenantry and the Church in Ohio. In the Ohio Rural Life Survey made under the direction - .--¢q-q 1Henry Wallace on Description of An Ideal Rural Civihzation, in Rural Church Message Chapter 2. page 22. ' 2Ibid, page 23. 298 The Religious Interests of Farm Tenants 299 of the Department of Church and Country Life of the Board of Home Missions of the Presbyterian Church in the U. S. A., the data obtained clearly reveal that the church is not exert- ing so great influence on the tenant farmer as on the farm owner. The following tablel taken from the survey in South- western Ohio illustrates this point: Membership in Church and Lodge Compared Owners Tenants Total l . I . k 4-7 g 4-7 g 43 s § .2 § s I é . a H E 5-4 E $4 ,-,.T_Y.1i.*.=i°_f1‘€*?§f%_*?€f.%.**}.P . 1 s: é a‘: é l- Total . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 193 100.0 136 100.0 329 100.0 Belonging both to church and to lodge or club . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52 26.9 30 22.1 82 24.9 Belonging to lodge or club but not to church . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 15 7.8 21 15.4 36 10.9 Belonging to church but not to lodge or club . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126 65.3 A85 62.5 211 64.2 This table shows that a comparatively small number of either tenants or owners who belong to organizations of any kind belong to lodge or club alone. Less than 25 per cent. belong both to church and lodge or club, while a total of 64.2 per cent. belong to church but do not belong to lodge 0r club. These percentages apply only to those who are reported as having affiliations with organizations of _some kind or other and do not apply to the total number of persons concerning whom data were obtained. The figures show that a large proportion of owners belong to both lodge and church and that the large proportion of those belonging to lodge but not to church is to be found among the tenants. The percentage of those of both groups belonging to church but not to lodge is about the same} A In the survey of the _four counties in Northwestern Ohio where 33.6 per cent. of the farmers are tenants and 65.6 per cent. are owners, it was found that only 13.4 per cent. of the tenants were on the church rolls, while there were 86.6 per - cent. of the owners who maintained church affiliations. The comparisons for each county are as follows: 1Table 43 page 87 and 88. 300 Farm Tenantry in the United States Church Members Farmers Per cent. Per cent. Per cent. Per cent. Cmmty Owners Tenants, c .mQv2§.@r,L_ flillQlalLliL Allen . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70.1 29.9 95.5 14.5 Defiance . . . . . . . . . . . . 72.3 27.7 I 92.3 Hancock . . . . . . . . . . . . 62.0 38.0 86.1 6- - Feneca . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61.4 38.6 81.5 15.5 All four counties . . . . .| 65.6 - 33.6 I 86-6 | 13-4 The general conclusion with reference to the tenant farm- ers’ church afiiliation in Ohio and the reasons for the situation are summarized in the final rural life survey on the “Church Growth and Decline in Ohio” as follows: “In this State throughout the better farming sections ten~ antry on the farms has increased rapidly. The renter follows the good land. Through the counties in the Miami Valley from 40 per cent. to 50 per cent. of the farms are operated by tenants, and in all other sections of the State where farming is relatively prosperous tenant farmers are now a considerable proportion of the population of the rural districts. It is no reflection upon the tenant farmer to say that the church has not yet learned how to reach him. The proportion of tenants to owners in the church membership is seldom as high as the proportion in the total farming population. Butler County’ is an instance of this. Here 41 per cent. of the operating farmers on the land are tenants, but only 22 per cent. of the operating farmers on the church roll are tenants. -A similar condition prevails throughout the State. The church has a slighter hold upon the renter, and it makes slower progress with him than with the land holder. One reason for this ap- pears when we study the question of the stability of the farm- ing population. A house-to-house canvass of three townships in Butler and Preble counties showed that while the average term of occupancy for any given farm is for the farm owner approximately 15 years, for the tenant farmer it is but 4.5 years. There are sections, of course, in which the tenant farmer is relatively a permanentresident. In general he belongs to the _ shifting element in the population, and for that reason he is not a real part of any given community and is less inclined to support its institutions. To have an ever-increasing propor- tion of the population members of a class upon whom the t grqrgfxrw f1» ~s 533, March 22, 1918. I A ditorial. “Contract Between Landlord and Tenant”. Hoard’s Dairyman Sept. 29, 1916, Vol. 52, N0. 10. itorial. “Farm Rental at Shares.” National Stock and Farm, Vol. 40, No. 866, Dec. 2, 1916. rial. “Farm Leases in Iowa.” Wallace’s Farmer, Jan. 7, 1916, Vol. - 41, No. 49. itorial. “Farm-tenantry Problem of the Country Church.” Current Opinion, Vol. 61, No. 406-7. Dec. 1916. ditorial. “Farming Under Five-Year Lease.” Orange Judd Farmer Vol. 60, No. 5, Jan. 29, 1916. .1 _ dito 37, No. 1223, July 31, 1918. n “ditorial. “A Tenant Problem.” Hoard’s Dairyman. Mar. 31, 1916. Vol._ ditoriziléfiiGood Farm Lease.” Ohio Farmer, Vol. 137, No. 454, Mar. 25. laditorial. “Half-and-half System Most Successful.” Jersey Bulletin, Vol. ditorial. “The One-year Tenant.” The Southland Farmer, Oct. 11, 1919. 400 Farm Tenantry in the United States l ,7 f. Editorial. “Has a Farm Tenant Any Rights.” American City, Town an? County, V01. 15, No. 630-7, Dec. 1916. Editorial. “How a Tenant Succeeded.” Progressive Farmer, Vol. 31, No. 1073, Sept. 9, 1916. " Editorial. “High Cost of Idleness.” Country Gentleman, Feb. 19, 1916,75 Vol. 81, N0. 8. Editorial. “Investigating Tenancy Problems in Missouri.” The Progresé. sive Farmer, Oct. 28, 1916. Vol. 31, No. 44. Editorial. “Is Renting Profitable Here?” Orange Judd Farmer, Vol. 65, N04 - 452, Nov. 16, 1918. - Editorial. “Illinois Landlord-Tenant Conference.” Orange Judd Farmer, Farmer, Jan. 1, 1916, Vol. 60, No. 1. f Editorial. “Landlord and Tenants in Partnership.” Orange Judd Farmer, Feb. 26, 1916, Vol. 60, No. 9. Editorial. “Leasing Recommendations.” Hoard’s Dairyman. Sept. 22, 1916, Vol. 52, No. 9. Editorial. “Landlord and Tenant.” American Cooperative Journal, Vol. 12, '7 No. 503, Mar. 1917; Agricultural Digest, Vol. 1, No. 379, Apr. c» 1917. " Editorial. “Let Tenant and Landlord Work Together.” Progressive Farm- er, Vol. 31, No. 1087, Sept. 9, 1916. Editorial. “Landlordism in the Corn Belt.” Wallace’s Farmer, Jan. 21, 1916, Vol. 41, No. 3. Editorial. “More Agricultural Knowledge Needed by Both Landlord and 1 Tenants.” Progressive Farmer, Sept. 9, 1916, Vol. 39, No. 37. ii Editorial. “Make a Business Partner of the Tenant.” Progressive Fann- er, Vol. 32, No. 967, Sept. 15, 1917. Editorial. “Renting a Dairv Farm on Shares.” Hoard’s Dairyman, Sept. 22, 1916, Vol. 52, No. 9. Editoriaé. “AJSStock-Share Lease.” Wallace’s Farmer, Dec. 8, 1916, Vol. 41, o. . Editorial. “Should Farm Owners Raise Rent Now?” Orange Judd Farm- er, Vol. 33, No. 1071, Oct. 5, 1918. Editorial. “Some observations on Land Tenantry in the South.” Pro- . gressive Farmer, Vol. 33, No. 1071, Oct. 5, 1918. Editorial. “Square Deal Will Get and Keen Good Tenants.” Progressive Farmer, Vol. 33, No. 1052, Sept. 28, 1918. Editorial. “Suggested Form of Rental Contract.” Progressive Farmer, Vol. 31, No. 1074, Sept. 9, 1916. Editorial. “Stock-Farming and Renting.” Breeder’s Gazette, Feb. 24, 1916, Vol. 69, No. 8. Editorial. “Try a Profit-sharing Plan with your Labor.” Progressive Farmer, Jan. 12, 1918, Vol. 33, No. 2. Editorial. “The Homestead Law.” Farm and Ranch, Dec. 29, 1918, Vol. 36, No. 52. Editorial. “The Safest Tenant System.” Country Gentleman. Feb. 19, 1916, Vol. 81, No. 8. Editorial. “Tenants and Landowners Should be Business Partners.” Pro- gressive Farmer, Vol. 33, No. 1045, Sept. 28, 1918. Editorial. “Tenantry and Its Place in the Agricultural Labour System, Sweden. International Review of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 64, No. 113-17, Apr. 1916. i RA“ “ha”; Bibliography 401 orial. {Tiéeelsqfog Tenant Homes.” Farm and Ranch, Jan. 31, 1921, V0.3 , o. . y orial. “Tenant Partners 0n Illinois Farms.” The Orange Judd Farm- er, Sept. 30, 1916, V01. 61, N0. 14. torial. “The Farm-tenantry Problem of the Country Church.” Cur- rent Opinion, Dec. 1916, Vol. 59, No. 6, p. 407. ‘torialé ‘1‘The lgrenlant Fagimer and Rural Life.” Wallace’s Farmer, Apr. 2 , 916, 0. 41, o. 17. ‘torial. “Winnebago Farmers’ Model Lease.” TheOrange Judd Farm- er, Feb. 12, 1916, Vol. 60, No. 7. f. ori2il8.3‘(‘)W1l)1ere ltéielgiehéiant Loses.” Wallace’s Farmer. Vol. 43,. No. - , ec. , . ,torial.1“lg7;st3d Iéand on Farms.” Country Gentleman, July 29, 1916, . o . , o. . . ‘ksolré, gnd22(;1(')f1th§3Lanilér3glO1ig1irg Gentleman, Vol. 81, l... o‘ ' 9 " r ' 1 ec- " 7 ~ A Jonezré Ji9E1lk“Tenant Contract.” Ohio Farmer, Vol. 138, No. 515, Nov. Rigliiildinlgggga the Run-down Farm.” Country Life, Vol. 29, . , pri . _ onNJ). (ibgltlarifi Relilitelié oii9F1a6rm Owner.” Rural New Yorker, Vol. 75, ~ . - , arc , . i” thsggi: Iil’. igFlaimggs. ifiiizllgBank Loans.” The Southland Farmer. f ey, Louis H. “Farm Credit Conditions in a Cotton State.” (1914) p Americalili Economic Review, Yo]. 4, pp. 47-67. This article dis: 2131835655; gegtigilnancial difficulties of tenant farmers In a typical 'Hger,2 “ééonlcfiiirtraigori 9o1if7Land Ownership.” Financial World, Vol. E , . , . , . q ‘S, 11% llpégTléoTeéigngs) Ggréeatest Chance.” Country Gentleman, Aug. bard, B- H. "‘Tena " th th St .” _ ' view of AgTiCUIlllgTLIl 13501181111105? yo??? Nd} gpliillvtkggllyllour bard, B- H. “Tenancy in the Southern States.” (1913),. Quarterly Jour- nal of Economics. Vol. 27, p. 482, 496. ‘i; T$iaint41‘ANTen1a7nt’s Experience.” Wallace’s Farmer, April 28, 1916. o . , o. . pp, B. F. “Tenant Farmer and the Poultry Business.” Progressive Farmer, Vol. 33, No. 13, Jan. 5, 1918. H. F. “Farm Leasing.” Hoard’s Dairyman, Vol. 54, No. 650, Nov. 30, 1,; 1917. , - ‘ty, L. N. “What is Right.” National Stock and Farmer, Vol. 40, No. i-i 746, Oct. 21, 1916. “le, William Dee. ‘Oklahoma Tenants Paying for Homes.” Farm and - v Ranch, Oct. 25, 1919, Vol. 38, No. 43. gLanglUtgilzlation in Iowa.” Wallace’s Farmer, Vol. 42, No. , ec. , . ly R. T. “Farm Tractor and the Renter.” Power Farming, Vol. 25, v} , No. 8, Sept. 1916. _ ' ” . fkham, L. A. “Cooperation Between Landlord and Tenant. Progressive Farmer, Vol. 31, No. 1086. Sept. 8, 1916. _ 1 'n, W. A. “Will Tenant Farming Increase?” Ohio Farmer, Vol. 140, No. 422, Nov. 10, 1917. 402 Far/m Tenantry in the United States Massey, W. F. “Better Methods of Land Re tl f L d- ,4 Tenant.” Progressive Farmer, Vol. 31, bllola 107021, seal, g(;),w1n9e1r6_af Miller, H. P. “Farm Tenancy Not an Unmixed Evil.” Ohio Farmer, V 142, N0. 161, Aug. 24, 1918. ‘ ' Miller, H. P. “Terms for Tenancy Partnership.” Ohio Farmer, Vol. 13 No. 126, June 29, 1916. - i O’Brien, H. R. “Ill Fares the Land.” Country Gentleman, Vol. 83, No. Dec. 14, 1918. ; O’Brien, H. R. “If They Make a Dollar So Do We.” Country Gentlem Vol. 83, No. 11-12, Apr. 6, 1918. j O’Brien, H. R. “Why Father’s Tenants Leave.” Hoard’s Dairyman, V0 54, No. 173, Sept. 7, 1917. .1 Papi, C. Mclayage on an Umbrian Estate (Italy). International Revie, of the Science and Practice of Agriculture No. 12:1823-7, De. 1916. ' 1 Parker, L. G. “Farming by the Golden Rule.” Wallace’s Farmer. Oct. I_ a 1916, Vol. 41, No. 41. '1, Parsons, L. E. “Forty Jerseys on Forty Acres.” Jersey Bulletin, Vol. No. 266 Feb. 25, 1916. ‘ - A Peacock, W. M. “Value of Inventories on Rented Farms.” Rural N Yorker, Vol. 76, No. 1462, Dec. 29, 1917. _ . Poe, Clarence. “Legislation Needed by Our Rural Interests.” Progressiv Farmer, Jan. 29, 1916, Vol. 31, No. 5. a Putnam, George E. “Agricultural Credit Legislation and the Tenanc Problem.” (1915) American Economic Review, Vol. 5, p. 805-81 The Writer favors reform in the rent credit system as the initi’; step in reducing farm tenants. - . i-_ Robinson, L. G. Address at convention of National Agricultural S” ciety. Agricultural Digest, Vol. 1, No. 420, May 1, 1917. i; Roosevelt, Theodore. “Will Our Farmers Become a Tenant Class?” Ohi Farmer, Vol. 140, No. 314, Oct. 13, 1917. Roosevelt, Theodore. “American Farmers as a Tenant Class.” Southlan Farmer, Oct. 15, 1917, Vol. 36, No. 16 Ryder, M. Solving Rented Farm Problems. Cooperative Manager and Farmer, Vol. 6, No. 76, Jan. 1917. Series of Letters. “Landlord and Tenant Experiences.” Progressiv Farmer, Oct. 4, 1919, Vol. 34, No. 40. Smith, Alfred VG. “Land-owner-ship.” Country Gentleman, Oct. 9, 1920. Soule, Andrew M. “Renting System in the South.” Breeder’s Gazette, V011 69, No. 10, Mar. 9, 1916. ' Stewart, George. “Can Farms of the United States Pay For Themselves?‘ _ Journal of Farm Economics, Oct. 1920, Vol. 2, No. 4. Taylor, B. R. “The Alabama Tenant Farmer.” Breeder’s Gazette. Jul T 27, 1916, Vol. 70, No. 4. »_ Ten Eyck, A. M. “The Stock-share Lease.” The Country Gentleman, Aug} -12, 1916, Vol. 81, No. 33. 5i Tomlinson, W. S. “Leasing a Dairy Farm.” Ohio Farmer, Vol. 137, No.1; 259, Feb. 19, 1916. j Wallace, H. “Rights of the Land.” Hoard’s Dairyman, Vol. 52, No. 316,”? Sept. 29, 1916. e -{ Warnock, C. W. “The Absentee Landlord Who Demands All-Cotton Rent” Progressive Farmer, Mar. 29, 1919, Vol. 34, No. 13. Watkins, D. W. “A Share Plan For Dairy Tenant Farming.” Hoard’s) Dairyman, Sept. 22, 1916, Vol. 52, No. 9. .3. Ir, Ed. H. “A New Basis For Farm Leases Proposed.” Hoard’s Dairy- lman, Sept. 22, 1916, Vol. 52, No. 9. .Dairyman, May 11, 1917, Vol. 53 " v01. 139, No. s01, June 2s, 1917. n, C. A. “How to Choose a Tenant.” Country Gentleman, Vol. 83, N0. 15, Mar. 23, 1918. n, C. A. “Only Safe Way to Rent a Farm.” Country Gentleman, Vol. 82, No. 1780-1, Nov. 17, 1917. . C. A. “Partners With the Renter.” Country Gentleman, Vol. 83, No. 8, Feb. 2, 1918. n, C. A. “Wanted—Renter For a Farm.” Country Gentleman, Vol. 82, No. 1485, Sept. 29, 1917. ’ , Robert M. “Tenant Is Improving Farm.” Orange Judd Farmer, Feb. 19, 1916, Vol. 60, No. 8. ' 26, 1819. Bibliography 403 , er, Dr. Arthur S. “The Biltmore System of Tenantry.” Hoard’s J. R. “Maintaining Soil Fertility on-a Rented Farm.” Ohio Farmer, , W. B. Tenants and the Homestead Law. Farm and Ranch, Jan. Viiia WILLIAM BENNETT BIZZELL. Born, Independence, Texas, Oct. 14, 1876. B. S., Baylor University, Waco, Texas, 1898; Ph. ‘B., IbidQ-Y 1900; M. A., University of Chicago, 1913. -- Author: Judicial Intrepretation G. P. Putnam’s Sons; The Social teachin‘ ets (1916), Silver Burdette & Co.; Education (1919) in-collaboration with M. H. Duncan; Rand McNally & Co. i? Superintendent, Navasota, Texas public schools 1900-1910;:i President, College of Industrial Arts, Denton, Texas, 1910-1914,’, President, Agricultural and Mechanical College of Texas, Collegxfi Station, Texas, 1914. 404 7; land settlement, p. 39; the l omestead, p. 40; the Deasy, p. _8; the Ashbourne, p. 368. r, J. P. testimony before In- strial Commission on Agri- lture and Labor, p. 275. ley, Professor, on beginning commutation of services, p. ‘f? ns, Chas. s. on thrifty and Jpipriftless tenants, p. 227. tin, Chas. B. on length of ten- ncy, p. 150; on chattel mort- ages, p. 217; on bank credit, -218. tralasia, taxation of land val- in, pp. 345-350. Q r, Ray S. on condition of the w" tenant, pp. 264-269. ‘p, John, his social agitations, s, State farm credit, p. 361. ett, Professor, quoted, p. 30. net, R. L. on a credit rate p. 219. ier, E. A. Farm management, "W _dy of, p. 132. rd, Professor, on ratio of rms to population, p. 180; on norial system Vin New York, ‘lsford, H. N. on new land pol- 1' . in Hungary, p. 332. n, W. G., on spread of im- 4.. gration, p. 164. ' ett, C. W. on cotton produc- ion, p. 168. "flgzornia, land settlement policy p, 1r» W. R. on rural credit, p. “llion, Essay of, p. 45. H. C., criticism of Ricard- f}: theory of rent, pp. 91, 92. Professor, on immigra- l’! p. 107. er, Professor,_ influence of ‘rginal production on rent, p. on agricultural income, p. ‘on the single tax, p. 339. .. the Agricultural Holdings, p.’ 405 INDEX. Cato, on the Roman villa, p. 14. Chance, A. E. on tenantry in Mass. p. 126. . Cheviot estate, confiscation of, p. 350 Clark, F. B., tenantry study‘ by, p. 228‘; on rural housing of farm tenants, pp. 276 and 277. Colonization, land, p. 363; forms of, p. 363; Wisconsin plan of, p. 365. Coman, Miss, on manorial system in this country, p. 34; on cap_- italistic farming, p. 162 Coulanges, de Fustel, on land na- tionalization, p. 321. Contract, transition from status to, p. 21 Corn, production of, pp. 169-171. Cotton, production of, p. 163. County, Ellis, farm management study in, pp. 136, 137. Credit, what Texas farmers pay for, p. 212; influence of bank loans on, p. 214; long-term rural, p. 354; short-term rural, p. 358; middle or intermediate, p. 360 Davis, E. E. rural school study of, p. 292. Denmark, land policy in, p. 370. Dickson, H. M. farm management, study of, p. 134. Durand, E. Dana, on tenantry in Minn. p. 125. Enclosures, effect on the farm tenant, p. 23. Ely, Richard T. on the tenantry problem, p. 309; on private col- onization of land, p. 364. Farmer, Wallace's, quoted p. 148. Foard, W. E., Farm management, study of, pp. 143 and 290. Fordham; Montague, classifica- tion of services and rentals, p. 1i; description of enclosures, p. 2 . George, Henry, on our public land system, pp. 36 and 41; on the theory of rent, p. 83; on the theory of private property in 406 INDEX Interest, rates of, on farm loans; p. 215; factors affecting ratesf land, p. 322; on the single tax, p. 343. Gide and Rist, quoted, pp. 48, 49 and 50. Gillette, Professor, on influences of immigration on tenantry, p. 256. Goldenweiser, E. A. on tenantry in New England, p. 124; farm management study of, p. 132. Hale, J. H. on housing of farm tenants, p. 278. Hamilton, Alexander, on policy of land settlement, p. 38. Hammond, Harry, testimony be- fore Industrial COIIIIYIISSIOII on Agriculture and Labor, p. 275. Haney, Professor, on J. S. Mill, p. 66. Hasbach, W. on motive for en- closure, p. 26. Hawthorne, H. W. farm manage- ment, study of, p. 134. Hayes, professor, on immigration, p. 108 Hedrick, W. O. defense of tenan- try, p. 312. Hills, A. L., on tenantry in Ver- mont, p. 125. Holdisch, Sir Thos. H., on land policy in India, p. 330. Holmes, George K., a farm man- agement study by, p. 158. Hookworm, cause of, p. 232. Hopkins, on law relating to fix- tures, p. 95. Housing, rural in England, pp. 281-293; reforms in, p. 283; standards in, p. 285. Houston, D. F., on tenantry, p. 316. Immigration, policy of, p. 107. Income Agricultural, definition of, p. 128; Labor, definition of, ,p. 128; in cotton belt, p. 132; in grain belt, p. 138; influence of manpower on, p. 140; in- fluence of type of farming on, p. 141; influence of size of farm on, p. 143. Individualism, as a factor in ten- antry, p. 235. Intellectual, interests of farm ten- ants, p. 288. of, p. 217. Jackson, J. T. on the Agricultural‘, Holdings Acts, p. 27. Johnson, A. H., on developmentof lease system, p. 21; on enclof sures, p. 25. Johnson, E. C. on tenantry in; Kansas, p. 126. Johnson, O. R. farm manageg ment, study of, pp. 144 and ; 290. ' Jones, Richard, theory of rent, p. :1 88; classification of rent, pp. 89-91; on relation between, landlord and tenant, p. 91. Justice, social, p. 197. Kansas, tenantry in, p. 118. King, W. I. on farm areas, p. 147. _ Land, tenure, influence of the revolution on, p. 36; nationali- a zation of, pp. 320, 321; monoply in, p. 340; values, speculation: in, pp. 374-377. Langland, William, quoted, p. 23. » Laveleye, de M., on land nation- alization, p. 321. Lease, essentials of, p. 197; stand- ard form of p. 198; social jus- .1 tice in p. 198-206; a model, ‘i 206 Leonard, W. E. on tenantry in l Texas, p. 1 19. Lindsey, S. A., on farm loans as an aid to tenants, p. 357. Lloyd, O. G., on labor income, p.“ ‘ 138; on age of acquiring own- 8I'Sl'11p, p. 150; on leases, p. 188. Macdonald, William, on unit acre- age for irrigation farms, p. 173. Malthus, quoted, p. 59; on rent, p. 60; hIS point of view, p. 60. Massachusetts, credit unions in . p. 353 Maurer, von G. L., on land nation- alization, p. 321. McClure Archibold on the Poles as farmers, p. 241; on effort to colonize the Jew on farms, o. 243; on the Japanese farmer, p. . McMillan, S. A., farm manage- ment, study of, p. 289. Mercantilists, ignored agricul-i ture, p. 43. ' ‘ill, J. S., quoted 66, 67; influ- 1 ence of Malthus on, pp. 68 and 5 76; interest in producer, p. 69; on private property, pp. 69, 70; ' on policy of leasing, p. 71; on land nationalization, p. 72; his ,_ classification of tenants, pp. 72- 77; his remedy for tenantry, g pp. 77-79: on rent, pp. 92, 93; on large and small scale produc- ;,tion, p. 177. iiller, H. P. on system of leasing, p. 193. illis, H. A. on efficiency of Jap- *1 anese farmer, P. 246. virabeau, Marquis of, on increas- ing food production, p. 43; on relation of food supply to the ;populat1on, p. 44; his writings, p. 44. vissouri, Land Bank Act of, p. 355. _ p. 24. eorgan, J. 0., on crop rotation, 'p. 172. ‘uzzy, Professor, on colonial pro- 1prietors, p. 33 ebraska, tenantry in, p. 118. _egro, as a farm tenant, p. 257. emours, de Dupont, p. 48; con- {ception of Physiocracy, p. 50. rth Carolina, credit unions in, ip. 353. den, Professor, on location of 'i‘rural homes, p. 280; on health égraditions in the country, p. ilvile, William, on reform of i‘ he tenantry situation, p. 383. io, rural life surveys in pp. 28s, 289. ’ 1ahoma, tenantry in, pp 118, 319; rural credit act of, p. 355. hanization, feudal, p. 13. ‘ Thos. Nelson, on property Wning by negroes. et, Sir Richard, on division of ‘ ome between landlord and It‘ (‘D - le, Thomas, on “Agrarian Jus- Ace,” p. 384. ilegra, its cause, p. 232. et, Walton, on farm credit, p. ~ 2. INDEX » 407 Physiocrats, real founders of pol- itical economy, p. 43; theory of net product, p. 47. ?oe, Clarence, on influence of rural organization on tenantry, p. 236. Policie 329. Pratt, E. A. on tenantry, p. 311. Pritchett, H. S., on rural educa- tion, p. 235. Prothero, on organization of the manor, p. 14; quoted, pp. 61 and 176. Pugsley, C. W., on tenantry in Nebraska, p. 125. Putnam, Geo. E., on tenantry in Kansas, p. 118. land nationalization, p. Quesnay, quoted, pp. 43, 45, 46, " his writings, p. 44; argument for large farms, p 45; on th_e distributive process, p. 46; his table, p. 47. Quick, Herbert, on speculation in land values, pp. 376, 376. Rayner, O. S., on tenantry in Col- orado, p. 127. Rent, the conception of, p. 81; contract, p. 95; nature of on the manor, p. 18; systems of, pp. 97- 103. Revolt, the peasant’s, p. 23. Ricardo, impersonal view of, p. 61; theory of rent, p. 62; defi- nition of rent, p. 89; criticism of his rent theory, p. 88. Rogers, Professor, on rent, p. 103. Ross, E. A. on distribution of Ger- man farmers, p. 244. Russia, socialization of land in, pp. 333, 334. ' Say, J. B. his writings, p. 58. Scheftel, Yetta, on taxation of land values, p. 339; on progres- sive land tax, p. 348. Seager, Professor, on rent, p. 81 and 96 Seebohm,‘ on origin of manor, pp. 14, 17 Seligman, Professor, on objects of taxation, pp. 337, 338; on graduated land tax, p. 347. Sismondi, his ethical viewpoint, p. 62; his writings, p. 63; his sym- pathy for the tenant, p. 64. Small, A. W., quoted, pp. 56 and 4% 58; on social content of Wealth of Nations, p. 57. Smith, Adam, economics of farm tenantry, p. 51; on law of in- heritance, p. 52; criticism of landowners ,p. 52; relative merits of systems of cultivation, p. 54; quoted pp. 54, 56; on the long lease, p. 55; on rent, pp. 83 and 84. Spillman, W. J. on “climbing the agricultural ladder,” p. 111; on iigniantry in New England, p. Stull, William, gages, p. 160. System, half-and-half, p. 97; share rent, p. 98; stock share- renting, p. 98; bushel rent, p. 99;_cash rent, p. 99; modifica- tion of, p. 100; the Torrens, pp. 377, 378. Taussig, Professor, 0n rent, p. 81; on margin of cultivation, p. 87; on theory of land nationaliza- tion, p. 335. Taylor, Professor, on land values, p_. 153; on tenantry in Wiscon- sin, p. 157. Tenancy, relation to labor income, p. 143. Tenantry, farm; increase in, p. 111; distribution of, p. 117; transition state, "p. 111; scope of problem of, p. 113; summary of social and economic effects of p. 114 and 115; a problem of, stated and solved, pp. 129-131. Tenants, classes on manorial es- tate, p. 15; labor income of, p. 132. on farm mort- INDEX Texas, tenantryin, p. 118; law on rural credit, p. 354. Thatcher and Swill, on nature of rents on manorial estate, p. 18. Thompson, C. W. on rates, p. 216. interest Tichenor, Prof. on basis of leas- . ing, p. 188. Varro, description of Roman villa, p. 14 Vinogradoff, Paul, on commuta- tion of services, p. 20. Violet, P. on land nationalization, p. 321. ' .. manna-thy. Vogt, Paul, on age of tenants, p. 149; on health conditions in the country, p. 231; on rural hous- ing, pp. 273, 274. Wallace, H. R., on land nationali- zation, pp. 323-325. Warwick, Countess of, on land, na- c tionalization, p. 328. Washington, Booker T., on the negro farmer, p. 269. Webster, Ed. H. on division of in- come between landlord and tenant, p. 190. White, E. V., on tenantry in Tex- as, p. 119; influence of tenant- ry on schools, p. 293. Williams, W. T. B. on the negro exodus from the South, p. 271. Wilson, W. R., on cause of rural church decline, p. 152. Woofter, F. J., on cause of exodus of negroes from the South, p. 271. Young, A., quoted, pp. 26, 113, 310. .