'\ a -" 5-155 March 198 30C ' FA245.7 g3l6€Y i . r » -. ' l'llBRARY APR 1 4 1987 BXM A5- M Universitv Effect of Proposed Port User Fees on Export Grain Flow Pattern The Texas Agricultural Experiment Stationl Neville P. Clarke, Direetor/The Texas A&M University SystemA/Qfioilege Station, Texas ~- Table of Contents Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 The Port User Charge . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 The Nature of Funds Subject to Recovery . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 The Research Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 Objectives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2 Methodology and Procedures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2 Effect of Port User Charge on Grain Trade: Methodology and Procedures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3 User Charge Estimation Procedure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3 User Charge Scenarios Based on Ports’ Operations and Maintenance Costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4 User Charge Scenarios Based on Ports’ New Construction Costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4 User Charge Scenarios Based on Combined Operations and Maintenance and New Construction Costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4 Estimated User Charges . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 Estimating the Market Effect of Port User Fees . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 Effect of Port User Charge on Export Grain A Flow Patterns: Empirical Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 Weight-Based, Port-Specific User Fee . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 Weight-Based, Uniform User Fee . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 Ad Valorem-Based, Port-Specific User Fee . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 Ad Valorem-Based, Uniform User Fee . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 Altered Flows and Port Elevator Capacity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 Summary and Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 Literature . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12 Appendix I. Technical Discussion of Methods and Procedures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 Procedure to Estimate the Effect of User Charges on Grain Trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 Effect of Weight-Based Port User Charges . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 Effect of Ad Valorem Port User Charges . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 Elasticity Estimation Procedures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16 Appendix II. The Grain Transportation Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18 General Description of Grain Network Flow Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19 Data Requirements of Grain Network Flow Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 Market-Related Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 Transportation-Related Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 Validation of Transportation Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 Appendix III. Further Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 Effect of Proposed Port User Fees on Export Grain Flow Patterns Hector Viscencio-Brambila formerly, Assistant Research Scientist Department of Agricultural Economics Texas A&M University Stephen W. Puller Professor Department of Agricultural Economics Texas A&M University Preface Historically, the federal government has funded the maintenance and construction of the nation's deep-draft ports. However, legislation has been submitted to the U.S. Congress which would allow the federal government to recover a portion of these costs through imposition of port user charges. Farm interests are concerned that user charges would increase the price of U.S. agricultural commodities, reducing export volumes and their income. The purposes of this research are to evaluate the effect of the proposed deep-draft port user fee on export grain flow patterns and export levels and provide insight into potential marketing adjustment costs which may result from diverted flows. Acknowledgements The authors express appreciation to the U.S. Department of Agriculture and the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers for counsel provided during this project. Substantial contributions were made by Bill Gallimore and Jim MacDonald of Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture. Special appreciation is expressed to Fred Ruppel for improving the exposition of Appendix I, in particular that portion dealing with the effects of user charges on international markets. Appreciation is expressed to reviewers Orlo Sorenson, Kansas State University; Mack Leath, U.S. Department of Agriculture, University of Illinois; and Don Farris and Warren Grant, Department of Agricultural Economics, Texas A&M University. This research was partially supported through U.S. Department of Agriculture cooperative agreement number 58-3523-2- 034. '\\_ a Effect of Proposed Port User Fees on Export Grain Flow Patterns Introduction The Port User Charge In the past few years, more than 30 pieces of proposed legislation have been submitted to the U.S. Congress that, among other things, would allow the federal government to recover a portion or all of the operations and maintenance expenses and the capital expenditures incurred in keeping the nation's deep- draft facilities navigable. The legislative efforts pro- pose a variety of user charge schemes as well as various cost sharing formulas between federal and nonfederal jurisdictions as a means to preclude fur- ther subsidization of commercial deep-draft naviga- tion. Some legislators have favored weight-based user fees while others have favored ad valorem-based user fees. Either type of fee would be applied on a port- specific or uniform basis. Port-specific fees would be based on the unique costs at each port whereas a uniform fee would represent a flat fee to all ports. Further, there is debate over which expenditures should be recovered by the user fee. Some legislation proposes fees which recoupe new construction costs, others propose recovery of operations and mainte- nance costs, while some call for recovery of both costs. Possible imposition of a port user charge has raised concerns among farm interests, port authorities, and transport operators. Farmers are concerned that user charges would increase the prices of U.S. agricultural commodities—reducing export volumes and, thus, their income. Port authorities are concerned that such levies could alter grain flow patterns, ports’ market areas, and interport competition. If grains flows are diverted, the viability of railroads and barge firms may be unfavorably affected on some transportation cor- ridors. This might render location of the marketing system infrastructure inappropriate. The Nature of Funds Subject to Recovery Several federal programs administered by the Coast Guard, the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers, and the Economic Development Administration (U.S. Depart- ment of Commerce) support commercial navigation on deep-draft harbors, ports, and channels. Federal resources are expanded to cover operations and maintenance costs of the existing port system as well as construction of new facilities. For purposes of this study, operations and mainte- nance costs include those costs incurred by the Army Corps of Engineers in maintenance of the existing ports’ navigation facilities. New port construction costs also are an important expense of the federal government. Port areas require two types of new construction. First, there are expenditures for infra- structure which complement port operation (piers, etc.). These investments are generally made by the local jurisdiction. Then, there are new construction expenditures made by the federal government (Army Corps of Engineers) which involve the deepening, widening, or lengthening of channels; it is these expenditures which are to be recovered with user fees. The Research Problem International trade represents a vital economic ac- tivity for the U.S. farm sector. Grains and soybeans are the U.S.'s principal agricultural exports, accounting for over 6O percent of the value of U.S. farm exports in 1983. The value of U.S. grain and soybean exports and related products, moreover, increased almost sev- enfold during the 1970-81 period, and accounted for 30 percent of the U. S. farm income (Cramer and Heid). During the marketing year 1981-82, U.S. farmers produced 16.8, 47.6, 32.4, and 62.6 percent of the world's total wheat, corn and other coarse grains, and soybeans, respectively. In calendar year 1981, the U.S.'s share of world exports amounted to 40, 58, and 37 percent, respectively, for food grains, feed grains, and oil crops and meal. Price competition is a major economic aspect of grain and soybean world markets. The viability of a grain exporter, such as the United States, rests on its ability to remain price competitive. The existence of 1 aggressive grain exporters such as Argentina, Austra- lia, Thailand, and Brazil makes it difficult to remain a competitive supplier to the world market (Paggi; Longmire and Morey). If a user charge is approved, the increase in transportation costs will increase the price of U.S. grain and soybean exports to importing nations and subsequently reduce U.S. sales and farm prices} Whether or not the user charge would signifi- cantly impact U.S. grain and soybean exports and agricultural products is an empirical question and depends upon the type and size of the fee as well as on the supply and demand relationships prevailing in the world markets. In summary, the levying of a user charge on deep- draft ports raises the following issues: (1) To what extent will U.S. exports of grain and soybeans be affected? (2) How will competition among U.S. ports change? and (3) Will grain and soybean flow patterns be significantly altered? This study attempts to answer these questions for selected commodities (wheat, corn, sorghum, and soybeans). Objectives The purpose of this study is to evaluate the effect of port user charges on the U.S. export grain economy. Specific objectives are: 1. Develop a procedure to estimate the size of a user charge under various scenarios, based on recent legislation proposed by Congress. 2. Estimate how the proposed user charge affects foreign demand for U.S. produced wheat, corn, sorghum, and soybeans. 3. Estimate the impacts of the user charge on U.S. and export grain flow patterns. 4. Analyze the extent to which the user charge would change the competitive positions of U.S. ports. 5. Provide insight into potential logistical inefficien- cies which may result from the diverted grain flows. Methodology and Procedures Based on available legislative initiatives, a proce- dure to estimate user charges will be developed. lConceivably the deepening of harbors and channels (new construc- tion) would facilitate the use of larger carriers and, because of economies of ship size, rates on routes which link deep water ports would decline. In which case, the reduced rate may offset or partially offset the proposed user charge. Although this may occur for some commodities on selected routes, there was limited evi- dence that this effect would be widespread for bulk grain carriage. First, many of the world's grain-receiving ports have less water than the U.S. ports which are candidates for new construction. In which case, the destination or foreign port is the constraint to the use of larger vessels. The important exceptions are several major ports in western Europe, Taiwan, and Japan. In addition, it has been observed that evolving ship size is not satisfactorily explained by the assumption that port constraints determine ship size, i.e., there are other factors than port water depth which limit or affect optimum ship size (Kendall). Kendall shows that ship costs, terminal costs (port, handling, and storage costs), annual volume of trade, length of voyage, etc. , interact to determine optimum ship size. 2 Second, an economic procedure based on an interna- tional trade model will be required to estimate the effect of a port user charge on grain prices and quantities traded in the international and U.S. domes- ' tic markets. Finally, transportation models for each commodity, modified to account for relevant changes in ocean shipping rates and in quantities supplied and demanded in all involved markets, will be used to estimate the effect of a port user charge on export grain flow patterns. ‘l Because no legislation has been enacted to date, user charge scenarios will be generated based on major features of the many pieces of proposed legisla- tion. These include (1) the type of fee, weight- or ad valorem-based; (2) the fee's form, (port-specific or uniform); (3) the nature of costs subject to recovery (operations and maintenance costs and/or capital expenditures); and (4) the level of cost recovery; i.e., the cost-sharing formula between federal and nonfed- eral jurisdictions. The interaction of excess supply and demand rela- tionships determines prices and quantities traded in the international grain and soybean markets. There exists a vast amount of economic literature dealing with econometric models which estimate grain supply relationships in international spatial equilibrium mod- els which include both supply and demand relation- ships as well as grain flow patterns (Grennes, John- son, and Thursby; Barr; Rausser). To estimate changes in prices and quantities in all relevant markets, a simple international trade model involving an export- ing country (the United States), and an aggregate importing country (the rest of the world) is developed. This is shown in Appendix I. In addition, Appendix I describes the procedure used to evaluate the effect of weight- and ad valorem-based fees on markets. Spatial models have been successfully used to ana- lyze grain and soybean flow patterns regionally, na- tionally, and internationally (Leath and Blakely; Makus; Taylor; Fuller and Shanmugham; Barnett, Binkley, and McCarl). Multiperiod, network flow models, originally developed by Taylor and later up- dated by Makus, are employed in an attempt to quantify the impact of a user charge on export grain flow patterns. Taylor developed transportation mod- To test Kendall's notion that ship size on various routes is affected by other factors than port water depth, data on grain ship size were collected for routes linking U.S. Gulf and Pacific Northwest ports with Japan. If water depth was the principal constraint, larger carriers would travel the Pacific Northwest to Japan route (Yokoha- ma port) since both of these ports have deeper water (45-60 feet). (Lloyds 1984 Ports of the World). Basedon 1984 data, ship size on the Pacific Northwest route ranged from about 14,000 to 61,000 DWT with an average of 47,730 DWT (140 observations). On the Gulf route, ship size ranged from 25,000 to 53,000 DWT with an average of 48,550 DWT (176 observations). This outcome tends to support Kendall's work since it shows similar size vessels operating on both routes, i.e., other factors than port water depth appear to be affecting ship size on these routes. Kendall's work implies that a deepened harbor may not substan- tially increase the size of grain carriers which frequent a port, in which case, rates may not be lowered. As a result, the user charg would not be offset by a lowered ship rate. For these reasons, it was assumed that any new construction which was financed through user fees would increase ship rates. els for various commodities including wheat, corn, grain sorghum, and soybeans. In addition, separate odels were developed for hard, soft, and durum g heats. In this study, the hard wheat model will be disaggregated into two models to account for dif- ferences in the geography of production and con- sumption of hard red winter and spring wheats. The spatial models used in this study include grain and ‘soybean surplus producing regions, domestic grain ‘ deficit regions, barge loading locations, grain shipping ports, and foreign demand regions. Four modes of transportation are specified which include truck, rail, barge, and ocean shipping vessels. See Appendix II for an overview of the spatial model used in this study Effect of Port User Charge on Grain Trade: Methodologies and Procedures To evaluate the effect of port user charges on export grain flow patterns, it is necessary to estimate (1) increases in ocean shipping rates that result from imposition of the user charge, and (2) market effects of the user charge; that is, the changes in prices and quantities traded in the international and U.S. domes- tic grain markets. The purpose of this section is to describe the methodologies and procedures used to obtain these estimates. The first section details the user charge estimation procedure. In the second sec- tion, methodologies and procedures to approximate the effects of port user fees on grain markets are developed. Per-Unit Port-Specific Proposed Legislation User Charge i __ User Charge i? User Charge Estimation Procedure As stated earlier, various types of user charge schemes have been proposed. Figure 1 illustrates all aspects of the proposed user charge and accordingly identifies features of this user fee which must be taken into consideration by the estimation procedure. The port user charge scenarios are based on proposed legislation and opinions of transportation experts from the U.S. Department of Agriculture and the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers. Table 1 presents the formulae used to estimate user charges which recoupe operations and maintenance expenses. A uniform user charge implies a flat rate applied to all ports regardless of a port's incurred costs or tonnage. Thus, this type of user fee is obtained through division of all ports’ operations and mainte- nance costs by all ports’ tonnage (weight-based) or the value of all ports’ commerce (ad valorem-based). Formulae 1 and 3 in Table 1 were used to estimate the weight-and ad valorem-based uniform user charges. Port-specific user charge estimates take into account the costs, tonnage, and value of commerce transiting each port. This user fee is calculated by dividing the operations and maintenance costs of each port by the port's tonnage (weight-based) or the value of all commerce transiting a port (ad valorem-based). For- mulae 2 and 4 in Table 1 are used to estimate these respective charges. Formulae to estimate user fees which recover new construction costs are obtained by replacing "operations and maintenance expenses” which appear in the various formulae in Table 1 with I‘ Ad Valorem i __J Uniform User Charge User Charge -- Corn Operations and _ 50 Percent __ Sowhum Maintenance Costs Cost Recovery li Soybeans New Hard Red Construction Costs WW6‘ W719i" Hard Red Spring Wheat Operations and Maintenance and 100 Percent __J i so“ wheat New Construction Cost Recovery Costs i‘ Durum Wheat Figure 1. Diagrammatic representation of the various features of the proposed user charges. Table 1. Formulae Used to Estimate Port User Fees Number Formula Weight-Based User Charge (PUUC) (1) Uniform PUUC = All Ports’ Tonnage (2) Individual Port-Specific PUUC = Port Tonnage f, a; Ad Valorem User Charge (AVUC) (3) Uniform AVUC = All POFIS’ OM COStS All Ports’ Value of Volume Serviced (4) Individual Port-Specific AVUC = port's OM Costs Port's Value of Volume Serviced ‘OM = operations and maintenance. "new constructions costs." User fees which include both costs are estimated by simply aggregating the two costs (operations and maintenance, new con- struction). User Charge Scenarios Based on Ports’ Operations and Maintenance Costs Data on ports’ operations and maintenance costs were obtained from the publication entitled, “Deep Draft Navigation Cost Recovery Analysis,” prepared by the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers Office and the Chief of Engineers Directorate of Civil Works Office of Policy, published in September 1982. Specifically, Table 110.1-D in the publication provides data on operations and maintenance costs that are subject to cost re- covery. Data on the value of products and commodities moving through individual ports, with an adjustment for volumes shipped to domestic locations were ob- tained from Table 501-D of the above document. Operations and maintenance costs and dollar-value of port commerce are expressed in 1982 constant dollars. Tonnage figures correspond to 1981 data. Data on annual operations and maintenance costs, tonnage, and value of port commerce are summarized in Table 2. Data are provided for the 16 grain-shipping port areas. A port area may involve more than one port; e.g., the New Orleans port area comprises the port of New Orleans, Baton Rouge, and the Mississippi River segment connecting these two ports. User Charge Scenarios Based on Ports’ New Construction Costs To estimate new construction costs, it is assumed that ports finance these expenditures through debt zThere is some disagreement among engineers regarding the opera- tions and maintenance costs necessary to maintain ports after their improvement. The U.S. Army Corps of Engineers advised that the current operations and maintenance costs were good estimates of these costs. If current costs underestimate the operations and maintenance costs associated with new construction, the projected flow levels will be biased downward. 4 capital (bonds). This assumption can be justified on several grounds. First, since this type of construction does not represent a voluntary investment project, there is no a priori reason why the port authority should consider it as part of their investment port- folio. Second, historically, ports have financed their needs for funds mostly through general obligation bonds and revenue bonds. Third, the decision to issue bonds is largely influenced by the growth rate of fixed assets at the port. Long-term assets are often financed through long-term debt. Fourth, the cost of capital of externally-raised funds is frequently lower than that of internal sources (equity or new stock). Two important reasons accounting for the latter are (1) interest costs on debt capital are tax deductible while dividends are not, reducing the cost of debt relative to that of equity capital; and (2) through bonds, firms are committed to pay a fixed return to bondholders to maturity of the issue, which provides protection against interest rate fluctuations. The yield used in this study represents an average over the period 1977-83 and is comprised of annual rates for corporate and general obligation bonds with maturities of at least 2O years, weighted by the type of port ownership (Table 3). Due to the fact that there are numerous port projects subject to cost recovery, with various government agencies and pri- vate corporations involved, bonds of mixed quality were thought to to be most appropiate. Table 4 pre- sents these yields as well as the weighted average rates for each year. It was assumed that an annuity would appropri- ately reflect the average effect of the callability and the serial features of the involved bond types. Table 5 provides each port's new construction costs and the annuities necessary to pay bondholders, under vari- ous government cost recovery scenarios. User Charge Scenarios Based on Combined Operations and Maintenance and New Construction Costs The formulae presented in Table 1 are used to estimate port charges which incorporate the ag- Table 2. U.S. Ports’ Annual Operations and Maintenance Costs Subject to Recovery‘ Operations and ‘I Authorized Maintained Maintenance 1981 Value of ' ort State Depth Depth Costs Tonnage Commerce feet feet $1,000 1,000 ton $1,000 Mobile AL 4O 40 5,303.2 19,541.3 3,119,252.680 New Orleansz LA 40 40 23,037.9 133,421.8 45,466,130.007 Galveston3 TX 40 40 9,093.6 78,189.5 35,570,810.519 ‘Iorpus Christi TX 45 45 6,130.9 31 ,525.8 5,719,312.431 I Brownsville TX * * * * 939,397.327 Charleston SC 35 35 5,483.2 8,231.5 8,802,356.191 Baltimore MD 50 42 2,420.9 39,035.7 18,192,283.640 Toledo OH 28 28 3,493.1 22,279.7 1 ,594,432.189 Saginaw Ml 27 27 6,730.2 2,281.7 179,569.765 Chicago IL 28 28 1 ,O20.2 1 3,155.0 1 ,582,631.819 Duluth‘ MN 28 28 2,384.1 39,425.1 2,492,417.947 Seattles WA 34 34 428.2 25,035.1 16,815,769.829 Portland“ OR 48 40 19,063.8 26,712.3 7,483,840.144 San Francisco’ CA 40 40 2,414.7 7,538.3 3,308,574.950 Long Beach“ CA 45 45 144.0 66,9994 44,581,706.615 San Diego CA 35 35 * 2,344.6 7,916,599.482 Subtotal 87,148.0 516,166.8 203,495,085.535 Other Ports 249,357.2 1,157,828.2 198,963,869.310 Total All Ports 336,505.2 1,673,995.0 402,458,954.845 Source: ”Deep-Draft Navigation Costs Recovery Analysis," U.S. Army Corps of Engineers, September 1982; August 1984. ‘All dollar figures in 1982 constant dollars. Zlncludes New Orleans and Baton Rouge, LA. 3lncludes Galveston and Houston, TX. ‘Includes Duluth, MN and Superior, MI. Slncludes Seattle and Tacoma, WA. ‘Includes Portland and Astoria, OR and Kalama and Longview, WA. 7lncludes San Francisco, Stockton, and Sacramento, CA. “Includes Long Beach and Los Angeles, CA. *Not available. gregated operations and maintenance and new con- struction costs. The U.S. Army Corps of Engineers advised that current operations and maintenance costs would be reasonable estimates of these costs for any anticipated new construction activity. Estimated User Charges User charge estimates are reported in Table 6 and correspond to a 100 percent cost recovery level. User charge estimates for other cost-sharing arrangements between federal and local jurisdictions can be ob- tained by multiplying the 100 percent estimate by the Qppropriate cost-sharing percentage. In general, the estimated charges are small. For example, a weight-based, uniform fee designed to recoupe operations and maintenance costs averages about $0.006 per bushel ($0.201/ton). A similar type of fee which recovers new construction is estimated to be about $0.012 perf bushel ($0.4436/ton), whereas the combined costs are estimated to be slightly less than $0.02 per bushel ($0.6446/ton). Although the es- timated charges are relatively small, there is substan- ; ' l variation among ports. For example, four port ;. reas have estimated weight-based fees which re- coupe operations and maintenance costs that are less than $0.0025 per bushel, and seven ports with fees that are less than $0.005 per bushel. In constrast, the Saginaw, Michigan port area has an estimated weight- based fee which is nearly $0.09 per bushel ($2.94/ton). Similar variation exists among fees designed to re- coupe new construction costs. Because Congress has not authorized this new construction, four grain port areas have no new construction costs. Congress has thus far not appropriated funds for any port. Estimating the Market Effect of Port User Fees’ Port user fees would increase ocean shipping rates that link the United States with foreign buyers. In the short run, the price of the commodity in the importing country will rise and the quantity demanded will decline. U.S. grain producers will find their export market has decreased. This is due to increased grain output of the importing regions and the reduced quantity demanded by these regions. The costs of production (marginal) will increase with output in the importing countries and decline in the United States as output levels decrease. The extent to which the burden of the ship rate increase will be shared between the United States and importing regions depends, among other things, up- on the importance of the importing region's demand for the commodity and the elasticities of supply and 5 Table 3. U.S. Port Ownership Categories by Coastal Region Type of Ownership Region State Local Private percent North Atlantic 28 24 48 South Atlantic 34 32 34 Gulf 8 44 48 South Pacific 10 61 29 North Pacific 0 48 52 Great Lakes 4 19 77 National Average 12 37 51 Source: National Port Assessment 1980/1990, An Analysis of Fu- ture U.S. Port Requirements. U.S. Department of Com- merce, Maritime Administration, Office of Port and Inter- modal Development. June 1980. Table 4. Interest Rates for Municipal and Corporate Bonds Bond Rates Weighted Year Municipals‘ Corporatez Rate percent 1977 5.68 8.19 6.96 1978 6.03 8.97 7.52 1979 6.52 10.02 8.30 1980 8.59 12.70 10.69 1981 11.33 15.46 13.43 1982 11.66 14.45 13.08 1983 9.51 12.15 10.86 Average 8.47 11.70 10.12 Source: Federal Reserve Bulletin. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, D.C. (various is- sues). ‘Bond Buyer's Series. General obligations only, with 20-year matur- ity; issued by 20 state and local government units of mixed quality. Based on figures for Thursday. 2Aaa Utility Bonds. Compilation of the Federal Reserve. Issues included are long-term (20 years or more). Offered issues on Friday close-of-business quotations. demand in the United States and importing regions. Assuming that the import demand is a significant portion of total demand, the U.S. export price will decrease by a greater amount (and the domestic price in the importing country will increase by a smaller amount) the less elastic is U.S. demand and supply. Thus, the United States will bear much of the burden if its domestic demand and supply are inelastic. A complete analysis of the various forces becomes too involved and detailed to present here. See Appendix I for a procedure to estimate the effect of the various user charges. Based on the procedure outlined in Appendix I, the estimated effects of the various proposed port user fees on prices and quantities produced and traded are calculated. Table 7 identifies the estimated percent change in quantity demanded by foreign buyers of U.S. grain, the percent change in quantity supplied by 6 Table 5. Estimated Costs of lmprovement and New Construction of U.S. Deep-Draft Port Areasl Total Estimated Port Cost Payment (million $) Mobile, AL 447.72 47.97 New Orleans 525.00 56.25 Galveston 595.00 j. 63.75 Corpus Christi 92.02 = 9.86 h. Brownsville -— — Charleston 80.10 8.65 Baltimore 400.00 42.86 Toledo -— — Saginaw — — Chicago — — Duluth 10.78 1.15 Seattle 82.24 8.81 Portland 3.16 0.34 San Francisco 276.60 29.64 Long Beach 460.00 49.29 San Diego — — Total 2,973.22 318.56 Other Ports 3,957.86 424.06 All U.S. Ports 6,931.08 742.62 30-year Annuity Source: U.S. Army Corps of Engineers, Washington, D.C. “All figures in 1982 dollars. U.S. producers, and percent change in U.S. domestic consumption. As expected, the supply and foreign demand for U.S. grain declines while domestic U.S. consumption increases. In general, the ad valorem- based fees have the least effect on quantities produced and traded. Table 8 relates the estimated impact on domestic and international grain prices that results from imposing various types of user fees. The analysis reveals only modest price increases and declines in the international and U.S. domestic markets, respectively. Again, the ad valorem-based fee appears to have the least effect on prices. Effect of Port User Charge on Export Grain Flow Patterns: Empirical Results This section includes discussion of weight-based and ad valorem-based fees, both of which may be levied on a port-specific or uniform basis. In addition, the analysis evaluates the effect of recovering opera- tions and maintenance expenses as well as new con- struction expenditures. The analysis assumes 100 per- cent recovery of costs by local jurisidictions. Altered flows associated with a 50 percent cost recovery level as well as individual commodity flows are included in Appendix III. Weight-Based, Port-Specific User Fee A weight-based user charge aimed at recovering operations and maintenance expenses through use of a port-specific fee would only modestly affect thr aggregate flow of grain and soybeans to Gulf, Atlantitiq. Great Lakes, and Pacific coast areas (Table 9). The greatest relative effect is in the Atlantic and Great Table 6. Ports’ User Charge Estimates for All Types of Costs Subject to Recoveryl Cost Subject to Recovery2 a OM NC OMNC Port Weight-Based Ad Valorem Weight-Based Ad Valorem Weight-Based Ad Valorem $/ton3 percent $/ton percent $/ton3 percent Mobile, AL 0.2714 0.17002 2.4548 1.53786 2.7262 1.70788 New Orleans, LA 0.1727 0.05067 0.4216 0.12372 0.5943 0.17439 Galveston, TX 0.1163 0.02556 0.8153 0.17922 0.9316 0.20478 Corpus Christi, TX 0.1945 0.10720 0.3128 0.17240 0.5073 0.27960 Brownsville, TX — — — — — — Charleston, S.C. 0.6661 0.06229 1.0504 0.09823 1.7165 0.16052 Baltimore, MD 0.0620 0.01331 1.0979 0.22330 1.1599 0.23661 Toledo, OH 0.1568 0.21908 —— — 0.1-568 0.21908 Saginaw, Ml 2.9496 3.74800 — — 2.9496 3.74800 Chicago, IL 0.0766 0.06446 — — 0.0766 0.06446 Duluth, MN 0.0605 0.09565 0.0293 0.04632 0.0898 0.14197 Seattle, WA 0.0171 0.00224 0.3520 0.05240 0.3691 0.05464 Portland, OR 0.7137 0.25473 0.01270 0.00452 0.7264 0.24925 San Francisco, CA 0.3203 0.02711 3.9313 0.89572 4.2516 0.96871 Long Beach, CA 0.0021 0.00032 0.7356 0.11055 0.7377 0.11087 San Diego, CA — Overall 16-port fee‘ 0.1688 0.04283 0.6172 0.15654 0.7860 0.19937 Uniform fee 0.2010 0.08361 0.4436 0.18452 0.6446 0.26813 ‘User charge estimates for a 100 percent cost recovery level. 20M operation and maintenance costs, NC= new construction costs, OMNC=operation and maintenance costs plus new construction costs. 3Short tons. ‘Weighted port-specific fee for 16 grain-shipping ports. Table 7. Estimated Market Effects of Port-User Charges: Percent Changes in Quantities Per-Unit User Charge Ad Valorem User Charge Port-Specific Uniform Port-Specific Uniform Commodity OM‘ NC OM , NC OM NC OM NC Percent Changes in U.S. Foreign Demand (—) Corn 0.095 0.347 0.113 0.249 0.030 0.109 0.058 0.128 Sorghum 0.118 0.433 0.141 0.311 0.037 0.136 0.073 0.161 Soybeans 0.035 0.128 0.042 0.092 0.023 0.086 0.046 0.101 Wheat 0.036 0.132 0.043 0.095 0.016 0.057 0.031 0.068 Percent Changes in U.S. Supply (—) Corn 0.012 0.043 0.014 0.031 0.004 0.013 0.007 0.016 Sorghum 0.018 0.066 0.021 0.047 0.005 0.021 0.011 0.023 Soybeans 0.008 0.030 0.010 0.021 0.005 0.020 0.011 0.023 Wheat 0.014 0.050 0.016 0.036 0.006 0.022 0.012 0.026 Percent Changes in U.S. Domestic Demand (+) Corn 0.024 0.086 0.028 0.062 0.007 0.027 0.014 0.032 “Sorghum 0.036 0.132 0.043 0.09s 0.011 0.042 0.022 0.049 Soybeans 0.011 0.040 0.013 0.029 0.007 0.026 0.014 0.031 Wheat 0.024 0.088 0.029 0.063 0.011 0.038 0.021 0.045 ‘OM and NC denote operation and maintenance costs and new construction costs, respectively. Lakes coastal areas where respective changes in flows are 3.9 and -2.3 percent of the base solution. In the Great Lakes area, Lakes Superior and Michigan gain ain while Huron and Erie lose exports. Lakes Huron . and Erie ports incur large operations and maintenance expenses and handle a relatively small volume of grain; and since weight-based fees are estimated by dividing costs by tonnage, they have relatively large user fees. (See Table 1 for procedure to calculate fees.) Because of the relatively modest operations and maintenance expenses at Atlantic ports and the associ- ated small user charge, a portion of the grain originally routed to Lakes Huron and Erie is rerouted to Atlantic ports. Table 8. Estimated Market Effects of Port-User Charges: Percent Changes in Price per Ton Weight-Based User Charge Ad Valorem User Charge w Port-Specific Uniform Port-Specific Uniform Commodity OM‘ NC OM NC OM NC OM NC $/ton International Market (+) Corn 0.106 0.387 0.126 0.278 0.033 0.122 310.065 0.143 y... Sorghum 0.063 0.229 0.075 0.165 0.020 0.072 ‘0.039 0.085 Soybeans 0.107 0.393 0.128 0.282 0.072 0.262 0.140 0.309 Wheat 0.056 0.203 0.066 0.146 0.024 0.089 0.047 0.104 U.S. Domestic Market (—) Corn 0.080 0.293 0.095 0.211 0.025 0.091 0.049 0.108,. Sorghum 0.123 0.451 0.147 0.324 0.039 0.142 0.076 0.168 Soybeans 0.079 0.288 0.094 0.207 0.053 0.192 0.102 0.226 Wheat 0.131 0.478 0.156 0.343 0.057 0.208 0.111 0.245 ‘OM and NC denote operation and maintenance costs and new construction costs, respectively. Table 9. Effect on U.S. Port Area Grain and Soybean Flows of a Weight-Based User Fee Which ls to Recoupe All Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OM NC OMNC OM NC OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent ln Percent In Percent In Percent ln Percent In Percent Port Area Volume’ Change3 Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Gulf: East Gulf - 0.05 - 0.03 -159.59 -83.34 -159.61 -83.35 - 0.1 -0.03 - 0.1 -0.07 - 0.2 -0.10 Mississippi River - 8.20 - 0.39 248.51 11.47 216.80 10.00 9.9 0.45 8.3 0.37 7.0 0.31 North Texas - 0.28 - 0.04 - 14.89 - 2.06 - 15.29 - 2.08 - 0.4 -0.05 - 0.9 -0.12 - 1.5 0.21 South Texas 0.01 0.02 0.88 1.20 0.88 1.23 0.0 0.00 0.0 -0.04 0.1 -0.08 Total - 8.55 - 0.27 74.89 2.38 42.75 1.36 9.5 0.30 7.3 0.23 5.3 0.17 Atlantic: North Atlantic 22.74 4.19 -107.89 -19.89 - 60.44 -11.14 -10.5 -1.93 -12.6 -2.32 -14.3 -2.63 South Atlantic - 0.01 - 0.02 - 0.03 - 9.07 - 0.03 - 0.07 0.0 -0.01 0.0 -0.04 0.0 -0.07 Total 22.73 3.90 -107.92 -18.52 - 60.47 -10.38 -10.5 -1.81 -12.6 -2.16 -14.3 -2.46 Great Lakes: Superior-Michigan 10.69 2.66 18.59 4.62 17.19 4.27 - 0.4 -0.10 - 0.4 -0.09 - 0.3 -0.09 Huron-Erie -25.77 -10.21 5.46 2.16 - 11.38 - 4.51 - 0.1 -0.03 - 0.2 -0.06 - 0.2 -0.08 Total -15.08 - 2.30 24.05 3.67 5.81 0.89 - 0.5 -0.07 - 0.5 -0.08 - 0.6 -0.09 Pacific: Seattle Area 50.17 23.76 - 2.37 - 1.12 49.90 23.76 - 2.2 -1.04 - 2.3 -1.11 - 2.4 -1.15 Portland Area -52.43 -22.14 - 0.18 - 0.08 - 52.66 -22.14 0.0 -0.02 - 0.1 -0.04 - 0.2 -0.09 California 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.0 0.00 0.0 -0.03 0.0 -0.04 Total - 2.26 - 0.48 - 2.56 - 0.54 - 2.76 - 0.58 - 2.2 -0.47 - 2.4 -0.51 - 2.6 -0.55 ‘p Total Port Exports‘ - 3.16 - 0.06 - 11.53 - 0.24 - 14.67 - 0.30 - 3.7 -0.08 - 8.3 -0.17 -12.1 -0.25 ‘Numbers at the coast level may not add up to totals due to rounding. zMillion bushels. 3Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. grain exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. Even though there is only modest redirection of flows to the various coastal areas, there is substantial rerouting of grain among ports in coastal areas—in particular, in the Pacific Northwest (interport flows). The estimated port-specific user fee in the Seattle area is about 5 percent of the Portland area fee; consequent- 8 1y, eastern Washington wheat is redirected (50 million bushels) from the barge-served Portland port area and routed to Seattle by railroad. Port-specific user fees that are based on recovery o new construction costs generate more dramatic changes in flows than user fees based on operations ~ ._ -v l Table 10. Effect on U.S. Port Area Grain and Soybean Flows of an Ad Valorem User Fee Which ls to Recoupe All Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OM NC OMNC OM NC OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change ln Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent Port Area Volumez Change3 Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Gulf: East Gulf - 9.67 - 5.05 -45.66 -23.84 -180.34 -94.17 0.0 -0.03 - 0.1 -0.04 - 0.1 -0.06 Mississippi River 19.92 0.91 63.61 2.93 180.74 8.34 10.4 -0.45 9.3 0.42 8.4 0.38 North Texas - 0.56 - 0.08 25.27 3.49 9.41 1.30 - 0.2 -0.05 - 0.5 -0.07 - 0.7 -0.10 South Texas 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.04 0.01 0.05 0.0 0.00 0.0 0.01 0.0 -0.02 Total 9.68 - 0.31 43.21 1.37 9.79 0.311 10.1 0.30 8.7 0.28 7.6 0.24 Atlantic: North Atlantic 6.43 1.18 -44.56 - 8.21 - 30.29 - 5.58 - 9.7 -1.78 -10.7 -1.99 -11.7 -2.15 South Atlantic 0.00 0.00 - 0.01 - 0.03 0.02 - 0.05 0.0 -0.02 0.0 -0.05 0.0 -0.06 Total 6.43 1.18 -44.57 - 7.65 - 30.31 - 5.20 - 9.7 -1.66 -10.7 -1.86 -11.7 -2.01 Great Lakes: Superior-Michigan 10.68 2.65 - 0.42 - 0.10 23.16 5.76 - 0.4 -0.10 - 0.4 -0.10 - 0.4 -0.10 Huron-Erie -25.75 -10.20 - 0.08 - 0.03 - 5.53 - 2.19 - 0.1 0.02 - 0.1 -0.04 - 0.1 -0.06 Total -15.06 - 2.30 - 0.50 - 0.07 17.63 2.69 - 0.5 -0.07 - 0.5 -0.08 - 0.5 -0.08 Pacific: Seattle Area 50.24 23.79 - 2.22 - 1.05 50.08 23.72 - 2.2 -1.02 - 2.3 -1.07 - 2.4 -1.11 Portland Area -52.41 -22.14 - 0.06 - 0.02 - 52.46 -22.16 0.0 -0.01 - 0.1 -0.03 - 0.1 -0.04 California 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.0 0.00 0.0 0.00 0.0 0.00 Total - 2.18 - 0.46 - 2.28 - 0.48 - 2.38 - 0.50 - 2.2 -0.46 - 2.4 -0.49 - 2.5 -0.51 Total Port Exports‘ - 1.13 - 0.02 - 4.14 - 0.08 - 5.27 - 0.11 - 2.2 -0.05 - 4.9 -0.10 - 7.1 -0.15 ‘Numbers at the coast level may not add up to totals due to rounding. 2Million bushels. aPercent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. grain exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. and maintenance costs. Since a port's operation and maintenance expense and capital expenditure on new deep-draft facilities are not directly related, a different flow pattern scheme often exists. Port areas in the Great Lakes are scheduled for less investment on new deep-draft facilities. As a result, they tend to benefit from imposition of a port-specific fee based on these costs. This is particularly true for the Lake Superior- Michigan area. The Atlantic port area loses grain volume to Lake and Gulf ports, with the North Atlan- tic area bearing most of the volume loss. The North Atlantic ports have been approved for new construc- tion activity, thus a user fee designed to recover these costs would direct grain from this area. Imposition of a port-specific user fee which recovers new construction costs increases Gulf coast export volume by about 2 percent, or 75 million bushels. Of more interest, however, is the altered interport com- petition within the Gulf coast area. Most Mississippi River and North Texas (Houston-Galveston area) port areas increase their volume at the expense of East Gulf ports. The East Gulf ports have been approved for new construction and the resulting user fee is proj- ected to redirect nearly 160 million bushels of corn and . soybeans from this port area. This grain is redirected to Mississippi River ports which are projected to increase export volume by 248 million bushels. A portion of this increased grain volume is rerouted from Atlantic coast ports. User charge scenarios which assume the combined recovery of operations and maintenance and new construction expenses yield somewhat different re- sults than those based on recovery of either cost. In some coastal areas, altered grain flows resemble those already discussed, whereas in others, there appears to be little relationship. This is not surprising since the aggregated magnitude of the operations and mainte- nance and new construction expenses may be similar or quite different than a user charge based on a particular cost. For instance, the Lakes port area has virtually no projected expenditures for new construc- tion, but has comparatively large operations and maintenance costs; thus, when all costs subject to recovery are combined, the resulting user charges are comparable to those of other ports. Due to its relatively high port user fees, Atlantic ports lose about 10 percent of their base volume when fees incorporate full recovery of all costs. In all other coastal port areas, flows are altered about 1 percent or less. Changes in interport flows are, in some cases, substantial and in most cases, similar to those gener- ated by user fees designed to recover new construc- tion costs. Weight-Based, Uniform User Fee Weight-based user charges which are uniformly applied to all U.S. ports have a small affect on inter- coast and interport competition (Table 9). In all cases, Lake ports suffer minor grain losses to Gulf ports, regardless of the recovered cost. This outcome con- firms the belief of some legislators that uniform fees would leave port competition and port volumes undis- turbed. Ad Valorem-Based, Port-Specific User Fee Table 10 reports alterations in grain flow patterns that arise from introduction of an ad valorem-based user charge. Ad valorem-based user fees are generally different in magnitude than weight-based fees, since they are based on value of exports transshipped through a port. Thus, the product mix of a particular port is an important factor determining the magnitude of this fee. The effect of an ad valorem-based fee is made more complex since each grain has a different value, and as a result, ocean shipping rates are unique to the commodity being shipped. Port-specific fees designed to recover port area's operations and maintenance expenses do not serious- ly alter flows (Table 10). Atlantic and Gulf coast ports experience modest increases in grain export volume, whereas the Lake and Pacific coast port areas suffer losses. Interport competition is relatively modest in all coastal areas with the exception of the Pacific North- west. Seattle and Portland ports are sensitive to ad valorem-based user fees, even though the changes in relative ocean freight rates from these port areas to foreign destinations are comparatively small. In the Gulf, small quantities of the East Gulf ports’ grain volume is redirected to the Mississippi River port area, whereas ports located in the Lake Huron-Erie area lose export grain while Lakes Superior and Michigan gain volume. Port-specific user fees that seek to recoupe new construction costs would leave flows to various coastal areas largely unchanged. The exception is the Atlantic Coast which would lose about 8 percent of its grain shipments. Interport competition within the Gulf area is altered at both Mississippi River and North Texas ports where export volume increases, while sizable losses are incurred by the East Gulf ports. Port-specific fees which incorporate the aggregated operations and maintenance and new construction fees do not redirect grain from one coastal area to another; however, grain is redirected among ports in a particular coastal area (Table 10). In the Gulf area, East Gulf ports experience a dramatic loss of grain exports, whereas Mississippi River ports’ volume increases 8 percent or about 180 million bushels. In the Great Lakes, the Lake Superior-Michigan area has the ad- vantage over Huron-Erie ports because of the com- paratively low level of costs subject to recovery; thus, the former increases its volume by about 6 percent, while the latter faces a loss of nearly 3 percent. Again, Seattle's export volume increases with imposition of the ad valorem-based, port-specific user fee by divert- 10 ing grain exports from Portland. Losses in the Atlantic Coast are constrained to the North Atlantic area. Ad Valorem-Based, Uniform User Fee Ad valorem-based, uniform user fees seem to pro- vide little change in grain export flow patterns, as was the case with weight-based, uniform charges (Table 10). In all cost recovery schemes, the Atlantic port area would be the most affected, though the impact is relatively inconsequential. Altered Flows and Port Elevator Capacity Five port areas emerged as experiencing increased volumes under the various user charge scenarios. These include the Mississippi River, Seattle, Lake Superior-Michigan, North Texas, and North Atlantic port areas. The Mississippi River port area is the most impor- tant grain outlet in the nation, accounting for up to 40 percent of U.S. agriculture’s grain exports. Depend- ing on the user fee scenario analyzed, increases in export volumes range from 19 to 248 million bushels of grain, which represent percentage increases relative to the base solution of 0.9 and 11.5 percent, respective- ly. Historical year-to-year (positive) variation of export grain volume in this area ranged from 6.2 percent in 1978-79 to 11.4 percent in 1979-80, suggesting that even an increase of 248 million bushels (11.5 percent) might be handled by Mississippi River ports. Howev- er, such an increment would require maximum utiliza- tion of port elevator capacity. Research by Barnett, Binkley, and McCarl showed that the Mississippi River port area operates up to 59 hours per week in peak volume months. This suggests that the extra volume generated by the user fees may be handled by in- creases in hours worked per week. It is estimated that the Mississippi River's port facilities would need to operate an additional 12 hours per week to accommo- date this outflow. In summary, the Mississippi River port area would probably be able to handle the large increase in exports brought about by imposition of a port-specific, weight-based user fee, however, there may be additional congestion during peak export periods. The Seattle area is an important outlet for export- destined corn and soft, hard, and durum wheats. The analysis shows Seattle to increase its grain exports (wheat) by nearly 5O million bushels at the expense of Portland when user fees are imposed to cover opera- tions and maintenance costs. Since this yields a total outflow which approximates some historical levels, the additional volume should not respresent a threat to system efficiency. The analysis shows the Lake Superior-Michigan port area to increase grain exports about 6.0 percent above the base volume if a port-specific, ad valorem- based fee, which is designed to cover operations and maintenance and new construction costs, were in- troduced. This maximum increase could be accommo- dated by operating facilities an additional 3 hours per week. Therefore, this modest increase could be ac- comodated by existing port elevator capacity. North Texas ports were shown to experience grain volume increases that range from 1.30 to 4.85 percent of the base volume. The generated variation in flows is generally less than the year-to-year variation and based on estimated port area capacity, the maximum flow could be accommodated by operating facilities an additional 2 hours per week. The North Atlantic port area is an outlet for U.S. produced soybeans and corn and is a competitor of Great Lake ports. The analysis shows a port-specific fee (weight-based), including only operations and maintenance costs, to redirect grain to this port area—the maximum increase is estimated to be 23 million bushels or about a 4 percent increase. This additional volume could be accommodated by operat- ing port infrastructure an additional 2 hours per week. Since no port elevators in this area appear to operate more than 40 hours per week, there would seem to be few capacity problems (Barnett, Binkley, and McCarl). The additional annual variation in flows generated by imposition of port user charges is generally smaller than the historical year-to-year variation in flows and, in most cases, the modest increase in flows can be accommodated with increases in operating hours. The exception may be the Mississippi River port area, where infrastructure would need to operate an addi- tional 12 hours per week if a port-specific user fee designed to recoupe 100 percent of new construction costs were introduced Summary and Conclusions The purpose of this study is to assess some of the effects of a proposed deep-draft user fee. User charge scenarios are generated to include the major features of legislation presented to Congress in the past several years. The analysis focuses on weight- and ad valorem-based charges which may be applied on a uniform or port-specific basis. In addition, the analysis examines the effect of recovering the various types of expenses—these include ports’ operations and maintenance expenses and new construction costs. Based on recent legislative proposals, various forms of the user fee are estimated. Then, with use of a multiperiod, network flow model, possible changes in grain flow patterns are analyzed. The model minimizes grain handling, storage, and transfer costs Qwhich include truck, rail, barge, and ocean shipping costs. The model is international in scope and includes 165 U.S. domestic grain surplus regions, 85 domestic grain deficit regions, 43 river points, and 16 represen- tative U.S. grain shipping port areas which are linked to 25 foreign demand regions. In general, the-analysis shows the most likely port user fee for grain and soybeans to be small. At most grain ports, either weight- or ad valorem-based fees which recover operations and maintenance expenses @would be less than $0.01 per bushel. If charges de- signed to recoupe authorized new construction and maintenance expenses were implemented, charges would average about $0.02 per bushel. Although the average fee is relatively small, there is substantial variation among ports. This is because (1) operations and maintenance expenses differ among ports; (2) only selected ports have been authorized for new construction; and (3) the volume and value of com- merce transitting the various ports differ. The least-cost analysis shows grain flow patterns to be affected most by the form of the user fee (uniform vs. port-specific) and, to a lesser extent, by the basis for levying the fee (weight vs. value). Results indicate that uniform fees, both weight- and ad valorem- based, alter flows least. In essence, uniform fees leave flow patterns unchanged. The principal flow pattern disruptions are limited to port-specific fees. And, in general, the port-specific, weight-based fee yields greater flow pattern changes than the ad valorem- based fee; however, the general effect of either user fee is similar. Because grain is relatively low-valued, the share of the ad valorem-based user cost borne by grain is small as compared to a user fee based on grain weight. It is difficult to generalize regarding the effect of user fees designed to recoupe the various types of costs. These costs include ports’ operations and mainte- nance costs, improvement or new construction expen- ditures, and the aggregate of these costs. The most dramatic change associated with a user fee designed to recover operations and maintenance costs is a port- specific, weight-based user fee which would reroute about 20 percent of Portland's historic volume to Seattle. When new construction costs are incor- porated into this type of user fee, several relatively dramatic changes in flows occur. In particular, East Gulf and North Atlantic ports lose 160 (83 percent) and 108 (20 percent) million bushels, respectively, while Mississippi River ports increase their outflow by 248 million bushels, or about 11 percent. A port-specific, weight-based user fee which covers the aggregated operations and maintenance and new construction costs yields flows that are similar to those generated by a user fee which is based on new construction. In general, most of the major changes in flows are limited to flows within a coastal area (interport) rather than flows between coastal areas. In many cases, a port's advantage or disadvantage that would result from imposition of a user fee is small and, in the short run, a disadvantaged port's infra- structure may absorb some of the user fee. Therefore, the least-cost methodology employed in this study may tend to overestimate altered flows. It is important to note that the analyses assumed peak export levels which approximated those of the 1980-81 period. Therefore, the magnitude of altered flows is increased and the pressures on port intermodal capacity possi- bly overstated. Regardless, an effort was made to determine whether port area intermodal transfer capacity was adequate. In most cases, port area inter- modal transfer capacity was adequate. The exception may be the Mississippi River port area which may have inadequate capacity to handle an additional 248 million bushels. This additional volume is projected to occur through imposition of a port-specific, weight- 11 based fee which recoupes new construction costs. In summary, the port user fee will not have a major effect on agriculture since the estimated unit fee is quite small. The magnitude of the user fee is closely associated with the amount of the charge to be re- covered and the volume or value of freight transitting the port. In most cases, a port's relative cost advantage or disadvantage that results from imposition of a user charge is not large. Therefore, in the short run, a port's cost disadvantage is likely to be partially absorbed by lowering the rate of return on capital investment, thus minimizing abrupt disruptions in trade flows. Literature A. T. Keamy, Inc. Unpublished study carried out for Inter- state Commerce Commisssion (contract ICC 78-C-0006) which involved analysis of 1977 One Percent Waybill . sample. Adams, Brian D. and Dale G. Anderson. Implications of the Staggers Rail Act of 1980 for Level and Variability of Country Elevator Bid Prices. Paper No. 7825, Journal Series, Nebras- ka Agricultural Experiment Station, 1985. Barnett, Doug, James Binkley, and Bruce McCarl. ”Port Elevator Capacity and National and World Grain Ship- ments." Western Journal of Agricultural Economics. 9(1984): 77-89. Barr, T. N. Demand and Price Relationships for the U.S. Wheat Economy. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Re- search Service, WS-226, November 1973. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Federal Reserve Bulletin. Washington, D.C., Various issues. Bredahl, Maury E. and Leonardo Green. "Residual Supplier Model of Coarse Grain Trade." Americal Journal of Agricul- tural Economics 65(1983): 785-790. Bredahl, Maury E. William H. Meyers, and Keith J. Collins. ”The Elasticity of Foreign Demand for U.S. Agricultural Products: The Importance of the Price Transmission Elas- ticity" American Journal of Agricultural Economics 61(1979): 58-63. Cooper, S. Kerry and Donald R. Fraser. The Financial Market- place. Reading, Massachusetts: Addison-Wesley Pub- lishing Company, 1982. Cramer, Gail L. and Walter G. Heid, Jr. Grain Marketing Economics. New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1983. Friedlaender, Ann F. The Dilemma of Freight Transport Reg- ulation. The Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C., 1969. Fuller, Stephen and Chiyyarath Shanmugham. "Network Flow Models: Use in Rural Freight Transportation Analy- sis and a Comparison with Linear Programming.” South- ern Journal of Agricultural Economics 10(December, 1978): 183-188. Fuller, Stephen, Larry Makus, and William Gallimore. ”Ef- fects of Increasing Panama Canal Toll Rates on U.S. Grain Exports.” Southern Journal of Agricultural Economics. 16(1984): 9-20. Fuller, Stephen W., Larry Makus, and Merritt Taylor. "Effect of Railroad Deregulation on Export-Grain Rates.” North Central Journal of Agricultural Economics 6 (January, 1983): 51-63. Grennes, Thomas, Paul R. Johnson, and Mary Thursby. The Economics of World Grain Trade. New York: Praeger Pub- lishers Co., 1978. Hauser, Robert. Unpublished Working Papers, Iowa State University, 1981. Hillman, Jimmy. “Policy Issues Relevant to United States 12 Agricultural Trade." Imperfect Markets in Agricultural Trade. Ed. Alex McCalla and Timothy Josling, pp. 113-142. Montclair, N .J.: Allanheld, Osmun & Company, 1981. Interstate Commerce Commission, Bureau of Accounts. Carload Cost Scales, 1977. Washington, D.C.: Statemen No. 1C1-77, November 1979. Interstate Commerce Commission, Bureau of Accounts. Uniform Railroad Costing System. Washington, D.C.: De- cember 17, 1982. Johnson, Paul R. "The Elasticity of Foreign Demand for USN Agricultural Products." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 59(1977): 735-766. Kendall, P. M. H. "A Theory of Optimum Ship Size." Journal of Transport Economics and Policy. 2(1972): 128-146. Klindworth, Keith A., Orlo Sorenson, Michael W. Babcock, and Ming Chow. Impacts of Rail Deregulation on Marketing of Kansas Wheat. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Office of Transportation, September 1985. Leath, Mack. Unpublished Memorandum on Elevator Cost, University of Illinois, 1982. Leath, Mack N. and Leo Blakely. An Interregional Analysis of the U.S. Grain Marketing Industry, 1966-67. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Re- search Service, TB-1444, November 1971. Leath, Mack N. and Lowell D. I-Iill. Grain Movements, Transportation Requirements, and Trends in the United States Grain Marketing System: Patterns During the 1970s. North Central Regional Research Publication No. 288, Universi- ty of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, 1983. Leath, Mack N ., Lowell D. Hill, and Stephen W. Fuller. Sorghum Movements in the United States. Illinois Bulletin No. 765, University of Illinois, January 1981a. . Soybean Movement in the United States. Illinois Bulle- tin No. 766, Universtiy of Illinois, January 1981b. - . Wheat Movements in the United States. Illinois Bulletin No. 767, University of Illinois, January 1981c. Lloyds of London Press Inc. Lloyds 1984 Ports of the World. Essex, United Kingdom. Longmire, Jim and Art Morey. Strong Dollar Dampens Demand for U.S. Farm Exports. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, Foreign Agricultural Eco- nomic Report No. 193, December 1983. McCalla, Alex. "Pricing in the World Feed Grain Market." Agricultural Economic Research. 19(1967): 93-102. Makus, Larry and Stephen Fuller. ”Location Shifts in U.S. Export Grain Demand and Their Effect on the Export Marketing System." Agribusiness: An International Journal. (Forthcoming). Makus, Larry D. "Sensitivity of U.S. Port Market Areas to Changing World Demands for Grains and Soybeans." Ph.D. Dissertation, Texas A&M University, December 1983. Milling and Baking News. 1982 Milling and Grain Directory. 1982. Q, Paarlberg, Donald. Farm and Food Policies: Issues of the 1980's. Lincoln, Nebraska: University of Nebraska Press, 1980. Paggi, Mechel. "A Strong Dollar Hinders Agricultural Exports." Texas A&M University, Food and Fiber Economics, ECO, Vol. 12, No. 9, October 1983. Rand McNally 8: Company. Handy Railroad Atlas of the United States. Chicago, Illinois, 1978. Rausser, Gordon C., Ed. New Direction in Econometric Model- ing and Forecasting in U.S. Agriculture. New York: North- Holland Publishing Company, 1978. Ray Daryll E. and James W. Richardson. Detailed Descriptio; I of POLYSIM. Oklahoma Agricultural Experiment Station% Oklahoma State University and U.S. Department of Agri- culture, 1978. Taylor, Merrit J. ”A Model to Analyze the Export Grain Transportation System." Ph.D. Dissertation, Texas A&M University, May 1982. ~18. Army Corps of Engineers. Deep-Draft Navigation Cost Recovery Analysis. U.S. Army Corps of Engineers Office, Chief of Engineers Directorate of Civil Works Office of Policy, Washington, D.C., 1982. .Towboat and Barge Operating Costs. Ft. Belvoir, Vir- ginia, January 1983. %U.S. Department of Agriculture. Annual Voyage Charter Rates, 1977-1982, Tape data base, Washington, D.C., Eco- nomic Research Service, 1983. .An Assessment of Impacts on Agriculture of the Staggers Rail Act and Motor Carrier Act of 1980. Washington, D.C., Office of Transportation, August 1982a. .Grain Market News. Agricultural Marketing Service, Various Issues, 1970-84. .National Interregional Agricultural Projections. Wash- ington D.C., Economic Research Service, 1980. .11 .S . Foreign Agricultural Trade Statistical Report, Calendar Year 1983. Washington, D. C. , Economic Research Service, April 1982b. U.S. Department of Commerce. United States Port Develop- ment Expenditure Survey. Washington D.C., Maritime Ad- ministration, Office of Port and Intermodal Development, January 1980. .Nati0nal Port Assessment 1980/1990. Washington D.C., Maritime Administration, Office of Port and Inter- modal Development, June 1980. foreign Production, Supply and Distribution of Agricul- tural Commodities (Tape). National Technical Information Service, Springfield, Virginia, 1984. Appendix I. Technical Discussion of Methods and Procedures Procedure to Estimate the Effect of User Charges on Grain Trade Market effects of both weight- and ad valorem- based user fees are similar with respect to the direction of change, but differ in magnitude (Figures 2 and 3). Major effects include an increase in the price of U.S. grain to foreign buyers and a subsequent decline in quantity traded. In the U.S. domestic market, price is lowered and quantities supplied and demanded de- crease and increase, respectively. The purpose of this section is to develop a mathematical procedure which will allow one to obtain quantitative estimates of these effects. Effect of Weight-Based Port User Charges In this subsection, algebraic expressions which can be used to estimate the market effect of weight-based user charges are derived. Market effects involve changes in prices and quantities traded both in the internaitonal market, and the U.S. domestic market. Changes in Prices and Quantities Traded in the International Market Under the assumption of free trade and linear narket relationships, let (1a) Q56 = a +b P8, b>o and (1b) Qiie=c+d Pe , e20 and d<0 be the supply and demand equations in the exporting country's (United States) domestic market, and let (2a) Qiii=g+h Pi , gzO and hsO and (2b) Qsi=j +k Pi , k>0 be the demand and supply equations in the ”aggre- gate” importing country's (Rest-of-the-World or ROW) domestic market. Qse and Ode are the quantities supplied and demanded, and Pe is the price in the exporter’s market, while Qsi, Qdi, and Pi represent quantities supplied and demanded and price in the ROW markets, respectively. The letters a, b, c, d, g, h, j, and k respresent constants. Using the "excess supply-excess demand" ap- proach, the following expressions are obtained by subtracting (lb) from (1a), as well as (2b) from (2a): (3a) ES=A+B Pe, B20 and (3b) ED=G+D Pi , D0$ 619/. t c“ 0G 1r" U s Port - - Ra” Elevators surplus 7 [m] Ocean Vessel’ Gran] T k o gun Pmdllfilllfl ruc 7 cfireat Lakes "Bfllflfls vAtlamic I165] vPacific ' Model allows for rail and truck shipments to Mexico and Canada Figure 5. Elements of spatial model. w? '\fl\-fl~ \&r-— it Figure 6. Model regions. 20 Data Requirements of Grain Network Flow Models Two types of data inputs are required by the grain and soybean network flow models: market-related and transportation-related data. Market data refer to quantities supplied and demanded in domestic and foreign markets. Transportation data relate to transfer costs associated with transporting, storing, and han- dling grain. Market-Related Data Grain supply and demand estimates are required for domestic producing regions, domestic consuming regions, and foreign demanding regions. The follow- . ing sections discuss the data gathering procedures employed to collect market information pertaining to the regions. U.S. Domestic Surplus and Deficit Regions To determine the basic structure of the network models, it is necessary to identify the number and size of supply and demand regions as well as their associ- ated quantities supplied and demanded. This requires (1) regional demarcation of surplus and deficit grain producing regions (domestic and foreign), and (2) estimation of quantities to be supplied and received by ' the various regions. Demarcation of regions is based upon existing geographical delineations. The Crop Reporting District (CRD) is the selected geographical base unit. For purposes of determining unambiguous transportation routes and mode rates, the most-cen- trally located city within a region is chosen as a representative source or destination location. The model includes 165 grain and soybean produc- ing regions (Figure 6). Some regions have grain and/or soybean surpluses since estimated production exceeds estimated consumption, whereas other re- gions have estimated deficits. A surplus region's supply is available to meet demand from grain deficit regions or export. Production estimates are made for each region and were based on projections elaborated by the Economic Research Service of the U.S. Department of Agricul- ture (1980). U.S. Department of Agriculture pro- jections were procured from the National Interregion- al Agricultural Projections (NIRAP) model. Domestic consumption estimates were made for each region and were comprised of (1) human con- I sumption, (2) animal consumption, and (3) seed utili- zation. Human consumption estimates were obtained from a study made by Hauser at Iowa State University. Hauser used time series analysis to isolate trends in human consumption based upon expectations of population growth and regional milling, processing, and crushing capacities of grains and soybeans. Ani- mal consumption figures were obtained from the NIRAP’s livestock and poultry projections. Seed use estimates were obtained through total acreage planted in each state. In some cases, wheat and corn milling demands and soybean processing demands are iden- tified with cities rather than regions. The model in- cludes 85 regions or locations with estimated grain or soybean deficits. Foreign Importing Regions Demarcation of foreign importing regions followed a similar procedure as that employed in demarcation of domestic regions. The minimum demarcation unit was a country. Because of their import volume, size, or geographical location, some countries were categorized as world regions themselves; for example, the United Soviet Socialist Republic, Japan, and Taiwan. In other cases, due to geographical proximity, several countries were grouped together; e.g., Scan- dinavia includes Denmark, Finland, East Germany, Norway, and Sweden. To establish appropriate ocean vessel routes and rates, a single port from the foreign region was chosen as the importing location or port. In general, the selected port was centrally located within the importing region. Estimates of grain and soybean demand (imports) by foreign region were obtained through trend analy- sis on historical quantities of U.S. grain exports to specified countries. U.S. exports to the demarcated world regions and average shares of U.S. exports to regions were procured (U.S. Department of Agricul- ture, Grain Market News). Historical shares were used to project U. S. exports to each foreign region. The time series analysis of U.S. exports revealed foreign re- gions’ imports of U.S. grain were seasonal; thus, export estimates to each world subregion were di- vided into quarters to account for this phenomenon. Transportation-Related Data An overview of the procedures employed in collect- ing, analyzing, and estimating mode rates, and stor- age and handling costs used as inputs in the transpor- tation network flow models is presented in this sub- section. Transportation modes discussed include barge, truck, rail, and ocean vessel. Barge Rates The barge mode is extensively used by the grain marketing system, since it represents the least expen- sive means of grain transportation. However, its utili- zation is limited to currently developed and main- tained waterways such as river channels and port canals. The network flow models comprise (1) the Mississippi waterway system which includes the Mis- sissippi River and its tributaries, (the Illinois, Ohio, Missouri, and Arkansas rivers) and the Columbia- Snake waterway system, which includes the Colum- bia and Snake Rivers (Figure 7). Barge and towboat costs are based on budget data from the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers (1983). Cost- ing procedures take into consideration the unique physical characteristics of the various segments in each major waterway system. Truck Rates Truck transportation is the most flexible of all inland transportation modes and grains and soybeans rely 21 o Port Locations ° Barge Locations Figure 7. LLS. ports and river locations in the grain transportation models. heavily on trucks at the assembly stage. Due to its flexibility, truck transportation has a competitive edge over the barge and rail modes for short hauls, with the converse holding for longer hauls. Based on the established demarcation of grain sur- plus and deficit regions, a computerized algorithm, developed at Iowa State University, was used by Taylor and Makus to estimate truck rates. The al- gorithm estimates truck cost equations, on a state-by- state basis, through use of regression analysis. Truck rates are estimated for all possible origin-destination combinations in which the truck mode may be used. Truck rates for movements from grain surplus regions to river points are based on distances between the surplus region and the nearest barge loading location. Rail Rates Railroads play an important role in transporting grain and soybean for longer distances of haul. Pro- ducing regions far from major waterway systems often move their grain and soybean surplus by rail. In the network models, rail lines link surplus producing regions to barge loading locations and numerous demand locations and ports. There is difficulty in knowing likely railroad pricing 22 behavior in view of the recent deregulation of the railroad industry Economics has no unified theory of oligopoly pricing and the recent deregulation experi- ence has been of insufficient duration to make long- run inferences regarding railroad pricing strategy. Several studies, however, have been made in the past few years and found evidence that railrates have declined during the post-Staggers era (Klindworth, et al. ; Adams and Anderson). But the economic environ- ment since deregulation has been characterized by declining export sales and large surpluses of transpor- tation equipment; therefore, the observed competi- tion between and within tranportation modes may not be reflective of the long run. A recent study notes that the rate reductions flowing from these competitive tendencies may be reversed once economic recovery takes hold and rail cars and barge surpluses are reduced or eliminated (U.S. Department of Agricul- ture, 1982a). Economists agree that in a market charac- terized by few competitors, interdependence is gener- ally recognized and, in the long run, there is a tenden- cy toward tacit ratemaking. Friedlaender states that ”. . .the history of collusive pricing in the railroad industry is sufficiently long so that collusion would probably. . . (exist with deregulation)," in which case interrailroad competition would be limited. \ '\ For purposes 0f estimating railroad rates, it is as- sumed that interrailroad competition is limited and railroads attempt to charge the highest rate that inter- modal competition will permit in surplus grain pro- ducing regions. The procedure to estimate rates is outlined in an article by Fuller, Makus, and Taylor. In essence, the highest revenue-to-variable cost ratio permitted by intermodal competition is estimated for each surplus producing region. These ratios are es- timated for corn, wheat, soybeans, and sorghum. This ratio is then multiplied by the estimated variable costs which link a particular origin-destination combination for purposes of estimating rates. The rail-rate estimation procedure requires that railroads’ variable costs be estimated for each route. Rail costs are based on the Rail Carload Cost scales published by the Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC); while mileages are gathered from several publi- cations, among them is the Handy Railroad Atlas 0f the United States published by the Rand McNally Co. Railroad variable costs are estimated by use of a computerized algorithm developed at Iowa State Uni- versity. The algorithm calculates rail rates per bushel costs for both single-car and multiple-car trains. Rail rate estimation is based on five ICC regions and takes into consideration cost parameters associated with covered hopper car weights, commodity, turnaround times, required switching, interest rates, size of ship- ment, route mileage, average mileage between inter- changes, and mileage between yards. The ICC’s 1981 cost scales and 1982 update cost ratios are used to estimate variable costs (Interstate Commerce Com- mission, 1982). Ocean Shipping Rates Data on ocean shipping rates were obtained from the U.S. Department of Agriculture for the 1977-83 period. These data are collected and reported by Maritime Research Incorporated and include informa- tion on origin, destination, tonnage, rates, and the Julian date of charter. Based on this information, Makus developed estimates for shipping rates from four coastal areas to the 25 world regions. Storage and Handling Costs Though storage facilities are found at all stages of the grain marketing channel (on farms, country eleva- tors, subterminals, terminals, and port elevators), storage was assumed to occur in the supplying re- gions. Reliable data regarding on-farm storage capaci- ty were not available. No storage constraints are, therefore, specified in the models. Cost estimates for storage follow those estimated by Leath, et al. 1982. Handling costs rare those associated with loading and unloading grain. Handling costs are incurred in the supply regions, at transshipment points, and at final destinations. Loading and unloading costs are dependent on the mode of transportation used. Costs included in the model take into consideration the combination of modes used in a particular haul. See Table 14 on estimated handling and storage costs. Table 14. Summary of Costs by Function and Type of Facility and Weighted Average Costs for All Facilities, by Function, 1981-82 Country River Port All Elevators Elevators Elevators Elevators cents per bushel Receiving By: Truck 4.796 4.213 4.350 4.697 Rail n.a. 6.051 3.931 4.629 Water n.a. 9.354 3.269 3.451 Shipping By: Truck 5.071 3.821 0.0 4.984 Rail 6.069 4.907 5.955 5.722 Water 2.352 2.337 2.535 2.487 Annual Storage 32.329 30.649 55.266 33.607 ‘Information provided in memo by Mac Leath. 2n.a. = not applicable Validation of Transportation Models Model validation is the process of gaining informa- tion on the model's ability to yield realistic grain flow patterns. Modeling efforts do not seek to exactly represent reality, since this is virtually impossible for the majority of situations due to cost, time, and data availability constraints. As a result, differences be- tween a given model's outcome and the real-world situation it attempts to emulate will occur. Conse- quently, model validation seeks to gain insight with regard to these differences. The optimization criterion of the network flow models involves minimization of total transfer cost associated with grain movements. In this regard, the models’ solutions may be inter- preted as the flow patterns that grain ought to follow in order to achieve this goal. The quality of the data is of great importance. Measurement and estimation errors are involved in collecting, recording, classifying, aggregating, processing, and reporting data. Mode rates as well as market data are bound to suffer from these errors. In addition, inappropriate aggregation of supply and demand regions may distort flows. Meaningful comparisons between model-projected and actual flows are difficult since grain production, consumption, and foreign demand change from year to year while the model's values are constants. Fur- ther, the model is constructed such that the produc- tion, consumption, and foreign demand estimates have a predetermined geographical location; whereas, the actual location of these activities exhibits variation. Additional divergence between actual and model- projected flows may exist because of the highly vari- able ship rate structures (Fuller, Makus, and Galli- more). Table 15 includes information on the historical per- centage of the U.S. aggregated grain and soybean outflow exiting through U.S. coast areas from 1970 to 1984 and the model-projected flow. Historically, 61.0 to 70.0 percent of U.S. grain and soybean exports have exited Gulf ports: the model projects 65 percent exiting 23 Table 15. Comparison of Aggregated Historical and Model-Generated Grain and Soybean Export Flows through U.S. Coastal Regions‘ Year Gulf Atlantic Great Lakes Pacific percent 1970 65.0 6.0 15.0 14.0 1971 67.0 6.0 17.0 10.0 1972 66.0 10.0 13.0 11.0 1973 67.0 12.0 10.0 11.0 1974 67.0 13.0 8.0 12.0 1975 65.0 14.0 10.0 11.0 1976 67.0 15.0 8.0 10.0 1977 67.0 14.0 10.0 9.0 1978 63.0 12.0 13.0 12.0 1979 61.0 13.0 11.0 15.0 1980 61.0 11.0 9.0 19.0 1981 64.0 11.0 7.0 18.0 1982 68.0 14.0 6.0 12.0 1983 70.0 9.0 5.0 16.0 1984 67.0 8.0 5.0 20.0 Model 65.0 12.0 13.0 10.0 ‘Historical data compiled from U.S. Department of Agriculture, Grain Market News, various issues 1970-84. this coastal area. The percentage of total exports exiting from the Atlantic coast area has varied be- tween 6.0 and 15.0 percent since 1970, again the model's projection is within this historical range with an estimate of 12 percent. The model-projected flows through Great Lakes and Pacific ports are within the historical ranges but tend to vary from these ports’ recent export shares. In particular, the model tends to overestimate recent exports from Great Lakes ports and underestimate outflow from Pacific ports. Much of the increase in exports from Pacific ports is attribut- able to corn which has recently begun moving from western Corn Belt origins to this port area. Several factors are responsible. To attract business, the Bur- lington Northern railroad introduced appealing rates between the western Corn Belt and Pacific Northwest ports; ship rates from Pacific ports to Japan, Taiwan, and Korea have, in some recent time periods, declined substantially relative to Gulf rates; and the Japanese importers have become associated with several Pacific coast export houses. These factors are also responsible for diminishing export flows from Great Lake ports. It is difficult to forecast the long run nature of these factors and their impact; accordingly, the model was not manipulated to generate the more recent outcome. In an effort to validate the employed model, Taylor compared historical grain flow patterns against those obtained from the models. Spearman’s correlation coefficients were estimated between model-projected flows and grain flows from a 1977 survey by Leath, et al. Sensitivity analysis was later carried out which showed that the grain network flow models appropri- ately ”tracked” changes in flows that resulted from changes in intermodal rates. Even though differences arose, the model was deemed appropriate to repre- sent the U.S. grain marketing system in 1977. This version of the model was used to evaluate the effect of 24 altering Panama Canal tolls and to identify the likely impact of rail deregulation on export rates (Fuller, Makus, and Gallimore; Fuller, Makus, and Taylor). Makus updated Taylor's models to account for changes in rail and ocean ship rates in order to reflect 1982 conditions. Even though there were some dif- ferences between the models’ projected flows and actual grain flows, the model was deemed appropriate to investigate the sensitivity of U.S. port areas to A changing patterns in foreign grain demands (Makus and Fuller). Various versions of the model have been used to analyze transportation issues and three re- ferred journal articles have resulted (Fuller, Makus, and Gallimore; Fuller, Makus, and Taylor; Makus and _ Fuller). These articles provide additional insight into ' the ability of the model to generate historical flow patterns. Appendix III. Further Results Included in this appendix are further results on grain flow patterns. Table 16 presents grain and soy- bean flows corresponding to what was labeled as the baserun solution. The baserun solution consists of the original model which was calibrated to approximate the U.S. domestic and international marketing sys- tem. Grain flow levels in the baserun solution reflect the grain marketing system prior to 1982. Current export levels are about 0.6 billion bushels less than the average for that period. Tables 17 and 18 report grain flows associated with port user fees which incorporate a 50 percent cost recovery level by the federal government. The format of these tables is identical to that of Tables 9 and 10 which reported grain flows that evaluated port user fees designed to recoupe 100 percent of all involved costs. Grain flows associated with port user fees that recoupe 50 percent of federal expenses proved to be similar to those which arise from a 100 percent recov- ery level. However, the magnitudes of altered flow patterns are for the most part considerably smaller. Tables 19 through 32 report altered flow patterns at the individual commodity level. Due to space con- straints, individual grain and soybean flow patterns were aggregated by coastal area rather than by port area. The format of these tables is identical to those presented above. 7K Table 16. Baserun Solution of Spatial Network Flow Models by Commodity.‘ HRW2 HRS3 Soft Durum Corn Sorghum Soybeans Wheat Wheat Wheat Wheat Total million bushels Gulf: East Gulf 118.66 0.00 72.84 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 191.50 Mississippi River 1,421.78 7.95 475.76 73.42 76.37 94.05 14.61 2,163.93 North Texas 114.30 178.64 5.64 420.41 3.38 0.00 0.94 723.31 South Texas 0.00 71.54 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 71.54 Subtotal 1,654.74 258.13 554.25 493.83 79.75 94.05 15.55 3,150.28 Atlantic: North Atlantic 413.18 1.20 86.20 0.00 1.24 40.71 0.00 542.54 South Atlantic 0.00 0.00 38.38 0.00 0.00 1.71 0.00 40.10 Subtotal 413.18 1 .20 124.59 0.00 1.24 42.42 0.00 582.64 Greak Lakes: Superior-Michigan 250.95 1.62 17.92 31.25 51.57 0.00 49.03 402.34 Huron-Erie 136.75 0.00 69.30 0.00 0.00 46.39 0.00 252.45 Subtotal 387.70 1.62 87.22 31.25 51.57 46.39 49.03 654.79 Pacific: Seattle Area 18.00 0.00 0.00 81.92 83.84 15.98 11.41 211.15 Portland Area 0.00 0.00 0.00 13.61 4.29 218.86 0.00 236.76 California 0.00 0.00 _ 0.00 3.15 7.47 4.36 12.00 26.98 Subtotal 18.00 0.00 0.00 98.68 95.60 239.20 23.41 474.88 Total Port Exports 2,473.62 260.95 766.06 623.76 228.15 422.06 87.98 4,862.59 interior Exports 28.80 0.00 24.32 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 53.12 Total Exports 2,502.42 260.95 790.38 623.76 228.15 422.06 87.98 4,915.71 ‘Subtotals and totals may not add up due to rounding. 2HRW stands for Hard Red Winter. 3HRS stands for Hard Red Spring. 25 Table 17. Effect on U.S. Port Area Grain and Soybean Flows of a Weight-Based User Fee which to Recoupe 50 Q Percent of Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OM NC OMNC OM NC OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent Port Area Volumez Change3 Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Gulf: East Gulf - 0.02 - 0.01 -30.10 -15.72 -30.12 -15.73 - 0.03 -0.01 - 0.06 -0.03 - 0.10 -0.05 Mississippi River 9.68 0.44 44.81 2.07 60.87 2.81 10.64 0.49 9.81 0.45 9.16 0.42 North Texas - 0.14 0.02 9.99 1.38 11.24 1.55 - 0.21 -0.03 - 0.43 -0.06 - 0.65 -0.09 South Texas 0.00 0.00 0.89 1.24 - 0.03 - 0.04 - 0.01 -0.01 - 0.01 -0.02 - 0.02 -0.03 Total 9.52 0.30 25.59 0.812 41.96 1.33 10.39 0.33 9.30 0.30 8.40 0.27 Atlantic: North Atlantic - 8.44 - 1.56 -53.28 - 9.82 -52.94 - 9.76 - 9.64 -1.78 -10.70 -1.97 -11.54 -2.13 South Atlantic 0.00 0.00 0.01 - 0.02 - 0.01 - 0.04 0.00 0.00 - 0.01 -0.02 - 0.01 -0.03 Total - 8.44 - 1.45 -53.29 - 9.15 -52.95 - 9.09 - 9.64 -1.65 -10.71 -1.84 -11.55 -1.98 Great Lakes: Superior-Michigan 10.69 2.66 18.71 4.65 17.32 4.30 - 0.41 -0.10 - 0.40 -0.10 - 0.39 -0.10 Huron-Erie -11.14 - 4.41 5.56 2.20 -11.24 - 4.45 - 0.04 -0.02 - 0.08 -0.03 - 0.12 -0.05 Total - 0.45 - 0.07 24.27 3.71 6.08 0.93 - 0.45 -0.07 - 0.48 -0.07 - 0.51 -0.08 Pacific: Seattle Area 50.22 23.78 - 2.24 - 1.06 50.05 23.71 - 2.14 -1.01 - 2.21 -1.05 - 2.27 -1.07 Portland Area -52.41 -22.14 - 0.07 - 0.03 -52.47 -22.16 - 0.02 -0.01 - 0.04 -0.02 - 0.07 -0.03 California 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Total - 2.19 - 0.46 - 2.31 - 0.49 - 2.41 - 0.51 - 2.16 -0.45 - 2.25 -0.47 - 2.34 -0.49 Total Port Exports‘ - 1.56 - 0.03 - 5.72 - 0.12 - 7.32 - 0.15 - 1.86 -0.04 - 4.14 -0.09 - 6.00 -0.12 lNumbers at the coast level may not add up to totals due to rounding. zMillion bushels. 3Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. grain exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. 26 1 1 4 T\ Fi Table 18. Effect on U.S. Port Area Grain and Soybean Flows of an Ad Valorem User Fee Which ls to Recoupe 50 Percent of Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OM NC OMNC OM NC 4 OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent Port Area Volumez Change3 Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Gulf: East Gulf - 0.01 - 0.01 -30.05 -15.69 -40.94 -21.38 - 0.02 -0.01 - 0.05 -0.02 - 0.06 -0.03 Mississippi River 10.50 0.48 53.61 2.48 47.21 2.18 10.86 0.50 10.33 0.48 9.93 0.46 North Texas - 0.52 - 0.07 10.70 1.48 10.47 1.45 - 0.12 0.02 - 0.26 -0.04 - 0.36 -0.05 South Texas 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 -0.02 Total 9.97 0.32 34.25 1.09 16.74 0.53 10.72 0.34 10.02 0.32 9.50 0.30 Atlantic: North Atlantic 6.66 1.23 -33.68 - 6.21 -34.80 - 6.41 - 9.24 -1.70 - 9.78 -1.80 -10.04 -1.85 South Atlantic 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Total 6.66 1.14 -33.68 - 6.21 -34.80 - 5.97 - 9.24 -1.59 - 9.78 -1.67 -10.04 -1.72 Great Lakes: Superior-Michigan 10.68 2.65 - 0.42 - 0.11 23.16 5.76 - 0.42 -0.11 - 0.43 -0.11 - 0.42 -0.10 Huron-Erie -25.73 -10.19 - 0.04 - 0.02 - 5.49 - 2.18 - 0.03 -0.01 - 0.04 -0.02 - 0.07 -0.03 Total -15.05 - 2.30 - 0.46 - 0.07 17.67 2.70 - 0.45 -0.07 - 0.47 -0.07 - 0.49 -0.07 Pacific: Seattle Area 50.26 23.80 - 2.14 - 1.01 50.18 23.77 - 2.11 -1.00 - 2.17 -1.03 - 2.21 -1.04 Portland Area -52.41 -22.13 - 0.03 - 0.01 -52.43 -22.14 - 0.01 -0.01 - 0.03 -0.01 - 0.05 -0.02 California 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Total - 2.15 - 0.45 - 2.17 - 0.46 - 2.24 - 0.47 - 2.12 -0.45 - 2.20 -0.46 - 2.26 -0.48 Total Port Exports‘ - 0.56 - 0.01 - 2.07 - 0.04 - 2.64 - 0.05 — 1.09 -0.02 - 2.44 -0.05 - 3.29 -0.07 ‘Numbers at the coast level may not add up to totals due to rounding. zMillion bushels. 3Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. grain exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. 27 Table 19. Effect on U.S. Port Area Corn of a Weight-Based User Fee Which ls to Recoupe Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OM NC OMNC OM NC OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent Volumez Change3 Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change 50 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf - 0.39 -0.02 22.72 1.37 22.37 1.35 -0.47 -0.03 -1.01 -0.06 -1.50 -0.09 Atlantic - 0.70 -0.17 -36.37 - 8.07 -34.07 - 8.25 -0.83 -0.20 -1.81 -0.45 -2.68 -0.65 Great Lakes - 0.00 0.00 6.63 1.71 6.58 1.70 0.00 0.00 -0.01 0.00 -0.01 0.00 Pacific - 0.00 -0.03 - 0.02 - 0.13 - 0.02 - 0.14 -0.01 -0.04 -0.02 -0.09 -0.02 -0.13 Total‘ - 1.00 -0.05 - 4.03 - 0.16 - 5.14 - 0.21 1.31 -0.05 -2.91 -0.12 -4.22 -0.17 100 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf -18.06 -1.09 38.03 2.30 24.87 1.50 0.92 -0.06 -2.07 -0.13 -2.98 -0.18 Atlantic 15.88 3.84 -52.54 -12.72 -41.49 -10.04 -1.68 -0.41 -3.69 -0.89 -5.37 -1.30 Great Lakes - 0.01 -0.00 6.47 1.67 6.39 1.65 -0.01 -0.00 -0.02 -0.00 -0.03 -0.01 Pacific - 0.01 -0.08 - 0.05 - 0.27 - 0.06 - 0.36 -0.01 -0.08 -0.03 -0.17 -0.05 -0.28 Total‘ - 2.20 -0.09 - 8.09 - 0.33 -10.30 - 0.42 2.63 -0.11 -5.81 -0.23 -8.43 -0.34 ‘Numbers may not add up to totals due to rounding. zMillion bushels. 3Percent change from baserun volume. u i ‘Overall reduction in U.S. corn exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. Table 20. Effect on U.S. Port Area Corn of an Ad Valorem User Fee Which ls to Recoupe Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)' Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OM NC OMNC OM NC OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent Volumez Change3 Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change 50 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf -0.14 -0.01 13.60 0.82 13.30 0.80 -0.24 -0.01 -0.53 -0.03 -0.70 -0.04 Atlantic -0.22 -0.05 -14.86 -3.60 -14.90 -3.61 -0.43 -0.10 -0.95 -0.23 -1.19 -0.29 Great Lakes 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Pacific 0.00 » 0.00 - 0.01 -0.03 - 0.01 -0.04 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 -0.04 -0.01 -0.05 Total‘ -0.35 -0.01 - 1.27 -0.05 - 1.16 -0.06 -0.67 -0.03 -1.49 -0.06 -1.91 -0.08 100 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf -0.25 -0.01 23.20 1.40 7.15 0.43 -0.48 -0.03 -1.05 -0.06 -1.54 -0.09 Atlantic -0.44 -0.10 -25.71 -6.22 -10.35 -2.50 -0.86 -0.21 -1.92 -0.46 -2.76 -0.67 Great Lakes -0.00 -0.00 - 0.01 -0.00 - 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.01 0.00 -0.01 0.00 Pacific -0.00 -0.00 - 0.01 -0.08 - 0.02 -0.09 0.01 -0.04 -0.02 -0.09 -0.02 0.13 Total‘ -0.69 -0.03 - 2.54 -0.10 - 3.23 -0.13 -1.357 -0.05 -3.00 -0.12 -4.34 -0.17 ‘Numbers may not add up to totals due to rounding. \ zMllllOfl bushels. @} 3Percent change from baserun volume. ’ ‘Overall reduction in U.S. corn exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. 28 P‘ Table 21. Effect on U.S. Port Area Sorghum of a Weight-Based User Fee Which Is to Recoupe Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)l Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OM NC OMNC OM NC a OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent Volumez Change3 Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change 50 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf -0.12 -0.04 -0.42 -0.16 -0.54 -0.21 -0.14 -0.05 -0.30 -0.11 -0.44 -0.17 Atlantic 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Great Lakes 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Pacific 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Total‘ -0.12 -0.04 -0.42 -0.16 -0.54 -0.21 -0.14 -0.05 -0.30 -0.11 -0.44 -0.17 100 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf -0.23 -0.09 -0.84 -0.32 -1.06 -0.41 -0.27 -0.10 -0.60 -0.23 -0.87 -0.33 Atlantic 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Great Lakes 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Pacific 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Total“ -0.23 -0.09 -0.84 -0.32 -1.06 -0.41 -0.27 -0.10 -0.60 -0.23 -0.87 -0.33 ‘Numbers may not add up to totals due to rounding. zMillion bushels. 3Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. sorghum exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. Table 22. Effect on U.S. Port Area Sorghum of an Ad Valorem User Fee Which ls to Recoupe Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OM NC OMNC OM NC OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent Volumez Change3 Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change 50 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf -0.04 -0.02 -0.14 -0.05 -0.17 -0.07 -0.07 -0.03 -0.16 -0.06 -O.23 -0.09 Atlantic 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 ‘K Great Lakes 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Pacific 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Total‘ -0.04 -0.02 -0.14 -0.05 -0.17 -0.07 -0.07 -0.03 -0.16 -0.06 -0.23 -0.09 100 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf -0.08 -0.03 -0.26 -0.10 -0.34 -0.13 -0.14 -0.06 -O.31 -0.12 -0.46 -0.18 Atlantic 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Great Lakes 0.00 l" 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Pacific 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Total‘ -0.08 -0.03 -0.26 -0.10 -1.34 -0.13 -0.14 -0.06 -0.31 -0.12 -O.46 -0.18 \ ‘Numbers may not add up to totals due to rounding. “Million bushels. 3Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. sorghum exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. 29 Table 23. Effect on U.S. Port Area Soybeans of a Weight-Based User Fee Which Is to Recoupe-Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 ‘ OM NC OMNC OM NC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent Volumez Change?’ Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change 50 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf - 0.13 - 0.02 1.87 0.34 5.91 1.07 -0.15 -0.03 -0.32 -0.06 -0.45 -0.08 Atlantic - 0.01 - 0.01 - 6.49 - 5.21 -6.50 -5.22 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 -0.03 -0.02 Great Lakes 0.00 0.00 4.16 4.77 -0.02 -0.02 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 Pacific 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Total“ - 0.14 - 0.02 - 0.47 - 0.06 -0.61 -0.08 -0.16 -0.02 -0.35 -0.05 -0.50 -0.07 100 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf - 0.25 - 0.04 36.79 6.64 5.35 0.97 -0.29 -0.05 -0.61 -0.11 -0.90 -0.16 Atlantic 14.60 11.72 -41.89 -33.62 -6.54 -5.25 -0.02 -0.01 -0.05 -0.04 -0.07 -0.06 Great Lakes -14.62 -16.76 4.15 4.75 -0.03 -0.03 -0.03 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 Pacific 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Total‘ - 0.27 - 0.04 - 0.96 - 0.12 -1.21 -0.16 -0.31 -0.04 -0.68 -0.09 -0.99 -0.13 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OMNC ‘Numbers may not add up to totals due to rounding. zMillion bushels. 3Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. soybean exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. Table 24. Effect on U.S. Port Area Soybeans of an Ad Valorem User Fee Which ls to Recoupe Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OM NC OMNC OM NC OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent . Volume’ Change3 Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change 50 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf - 0.07 - 0.01 6.16 1.11 1.92 -0.35 -0.16 -0.03 -0.35 -0.06 -0.50 -0.09 * Atlantic 14.61 11.72 -6.48 -5.20 -6.49 -5.21 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 -0.03 -0.03 _ I Great Lakes -14.61 a -16.76 -0.01 -0.01 4.16 4.77 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 w Pacific 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Total‘ - 0.08 - 0.01 -0.32 -0.04 -0.40 -0.05 -0.17 0.02 -0.38 -0.05 -0.54 -0.07 100 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf - 0.16 - 0.03 5.89 1.06 1.56 0.28 -0.32 -0.06 -0.67 -0.12 -0.99 -0.18 Atlantic 14.60 11 .72 -6.50 -5.22 -6.52 -5.23 -0.02 -0.01 -0.06 -0.04 -0.08 -0.06 Great Lakes -14.61 -16.76 -0.02 -0.02 4.15 4.76 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 -0.03 Pacific 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Total‘ - 0.17 - 0.02 -0.63 -0.08 0.81 -0.10 -0.34 -0.04 -0.75 -0.10 -1.09 -0.14 ‘Numbers may not add up to totals due to rounding. zMillion bushels. 3Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. soybean exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. 30 P‘ Table 25. Effect on U.S. Port Area Hard Red Winter Wheat of a Weight-Based User Fee Which ls to Recoupe Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OM NC OMNC OM NC OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent Volume’ Change3 Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change 50 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf -0.04 -0.01 -0.37 -0.07 -0.42 -0.09 -0.11 -0.02 -0.25 -0.05 -0.36 -0.07 Atlantic 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Great Lakes 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 -0.02 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 -0.02 Pacific -0.06 -0.06 0.00 0.00 -0.06 -0.06 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 -0.03 -0.03 Total‘ -0.10 -0.02 -0.37 -0.06 -0.49 -0.08 -0.12 -0.02 -0.27 -0.04 -0.40 -0.06 100 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf -0.15 -0.03 -0.75 -0.15 -0.90 -0.18 -0.23 -0.05 -0.50 -0.10 -0.72 -0.15 Atlantic 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Great Lakes -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 0.03 -0.01 -0.04 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 -0.03 Pacific -0.06 -0.06 -0.01 0.01 -0.07 -0.07 -0.02 -0.02 -0.05 -0.05 -0.06 -0.07 Total‘ -0.21 -0.03 -0.77 -0.12 -0.98 -0.16 -0.25 -0.04 -0.55 -0.09 -0.80 -0.13 ‘Numbers may not add up to totals due to rounding. zMillion bushels. 3Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. hard red winter wheat exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. Table 26. Effect on U.S. Port Area Hard Red Winter Wheat of an Ad Valorem User Fee Which ls to Recoupe Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OM NC OMNC OM NC OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent Volumez Changeg’ Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change 50 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf 0.01 0.00 -0.15 -0.03 -0.16 -0.03 -0.08 -0.02 -0.17 -0.03 -0.26 -0.05 q Atlantic 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Great Lakes 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 -0.02 Pacific -0.06 -0.06 0.00 0.00 -0.06 -0.06 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 Total‘ -0.04 -0.01 -0.15 -0.02 -0.21 -0.03 -0.08 -0.01 -0.19 -0.03 -0.28 -0.04 100 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf -0.03 0Q; -0.32 -0.06 -0.35 -0.07 -0.15 -0.03 -0.35 -0.07 -0.51 -0.10 Atlantic 0.00 i 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Great Lakes 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 -0.02 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 -0.02 Pacific -0.06 -0.06 0.00 0.00 -0.06 -0.06 -0.01 -0.01 -0.03 -0.03 -0.05 -0.05 Total‘ -0.09 -0.01 -0.33 -0.05 -0.41 -0.07 -0.17 -0.03 -0.38 -0.06 -0.57 -0.09 \V‘Numbers may not add up to totals due to rounding. zMillion bushels. ‘Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. hard red winter wheat exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. 31" Table 27. Effect on U.S. Port Area Hard Red Spring Wheat of a Weight-Based User Fee Which ls to Recoupefil" Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OM NC OMNC OM NC OMNC Change Change In Percent In Volumez Change3 Change Change Percent In Percent In Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Change Percent In Percent In Percent Change Volume Change Volume Change Gulf Atlantic Great Lakes Pacific Total‘ Gulf Atlantic Great Lakes Pacific Total‘ 50 Percent Cost Recovery Level -0.02 -0.03 -8.40 -10.53 -0.14 -0.18 -0.03 -0.04 -0.08 -0.10 -0.11 -0.14 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 8.28 16.06 -0.02 -0.03 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 -0.03 -0.01 -0.01 0.03 0.03 -0.02 -0.02 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 -0.03 -0.03 -0.03 -0.01 -0.14 - 0.06 -0.18 -0.08 -0.04 -0.02 -0.10 -0.04 -0.15 -0.07 100 Percent Cost Recovery Level -0.05 -0.07 -8.49 -10.65 -0.26 -0.33 -0.07 -0.08 -0.15 -0.19 -0.22 -0.27 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 8.25 16.00 -0.03 -0.06 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 -0.04 -0.03 -0.05 -0.02 -0.02 -0.05 - 0.05 -0.07 -0.07 -0.02 -0.02 -0.03 -0.03 -0.05 -0.04 -0.07 -0.03 -0.29 - 0.13 -0.36 -0.16 -0.09 -0.04 -0.21 -0.09 -0.30 -0.13 ‘Numbers may not add up to totals due to rounding. “Million bushels. 3Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. hard red spring wheat exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. Table 28. Effect on U.S. Port Area Hard Red Spring Wheat of an Ad Valorem User Fee Which ls to Recoupe Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 OM NC OMNC OM NC OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent In Percent In Percent ln Percent In Percent In Percent Volumez Change3 Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change 50 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf -0.01 -0.01 -0.04 -0.05 -8.36 -10.48 -0.01 -0.02 -0.05 -0.06 -0.08 -0.10 y. Atlantic 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 ’ Great Lakes 0.00 ’ 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 8.30 -16.10 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 l ‘ Pacific 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 - 0.02 0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 Total‘ -0.01 -0.01 -0.06 -0.03 -0.07 - 0.03 0.03 -0.01 -0.07 -0.03 -0.10 -0.04 100 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf -0.02 -0.03 -0.09 -0.11 -8.41 -10.55 -0.05 -0.06 -0.10 -0.13 -0.15 -0.19 Atlantic 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Great Lakes 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.02 8.28 16.06 0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 -0.04 Pacific -0.01 -0.01 -0.03 -0.03 -0.03 - 0.03 0.02 -0.02 -0.03 -0.03 -0.04 -0.04 Total‘ -0.03 -0.01 -0.13 -0.06 -0.16 - 0.07 0.07 -0.03 -0.14 -0.06 -0.21 -0.09 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees ‘Numbers may not add up to totals due to rounding. zMillion bushels. 3Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. hard red spring wheat exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. 32 m9JL'$n.-.J_u.fi < CPFabIe 29. Effect on U.S. Port Area Soft Wheat of a Weight-Based User Fee Which ls to Recoupe Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OM NC OMNC OM NC OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent Volumez Change3 Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change 50 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf 7.72 8.21 7.70 8.18 12.29 13.07 8.79 9.34 8.77 9.32 8.76 9.32 Atlantic -7.73 -18.23 -13.44 -31.67 -12.38 -29.19 -8.80 -20.75 -8.82 -20.79 -8.84 -20.83 Great Lakes -0.01 - 0.01 5.65 12.18 - 0.02 - 0.05 -0.01 - 0.01 -0.01 - 0.03 -0.02 - 0.04 Pacific -0.06 - 0.02 0.20 - 0.08 - 0.24 - 0.10 -0.07 - 0.03 -0.13 - 0.06 -0.19 - 0.08 Total‘ -0.08 - 0.02 - 0.28 - 0.07 - 0.35 - 0.08 -0.09 - 0.02 -0.20 - 0.05 -0.29 - 0.07 100 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf 7.70 8.19 7.66 8.15 12.26 13.04 8.77 9.32 8.75 9.30 8.74 9.29 Atlantic -7.75 -18.26 -13.48 -31.77 -12.44 -29.32 -8.82 -20.78 -8.85 -20.87 -8.88 -20.94 Great Lakes -0.01 - 0.02 5.64 12.16 - 0.04 - 0.10 -0.02 - 0.03 -0.02 - 0.05 -0.04 - 0.08 Pacific -0.10 - 0.04 - 0.38 - 0.16 - 0.49 - 0.20 -0.12 - 0.05 -0.27 - 0.11 -0.40 - 0.17 Total‘ -0.15 - 0.04 - 0.56 - 0.13 - 0.71 - 0.17 -0.18 - 0.04 -0.40 - 0.10 -0.58 - 0.14 ‘Numbers may not add up to totals due to rounding. zMillion bushels. ‘Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. soft wheat exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. Table 30. Effect on U.S. Port Area Soft Wheat of an Ad Valorem User Fee Which ls to Recoupe Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees OM NC OMNC OM NC OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent Volumez Change3 Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change 50 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf 7.72 8.21 12.32 13.10 7.71 8.19 8.79 9.34 8.78 9.33 8.77 9.32 Atlantic -7.73 -18.22 -12.34 -29.08 -13.42 -31.63 -8.80 -20.74 -8.82 -20.78 -8.82 -20.80 Great Lakes 0.00 0.00 - 0.01 - 0.02 5.65 12.18 -0.01 - 0.01 -0.01 - 0.02 -0.01 - 0.03 Pacific -0.02 - 0.01 - 0.09 - 0.04 - 0.10 - 0.04 -0.04 - 0.02 -0.10 - 0.04 -0.14 - 0.06 Total‘ -0.03 - 0.01 - 0.12 - 0.03 - 0.16 - 0.04 -0.05 - 0.01 -0.15 - 0.03 -0.21 - 0.05 100 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf 7.72 8.21 12.30 13.08 7.69 8.18 8.78 9.33 8.76 9.32 8.75 9.30 Atlantic -7.73 -18.22 -12.36 -29.14 -13.44 -31.68 -8.81 -20.77 -8.84 -20.83 -8.86 -20.88 Great Lakes -0.01 - 0.01 - 0.02 - 0.03 5.65 12.18 -0.01 - 0.02 0.02 - 0.04 -0.03 - 0.06 Pacific -0.05 - 0.02 - 0.17 - 0.07 - 0.21 - 0.09 -0.09 - 0.04 -0.19 - 0.08 -0.28 - 0.12 Total‘ -0.06 - 0.02 - 0.24 - 0.06 - 0.31 - 0.07 -0.13 - 0.03 -0.29 - 0.07 -0.41 - 0.10 "\lNumbers may not add up to totals due to rounding. Million bushels. ‘Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. soft wheat exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. 33 Table 31. Effect on U.S. Port Area Du rum Wheat of a Weight-Based User Fee Which ls to Recoupe Operationfi .1 and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)1 r Gulf Atlantic Great Lakes Pacific Total‘ Gulf Atlantic Great Lakes Pacific Total‘ OM Change In Volume’ Change’ 2.50 0.00 -0.44 -2.07 0.00 2.50 0.00 -0.44 -2.07 -0.01 Percent 16.06 0.00 - 0.89 - 8.82 - 0.00 16.06 0.00 - 0.89 - 8.83 - 0.01 Uniform Fees NC Port-Specific Fees NC OMNC OM OMNC Change Change In Percent In Volume Change Percent In Change Volume Change Volume Change Percent In Change Volume Change Percent In Percent Change Volume Change 50 Percent Cost Recovery Level 2.50 16.06 2.50 16.06 2.50 16.06 2.50 16.06 2.50 16.06 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.44 - 0.89 -0.44 - 0.90 -0.44 - 0.89 -0.44 - 0.89 -0.44 - 0.89 -2.07 - 8.83 -2.07 - 8.84 2.06 - 8.82 2.07 - 3.83 2.07 - 8.83 -0.01 - 0.01 -0.02 - 0.02 -0.00 - 0.00 -0.01 - 0.01 -0.01 - 0.01 100 Percent Cost Recovery Level 2.49 16.01 2.49 16.01 2.50 16.06 2.49 16.02 -2.49 16.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.45 - 0.91 -0.45 - 0.92 -0.44 - 0.89 -0.44 - 0.90 -0.45 - 0.91 -2.07 - 8.86 -2.07 - 8.86 -2.07 - 8.84 -2.07 - 8.85 -2.07 - 8.86 -0.03 - 0.04 -0.04 - 0.04 -0.01 - 0.01 -0.02 - 0.03 -0.03 - 0.04 ‘Numbers may not add up to totals due to rounding. zMillion bushels. 3Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. durum wheat exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. Table 32. Effect on U.S. Port Area Durum Wheat of an Ad Valorem User Fee Which ls to Recoupe Operations and Maintenance Expenses (OM), New Construction Costs (NC), and the Aggregate of These Costs (OMNC)l OM NC OMNC OM NC OMNC Change Change Change Change Change Change In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent In Percent Volume’ Change3 Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change Volume Change 50 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf 2.50 16.07 2.50 16.06 2.50 16.06 2.50 16.06 2.50 16.06 2.50 16.06 , Atlantic 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 _ 1 Great Lakes -0.44 g - 0.89 -0.44 - 0.89 -0.44 - 0.89 -0.44 - 0.89 -0.44 - 0.89 -0.44 - 0.890 Pacific 2.06 - 8.82 2.06 - 8.82 2.07 - 8.83 -2.06 - 8.82 -2.07 - 8.83 -2.07 - 8.83 Total‘ 0.00 0.00 -0.01 - 0.01 -0.01 - 0.01 0.00 0.00 -0.01 - 0.01 -0.01 - 0.01 100 Percent Cost Recovery Level Gulf 2.50 16.06 2.50 16.06 2.50 16.06 2.50 16.06 2.50 16.06 2.50 16.02 Atlantic 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Great Lakes -0.44 - 0.89 -0.44 - 0.90 -0.44 - 0.90 -0.44 - 0.90 -0.44 - 0.90 -0.44 - 0.91 Pacific -2.07 - 8.82 -2.07 - 8.83 -2.07 - 8.84 -2.07 - 8.82 -2.07 - 8.84 -2.07 - 8.85 Total‘ -0.00 - 0.01 -0.10 - 0.01 -0.01 - 0.02 -0.01 - 0.01 -0.01 - 0.01 -0.03 - 0.02 Port-Specific Fees Uniform Fees ‘Numbers may not add up to totals due to rounding. zMillion bushels. 3Percent change from baserun volume. ‘Overall reduction in U.S. durum wheat exports resulting from increase in export price due to user charge imposition. 34 i [Blank Page in Original Bulletin] ' 5c zlx I A. l» ‘Knit: Mention of a trademark or a proprietary product does not constitute a guarantee or a warranty of the product by The Texas Agricultural Experiment Station and does not imply its approval to the exclusion of other products that also may be suitable. a All programs and information of The Texas Agricultural Experiment Station are available to everyone without regard to race, color, religion, sex, age, handicap, or national origin. 1M—3-87